• No results found

Link with empirical evidence and empirical predictions

1.5 Implications of the Optimal Contract

1.5.3 Link with empirical evidence and empirical predictions

Similarly to this setting, financial analysts collect private information re- garding the ex-ante unknown state of the world (profitability of a com- pany), and issue a forecast regarding future earnings. By applying our framework to this environment, we would expect that the analysts’ fore- casts are biased against the publicly available information. Thebias against

the flowis consistent with the empirical evidence on financial analysts. For instance, Bernhardt and Kutsoati (2001) and Pierdzioch et al. (2013) provide evidence that analysts issue biased contrarian forecasts. In fact, Bernhardt and Kutsoati (2001) show that the conditional probability that a forecast exceeds realized earnings, given that the forecasts exceeds the consensus forecast, is lower than the unconditional probability. Note that the under- lying idea in Bernhardt and Kutsoati (2001) is similar to our setting: our model predicts that in an environment where prior beliefs indicate it is more likely that the price will drop, the conditional probability that the asset price increases given a long position, is lower than the corresponding probability when the first best threshold is implemented.

Also, Corollary 2 and the mechanism which was presented in the section 1.5.2 , could provide a theoretical foundation of the empirical evi- dence which indicate that investor over-react and/or under-react to finan- cial analysts’ forecasts (Elgers et al., 2001, Elliot et al., 1995, Elliot et al., 1995, Mendenhall, 1991, Sloan, 1996). Similarly to the forecasts of financial analysts, the position of the manager is informative about his private sig- nal. Hence, the implemented position can be used by market participants, to infer the quality of the asset and the future price. Our model predicts that rational investors should under-react when the manager’s position is against the flow, and over-react when the manager’s position follows the flow.

1.5.4

Impact of information acquisition cost,

c.

Proposition 5 summarizes the impact of the cost of acquiring information,

c, on the optimal contract and its main implications. We consider values of

cfor which the equity holder finds it optimal to incentivize the manager to acquire information.

Proposition 5: Impact of an increase in c

If p> 0.5 (p <0.5), an increase in the cost of information acquisition from c to c0, leads to:

(i) An increase (decrease) in the optimal threshold fromsˆ∗ tosˆ0∗.

(ii) A higher bias|sˆ0∗−sˆFB| >|sˆ∗−sˆFB|.

(iii) A lower (higher) probability that an implemented short position is revenue- maximizing.

(iv) A higher (lower) probability that an implemented long position is revenue- maximizing.

(v) A lower expected probability of taking the revenue-maximizing position. Proof. See Appendix A.3.

We provide the underlying intuition behind Proposition 5 for the case where p > 0.5. Similar intuition applies for the case where p <

0.5. The findings of Proposition 5 depend on the behavior of EC(sˆ) as c

increases. By Lemma 3, EC(sˆ) is convex, decreasing in ˆs for ˆs ∈ [0, ˆsmin), increasing in ˆs for ˆs ∈ (sˆmin, 1] and linearly dependent in c. Thus, an increase in cost c shifts the entire EC(sˆ) curve upwards, which leads to a

steeper-sloped U-shape. This is captured in Figure 1.6, where ˆsis depicted in the horizontal axis, the red line represents the ER(sˆ), the green line representsEC(sˆ,c) and the blue line representsEC(sˆ,c0).

0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 0.5 1 1.5 2 ˆ sFB sˆ∗ sˆ0∗ A A0 B B0 ER(sˆ) EC(sˆ,c) EC(sˆ,c0)

Figure 1.6. Impact of an increase in the information acquisition costc

Recall that when p≥0.5, a deviation from ˆsFB to ˆs=sˆFB+η has a positive and a negative effect. On the one hand, it decreases the expected compen- sation cost (Lemma 3), but on the other hand, it decreases the expected revenue (Lemma 4). Under the optimal value, ˆs∗, the two opposite forces cancel each other, i.e., the benefit of decreasing the expected cost coincides with the loss of decreasing the expected revenue. Notice that a steeper- sloped U-shape forEC(sˆ), which follows an increase inc, strengthens the incentive to increase ˆs. This is because, for a given deviation η from the first best, the reduction in the expected cost is higher the steeper the slop of U-shape is. This can be seen in Figure 1.6, where the distance A0B0 (AB) captures the reduction in the expected cost before (after) the increase in c. Thus, ˆs0∗ >sˆ∗, which combining with the fact that ˆsFB is unaffected by the change inc, leads to a higher bias compared to the first best.

Part three (four) is a consequence of part two of Proposition 5 and part two (three) of Corollary 2. Finally, part five stems from the monotonic

relation between the expected revenue and the probability of getting the revenue-maximizing position. Notice that the lower probability of taking the right position is not a consequence of the fact that the manager does not acquire information (recall that Proposition 5 refers to the case where incentivizing information acquisition is optimal). The underlined intuition is that the distortion in the investment decision increases, which in turn, diminishes the information which is incorporated into the implemented position.