• No results found

Debt Sustainability for Low Income Countries: A Review of Standard and Alternative Concepts

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2020

Share "Debt Sustainability for Low Income Countries: A Review of Standard and Alternative Concepts"

Copied!
37
0
0

Loading.... (view fulltext now)

Full text

(1)

Debt Sustainability for Low-Income

Countries: A Review of Standard and

Alternative Concepts

Cassimon, Denis and Moreno-Dodson, Blanca and Wodon,

Quentin

World Bank

January 2008

Online at

https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/11077/

(2)

Governments in low-income countries (LICs) have the difficult task of making wide-ranging decisions about public spending, taxation, and bor-rowing. Although we can analyze at length how both public spending and taxation can be designed and implemented to contribute to growth and poverty reduction, the biggest challenge that most developing countries face is in determining how much they can borrow without jeopardizing their long-term prospects. The objective of this chapter is to introduce the key issues involved in debt sustainability analysis (DSA). We will re-view the main approaches developed in the literature, starting from the traditional fiscal and external approaches and covering recent alternative frameworks, such as the debt overhang analysis and the human develop-ment approach (especially as it relates to the funding requiredevelop-ments for achieving the Millennium Development Goals [MDGs]).

Debt sustainability requires that indebtedness be kept in line with the capacity of the borrower to repay (IMF 2003). At a firm or project level, this means that borrowed funds should be invested productively with a return high enough to cover debt-service costs. This simple definition, however, is not as easily applied to countries as it is to firms or projects.

Debt Sustainability

for Low-Income Countries

A Review of Standard and Alternative Concepts

(3)

Government borrowing often is used to cover public deficits rather than to invest in specific projects, and the returns to public investments in the social sectors or infrastructure may materialize only in the distant future. This makes it difficult to take the returns to investment into account. In addition, debt-servicing capacity is determined by government revenues, which depend on tax rates as well as on economic growth. Finally, debt sustainability is affected by variables that often are not under government control, such as the level of world interest rates, the degree of concession-ality in the loans received, and the foreign exchange rate.

Given the complex web of factors that affect debt sustainability and are affected by it, the concept cannot be captured in a single indicator or in simple rules of thumb that would apply indiscriminately to all coun-tries. What is needed when working on debt sustainability is a country-specific analysis looking at a set of different indicators and their dynam-ics, with a particular focus on identifying binding constraints to development as well as key vulnerabilities to which the country may be exposed in the future. At the same time, some guidance and an overview of the main approaches used in the literature on debt sustainability should be useful to anyone studying the relationships between public fi-nance and poverty reduction.

The traditional approaches to debt sustainability cover two basic crite-ria: fiscal and external. Consider first fiscal sustainability. Developing countries typically experience a chronic shortfall of domestic savings over the (targeted) level of domestic investment required to generate enough growth to reduce poverty and to meet the MDGs. This savings gap often is mirrored by a fiscal gap—that is, the public sector runs a fiscal deficit to allow for more spending than would be allowed on the basis of gov-ernment revenue (or more investment than would be allowed on the ba-sis of public saving).1To the extent that it is not covered by monetary

(4)

budget that, for some reason, cannot be transferred into the current budg-et. This may happen in some aid-dependent developing countries where there is not enough country budget ownership and donors funding in-vestment projects face absorption capacity limits on the recipient side but are reluctant to divert some of those resources to the current budget.

Beyond a fiscal gap, many countries are confronted with an external fi-nancing gap, which may lead to concerns about the external sustainabili-ty of the country’s debt. LICs must rely on foreign capital to finance their savings gap. In an open economy, the excess of domestic investment over domestic savings is equal to the trade deficit; or, put in other terms, an ex-cess of domestic investment over national savings translates into a current account deficit. Because LICs’ debts are largely denominated in foreign currencies, productive investments should enable countries to convert domestic resources into foreign exchange by generating sufficient export earnings—but this is not always the case.

In addition to the concerns about fiscal and external debt sustainabili-ty, the recent literature has identified two additional constraints that feed into debt sustainability concepts and indicators. These relatively recent phenomena, partly linked to the current debt burden itself, have been translated into “alternative” concepts of debt sustainability, two of which are especially important here. First, a high current debt itself may severe-ly hamper future debt-servicing capacity because it might introduce to the economy all kinds of disincentive effects to invest and adjust, result-ing in a severe negative effect on future economic growth. This is the so-called debt overhang hypothesis.This effect is usually linked to a high stock of debt. Second, a high current debt-service burden also may act as an im-portant constraint that is difficult to deal with from a political or moral point of view. The issue is that the resources allocated to debt service may crowd out social or other poverty-related spending as defined, for in-stance, through the measures needed to reach the MDGs or other targets specified in a country’s Poverty Reduction Strategy Paper (PRSP). As such, a wedge can be inserted between the capacity to pay debt service and what would be considered “affordable” debt service (EURODAD 2001) in order not to crowd out priority sector spending. The so-called

(5)

Given the multiple dimensions of the debt sustainability issue, instead of using a one-dimensional measure of debt sustainability, we would ar-gue that it is preferable to rely on a framework that recognizes the multi-ple constraints faced by LICs. This argument implies that DSA should be carried out using a menu of indicators, including both the present value of the debt stock and debt-service indicators relative to a range of vari-ables, such as exports, revenues, and GDP; and analyzing their dynamic evolution over time using realistic macroeconomic assumptions. It also is important to simulate the effect of country-specific key bottlenecks and vulnerabilities. To apply such a menu of indicators and approaches suc-cessfully in a country-specific context, one has to show which aspects are most binding in a particular case and moment in time.

This chapter is structured as follows. In the next section, we provide a brief review of the theoretical concepts used in traditional debt analysis to derive a list of possible constraints and variables that affect debt sus-tainability. In the third section, we discuss how different indicators have been applied in operational schemes, such as the Enhanced Heavily In-debted Poor Countries (HIPC) Initiative and the new (revised) Interna-tional Monetary Fund (IMF)/World Bank (2006) framework for long-term debt sustainability for LICs. The fourth section is devoted to an analysis of alternative DSA frameworks (such as the debt overhang hy-pothesis and the human development approach to debt sustainability). There is also a brief discussion of the new debt relief initiative advocated by the Group of Eight (G-8)—the Multilateral Debt Relief Initiative (MDRI)—that situates debt relief within an MDG perspective. A conclu-sion completes the chapter.

Traditional Approaches to Debt Sustainability: A Brief Review

(6)

public agencies; or due to restrictions on shifting resources from invest-ment to recurrent expenditures. All these constraints may lead to a severe shortage of funds available for recurrent expenditures and thus cause sit-uations where debt service has to compete with other recurrent priority spending. These constraints, and the need to borrow to invest for the country’s development and provide much-needed basic services to the population, also may give rise to the so-called twin-deficit situation—a fiscal deficit coupled with a current account balance deficit.

Our objective in this section is to link the different potentially binding constraints faced by LICs with simple concepts and indicators that are de-veloped in the literature and applied in practice to measure debt sustain-ability. We focus first on fiscal sustainability concepts, and then discuss external sustainability indicators. We also briefly present the solvency ap-proach to debt sustainability. Building on the concept of the present val-ue of debt in the solvency approach, and given that most low-income debt is concessional, we then show how the conventional fiscal and ex-ternal sustainability concepts can be fine-tuned by using this present val-ue of debt concept rather than nominal stocks or debt-service flows. We start with the traditional approaches to debt sustainability, leaving the other two alternative concepts for later.

Fiscal Approach

The conventional accounting approach to fiscal sustainability is based on a simple indicator: the ratio of debt to gross domestic product (GDP). The difficulty lies in estimating this ratio and in analyzing how it changes over time. There are many good descriptions of the mathematics of debt sustainability in the literature. One such description, which is both de-tailed and short, is provided by Ley (2004). To present the concepts of debt sustainability as simply as possible in our review, we will not derive the key results of the literature; rather, we simply will provide and inter-pret them. The reader is referred to Ley (2004) or other similar accounts for a formal treatment.2

(7)

used to reduce the public debt stock. This means that the debt at time t is equal to the debt at time t – 1 plus the interest paid on the debt minus the creation of money and a term (the primary budget balance) equal to the difference between the resources available to the government from tax revenues and foreign aid in the form of grants, and the use of those re-sources in the form of recurrent consumption and investments. Formally, this equation can be written as follows:

Dt= Dt–1+ iDt–1– (T+ AgbIgC*g) – DM= (1 + i)Dt–1– (B+ DM), (2.1)

where D is the stock of public debt;i is the average nominal interest rate on public debt;Tis the domestic government revenue, consisting mainly of taxes;Agbis foreign aid in the form of grants flowing to the government budget;C*gis government recurrent spending (including transfers) but ex-clusive of interest payment on public debt;DMis monetary financing; and

B is the primary (that is, noninterest) government balance, including bud-getized grant aid (with B>0 denoting a surplus).

The concept of sustainability implies that we must look at changes in debt indicators over time, and that we must normalize these indicators by a measure of the government’s ability to service debt, such as government revenue or GDP. Let’s denote by dtthe ratio of debt to GDP at time t;by

rtthe average real interest rate on the debt (after netting out inflation to simplify the notation); by gtthe real growth rate of GDP; and by b*tthe ratio of the primary balance, including any monetary financing, to GDP at time t.With a few assumptions and relatively simple algebra applied to equation (2.1), we can show that changes to the debt-to-GDP ratio over time will adhere to the following “law of motion”:

Ddt=

1 +rt– ggt

dt–1b*t. (2.2)

t

(8)

rise unless the government runs a sufficiently large primary fiscal surplus. Keeping the debt-to-GDP ratio stable also will require a primary surplus. If, on the other hand, the growth rate of GDP exceeds the average rate of interest on public debt, keeping the debt-to-GDP ratio stable or even re-ducing it is compatible with running a primary fiscal deficit. The intuition for this result is that higher growth will generate higher revenues that will make it easier to pay the government debt in the future. Note also that equation (2.2) can be transformed into a relationship showing the pri-mary balance (with monetary financing) b* that is required to stabilize the public debt-to-GDP ratio (that is,Dd = 0). For countries that are able to borrow at concessional interest rates, it is easier, in principle, to realize a positive growth-to-interest rate differential. This in turn makes debt sustainability easier to achieve and maintain even when running fiscal pri-mary deficits. In reality, however, there have been many disappointing cases of LICs with exploding debt ratios, despite favorable borrowing terms, resulting from lower-than-expected growth rates (the implicit “re-turn” on the borrowed funds), large deficits, or a combination of the two. One could argue that sustainability should not be defined only in terms of maintaining a stable debt-to-GDP ratio. Sustainability ultimately de-pends on the difference between the current level of the debt ratio and its “desired” level. Given a range of combinations of growth rates, interest rates, and primary surpluses (for a given debt ratio), it is possible in prin-ciple to arrive at and sustain a desired level of indebtedness. But the fiscal sustainability framework presented here is intentionally not normative— it only highlights the dynamic behavior of the indicator chosen to analyze the sustainability of debt over time. More normative definitions of what could constitute a desired, optimal, or sustainable level of debt will be in-troduced in later sections of this chapter. Note also that, in principle, vul-nerability to output shocks (which negatively influences the debt-to-GDP ratio) could be dampened by making debt contingent—for example, by creating instruments such as GDP-linked debt. In practice, however, it appears to be extremely difficult to create a market for such instru-ments.3

(9)

gov-ernment’s balance sheet (that is, revenues in local currency and part of the expenditures in foreign currency). Exchange rate dynamics thus play an important role in determining the domestic cost of debt service and fiscal sustainability.4

Define by et= Det/et–1the change in the exchange rate over two peri-ods (with a depreciation showing a positive sign), by afthe part of the

debt that is denominated in foreign-currency, by r*the weighted average real interest rate on both foreign and domestic debt, and by rfthe real

in-terest rate on the foreign debt. It can then be shown that

Ddt=

r*tgt+ eta

f(1 + r tf)

dt–1b*t. (2.3)

(1+ gt)

Equation (2.3) introduces a foreign exchange rate effect through the en-dogenous dynamics term of the debt sustainability relationship, which now is driven by four variables: (1) the interest rate on the debt, (2) the growth rate of GDP, (3) the inflation rate (which does not appear in the equation because we use real interest rates), and (4) the foreign exchange rate. A depreciation of the currency will lead to an increase in the debt ra-tio over time, and this increase will be larger if the share of the debt de-nominated in foreign currency is larger and if the real interest rate paid on the debt in foreign currency is higher.

(10)

two components, similar to the interest rate decomposition, to express it as a weighted average of domestic and foreign inflation rates. The valua-tion gains or losses in tradable sector output induced by the exchange rate then depend on the share of tradable output in total output. Because this introduces an exchange rate effect on the denominator of the endogenous dynamics term in equation (2.3), it dampens the previous foreign ex-change rate effect so that the result shown in equation (2.3) is best inter-preted as the maximum foreign exchange effect.

One last remark on the accounting approach to DSA refers to the use of specific variables for the denominator and numerator in the debt ratio. We have presented the basic analysis of debt dynamics using the debt-to-GDP ratio as a good indicator to measure debt sustainability. This should be a rather obvious choice for fiscal sustainability, although other indica-tors relating debt to government revenues can provide useful additional information. Moreover, sustainability indicators where the numerator is a flow variable rather than a stock variable, such as debt service to GDP or to government revenues, also can provide complementary and sometimes more useful information.

External Approach

We now turn to a discussion of the sustainability of the combined public and private debt from a foreign exchange or external point of view. The idea is to measure sustainability in terms of a foreign exchange constraint instead of the fiscal constraint. A sustainable fiscal stance may not be suf-ficient for external sustainability if private sector investment exceeds pri-vate sector savings. Conversely, an unsustainable fiscal deficit may trans-late into a sustainable external position if the balance of private savings minus private investment is positive and compensates for an unsustain-able fiscal deficit. Thus there may be divergence between fiscal and ex-ternal sustainability (Parker and Kastner 1993).

For external debt analysis, all variables (including output) are now ex-pressed in U.S. dollars rather than domestic currency, given the promi-nence in U.S. dollar-denominated debt.5Let us define Dfas the total

for-eign debt stock, which is both public and private; if´ as the average

(11)

capital flows; and DNFAas the change in official reserves and other for-eign assets (with a positive figure denoting an increase in forfor-eign assets), which also includes “exceptional finance.” The basic debt relationship over time is given by the following equation:

Dtf ’= (1 + i

tf ’)Dt–1f ’ – (NICA*t+ Trt) – FIt+ DNFAt. (2.4)

Equation (2.4), which is very similar to equation (2.1), provides the starting point for the analysis. The only difference is that, instead of con-sidering money financing for the fiscal approach, the relationship now is based on the current account financing. The equivalent to equation (2.2) for the fiscal approach is

Ddtf’=

rt f’– g

t’

dtf’–1– nica**

t . (2.5)

1 + gt

The key results are similar to those obtained for the fiscal accounting ap-proach to debt sustainability. As before, the first key factor affecting the ratio of debt to GDP is the difference between the real interest rate on the debt and the real growth rate of GDP. These variables are expressed in equation (2.5) with a tilt to highlight the fact that they are now ex-pressed in dollar terms. For example, the growth rate is now the dollar-denominated growth rate. The second factor is now the adjusted non-interest current account balance. A nonnon-interest current account not financed by non-debt-creating equity flows or changes in the foreign re-serves position feeds into higher external debt, whereas noninterest cur-rent account surpluses can reduce the external debt stock. Thus, if the av-erage interest rate is structurally higher than the GDP growth rate, the debt-to-GDP ratio will rise unless the country runs a sufficiently large noninterest current account surplus. On the other hand, if the growth rate of GDP exceeds the average rate of interest on external debt, keep-ing the debt-to-GDP ratio stable, or even reduckeep-ing it, is compatible with running a current account deficit.

(12)

intro-duced more specifically in the analysis, and the exchange rate effect will depend on the shares of tradable versus nontradable output. The effect will be maximal when tradable output is zero.

Solvency Approach

The accounting approach to DSA enables one to estimate a sustainable fiscal stance at a particular moment in time on the basis of a definition of the fiscal deficit, which refers to the result of a fiscal year and its corre-sponding annual borrowing requirements. However, governments do not finance their expenses entirely with their annual income. Instead, they shift spending between periods to meet annual fiscal targets. To analyze the medium- and long-run sustainability of the fiscal policy, we must con-sider the financing constraint facing the public sector in a long-term dy-namic context. Looking at the government budget constraint from this intertemporal viewpoint introduces the concept of long-term “solvency.” Even if the government faces substantial fiscal deficits and a high (or pos-sibly unsustainable debt-to-GDP ratio) today, the government still can be considered solvent as long as resources generated in the future are suffi-ciently large to cover all future debt-service obligations. The borrower may experience a “liquidity” problem, but lenders should not worry too much about current debt-servicing problems if they are prepared to roll over current debt-servicing obligations. The same type of argument can be made to some extent for the external approach to debt sustainability.

To take this argument into account, the solvency approach to fiscal debt sustainability is based not on nominal debt, but on the present value (PV) of future debt payments. The government can be considered solvent as long as the present value of future resources available for debt servic-ing (DS), as represented by future primary fiscal balances (adjusted for seigniorage,B*), is larger than the present value of all future public debt-servicing obligations (which equals the current public debt stock for bor-rowers at market terms)—in other words, if the government has a posi-tive net worth. The case of an equality between debt-service obligations and future primary fiscal balances is referred to as the “no-Ponzi game” condition.6

(13)

choose the timing for doing so. This framework can be used to calculate the required primary surplus necessary to stabilize the debt-to-output ra-tio, which will depend on the difference between the (real) interest rate and the (real) GDP growth rate. Again, inflation rates and exchange rate (changes) can be introduced into the analysis.

Take PVD and PVB,respectively, to represent the present value (PV) of future debt-service payments (DS) and of future primary fiscal balances (including seigniorage,B*) by discounting these values of DS and B* at the appropriate (real) discount rate,d. As such, public debt can be con-sidered sustainable from a solvency point of view as long as

DSt B*t

PVB(B*,d,p)= ∞∑

t=s[(1+p)(1 +d)]t–s

∞ ∑

t=s[(1+p)(1 +d)]t–s (2.6)

PVB(B*,d,p)= PVD(DS,d,p).

The net worth of a country is simply the difference between the two. The upper bound for the time index of the present value calculation used in determining the solvency constraint is important. Choosing an infinite time horizon enables the country to stay solvent whenever it stabilizes the debt-to-GDP ratio over time, without needing to pay back the debt entirely. The analysis conducted in some of the existing solvency models implies that solvency is ensured only when the rate of growth of the debt-to-output ratio remains below the long-run value of the difference be-tween the real output growth rate and the real interest rate. This implies that the present discounted value of the government debt converges to zero (Cuddington 1997), which is necessary only when working with a solvency concept in a finite time horizon (T instead of ∞).

On a theoretical level, the solvency approach is the appropriate way to look at fiscal sustainability. In practice, however, determining long-term fiscal sustainability using the solvency constraint is difficult in part be-cause estimating the present value of future revenue and expenditure flows is problematic, particularly in LICs. Projecting real rates of growth and real interest rates over the long run also can be very uncertain.7For

(14)

fiscal stance with balance of payments and growth targets. Therefore, from an operational viewpoint, the solvency approach is less useful for debt analysis than other, simpler approaches.

In a similar way to what has just been outlined for fiscal analysis, we could try to evaluate solvency, including the external constraint, by ana-lyzing the relationship between the future external debt-service paths and some indicator of future capacity to generate foreign exchange, such as current account balances or expected growth of exports. Again, how-ever, it has proved difficult to translate this into operational indicators. One interesting example is provided by Cohen (1985), who defined a solvency index that measures the fraction of exports that should be de-voted to repaying the debt in order to satisfy the solvency constraint. In follow-up work, Cohen (1996) estimated that, for African countries, a debt-to-export ratio of about 210 percent should be the threshold at which a country’s debt should be rescheduled. Because this index is based on trade flows only, leaving aside capital movements, it needs to be used with caution. In a situation of massive capital flight, it should be used to-gether with an evaluation of the capital outflows and their possibility of being repatriated while causing liquidity problems.

Concessionality and the Present Value of Debt

(15)

GEt= (DtPVt) D t=

PVt

(2.7)

Dt (1 – GEt).

To look at the dynamics of the GE, define mtas the change in GE over time, with (1 – GEt)/(1 – GEt–1) = 1 – mt.The parameter mis thus equal to zero if the GE of the overall debt stock remains unchanged between two periods, and the parameter is positive (negative) if the GE increases (falls). Using this definition, it can be shown that the change in the ratio of the present value of debt to GDP over time, which is denoted as Dpv,is equal to

Dpv = rtf’– g’t– mt(1 + rtf’)pv

t–1f’ (1 GEt)(nica**t ).

(1 + gt’) (2.8)

There are two main differences between equations (2.5) and (2.8). The first difference is that a higher degree of concessionality (a larger value for GE) relaxes the constraint imposed by the adjusted noninterest current account balance. The second difference is that, if the degree of conces-sionality increases over time, the required growth rate, necessary to en-sure that the debt ratio does not increase, is reduced. Simply stated, a higher degree of concessionality over time reduces the required ability to finance future interest payments through growth. Conversely, for coun-tries whose borrowing becomes less concessional over time (for example, because a country reaches middle-income status and graduates from the International Development Association [IDA]), the required growth rate to ensure sustainability will increase with the drop in concessionality of the loans received.

Equation (2.9) provides the law of motion of the present value debt-to-GDP ratio under the fiscal accounting approach, starting from equa-tion (2.3), which already factored changes in the exchange rate. There is one variable in equation (2.9) that needs to be defined:agbis the net bud-getized grant aid as a ratio of GDP (and b** is the primary balance with-out grants) to single with-out the effect of (budgetized) grant aid on the dy-namics.

Dpv=

r*tgt+ etaf(1 + rtf)(1–mt) – (1 + r*t)mt

(2.9)

(1 + gt)

(16)

As before, a large depreciation that raises the domestic currency value of foreign currency debt can lead to a sharp rise in the debt ratio, even if revenue growth exceeds the interest rate, and the primary balance after grants is in surplus. Thus, substantial changes in the present value debt-to-exports ratio can occur in only a few years, even with a prudent and highly concessional borrowing policy and low fiscal deficits.8In addition,

as was the case with external sustainability, equation (2.9) shows that, in the fiscal approach, changes toward higher concessionality over time will decrease the burden placed on growth to be able to repay loans, and re-duce the impact of variations in the exchange rate because grants do not have to be repaid. In addition, a higher level of grant aid will reduce the financing gap.

It is also worth noting that the external or fiscal financing gap—that is, the second term on the right-hand side of equations (2.8) and (2.9)—is the factor that most directly captures the tension between debt sustain-ability and the need for financing. A fiscal gap is equivalent to the adjust-ed primary deficit after grants, whereas an external gap is definadjust-ed as the adjusted noninterest current account deficit. When a country or govern-ment boosts its investgovern-ment to achieve higher growth and eventually greater poverty reduction, the financing gap rises, as reflected in a larger current account and/or fiscal deficit, unless there is an offsetting fall in domestic public or private consumption. In the absence of higher grants or other nondebt financing, such as debt rescheduling or the buildup of arrears, debt ratios would increase.

In the applied chapters on Paraguay, Guinea, Rwanda, and Senegal in this volume, case studies that rely on the above-mentioned concepts or adaptations of them are provided to reveal the sustainability of various growth and taxation-spending scenarios over time. The debt module of SimSIP (which stands for Simulations for Social Indicators and Poverty) is a simple tool used to perform complex simulations easily. Analysts can use such tools to help governments and other actors identify some simple trade-offs between debt sustainability and key macroeconomic variables involved in the debt dynamics, such as growth, interest rates, inflation rates, and exchange rate changes, as well as fiscal and current account deficits and their impact on antipoverty spending.

(17)

Initiative and the MDRI) taken by donors to reduce the burden of debt service for poor countries.

Operationalizing Debt Sustainability Concepts: The HIPC Initiative

How can the different concepts and indicators of debt sustainability be put together in an operational framework to guide monitoring and deci-sion making on real-world country cases?

Four Steps Necessary to Conduct a DSA

This section sketches four basic steps required to conduct a DSA, and then briefly discusses the HIPC framework adopted by the IMF and the World Bank. The four steps actually draw on what already is operational at the IMF and the World Bank (IMF 2002; IMF and IDA 2005). The steps are as follows:

1. Deciding on the appropriate debt sustainability concepts and indicators. 2. Conducting consistent analysis of the debt dynamics based on the chosen menu of indicators, under a most-likely benchmark scenario, over a medium-to-long-term period.

3. Running stress tests using a number of detailed alternative scenarios, taking into account the most relevant structural vulnerabilities of the economy.

4. Translating debt sustainability into borrowing policies.

The first step involves measuring the selected indicators. One require-ment for this step is an up-to-date and complete database of the country’s debt. This might demand that a lot of technical assistance be given to a debtor country’s debt management offices by the Commonwealth units, the IMF, the United Nations Institute for Training and Research, the World Bank, and the bilateral donor-funded HIPC Capacity Building Pro-gram.9This step also requires country-specific analysis. First, the analysis

(18)

focus more on the present value of debt. Next, one should consider whether to put the focus on debt stock ratios or on debt-service analysis: is it debt overhang or the crowding-out of current resources that is the key constraint? Finally, one should decide whether to focus more on ex-ternal or on fiscal sustainability—that is, whether a country basically is constrained more by foreign exchange issues or by recurrent fiscal gaps, and thereby choose the most appropriate debt indicator denominators (exports, GDP, or government revenues).10

In the second step, when the key constraints are identified and appro-priate indicators are chosen, DSA applies the basic dynamics formulas, such as those derived before, to the current values of the indicators to de-rive their medium-to-long-term evolution. Again, this should be done on the foundation of most-likely base values for the key macroeconomic variables involved in the dynamics. For this, the IMF and the World Bank have designed templates—one for fiscal and one for external debt analy-sis—that can be adjusted to fit a specific country situation. The templates look at the role of endogenous dynamics, as well as the role of primary fis-cal and noninterest current account balances. For LICs, it is important that the dynamics explicitly take into account the importance of bud-getized grants and other non-debt-creating flows, as well as the use of “ex-ceptional financing.”11

Next to highlighting the evolution under a baseline scenario, it is cru-cial to perform the stress tests described in step three to determine the impact of possible shocks and alternative outputs of key macroeconomic variables. Scenarios can be based on historic volatilities or can take into account changed structures and likely new near-future threats (such as the impact of HIV/AIDS) or opportunities as well as needs (such as those related to the MDGs and the increased focus on poverty reduction). Fol-lowing the discussion of the human development approach to debt sus-tainability, a case could be made routinely to include in those stress tests one scenario involving the projected amount of spending needed to meet the MDGs or other similar objectives put forward in the country’s pover-ty reduction strategy.

(19)

sus-tainability in a conventional way and borrowing policies linked to meet-ing poverty reduction and MDG needs. It also is important to note that DSA often has been performed jointly by the IMF and the World Bank on the basis of country input. Now, however, it is growing more common for countries (especially within the HIPC Initiative context) to conduct their own DSAs using the same tools and formulas as the IMF and World Bank use, largely thanks to capacity-building assistance provided.

Debt Sustainability Concepts Used in the HIPC Initiative and the Impact of the Initiative

The best-known operational debt sustainability framework has been the one devised to guide debt relief decisions for the HIPC Initiative. Started in 1996, the initiative explicitly aimed to use the debt relief instruments to reduce to a sustainable level the participating countries’ debt burden. The purpose of this section is not to evaluate the initiative in detail for there is a large body of literature on the topic.12We give only a brief

overview of the framework used.

(20)

It is important to note that the HIPC Initiative framework relies on data concerning external public and publicly guaranteed debt (outstand-ing and disbursed), includ(outstand-ing arrears. This means that domestic debt is not included in the fiscal window.13Similarly, private external debt is not

in-cluded in the external window.14A three-year average is used for

calcu-lating exports (of goods and services). Government revenue is central government revenue, excluding grants. Currency-specific commercial in-terest reference rates are used as discount rates for calculating the present value of the debt. The amount of relief is determined on the basis of a DSA. Note that the debt thresholds used in the Enhanced HIPC Initia-tive are not to be considered as an elaborated framework of debt sustain-ability (IMF 2003). The level of the thresholds was set to provide a cush-ion against external shocks and some safety margin to avoid debt crises.

Recently, the World Bank and the IMF have revised the framework of the Enhanced HIPC Initiative to better tailor DSA and thresholds to country circumstances, and they have broadened this into a forward-look-ing debt sustainability framework for all LICs. Originally, under the En-hanced HIPC Initiative, the thresholds were set at a uniform level for all countries. To provide future-oriented guidance on new borrowing and lending decisions, the new framework adapts the thresholds according to the performance of the countries as measured through the Country Poli-cy and Institutional Assessment (CPIA).15Table 2.1 provides the new

in-dicative thresholds for different levels of policy quality. Furthermore, the new debt sustainability framework adopted by the Bretton Woods

insti-Table 2.1. Debt Sustainability Thresholds and Policy Performance for IDA14 percent

CPIA score

Strong Medium Poor

Debt sustainability indicator (CPIA 3.75) (CPIA 3.25–3.75) (CPIA 3.25)

Present value of debt/GDP 50 40 30

Present value of debt/exports 200 150 100 Present value of debt/revenue 300 250 200

Debt service/exports 25 20 15

Debt service/revenue 35 30 25

Source:IMF and IDA 2005.

[image:20.432.60.378.448.549.2]
(21)

tutions takes into account debt sustainability indicators for determining country allocations within the IDA. Previously, debt sustainability did not enter directly into determining IDA allocation because all IDA credits were in the form of highly concessional loans. Under IDA13 (the 13th re-plenishment), however, donors decided that up to a fixed percentage of IDA allocations could be in the form of grants to reduce future debt bur-dens. More important, IDA14 country allocations include debt sustain-ability issues in a direct way by distributing country allocations between loans and grants, with a higher proportion of grants when debt sustain-ability is more of a concern (IDA 2005a).

Alternative Approaches to Analyzing Debt Sustainability

The policy-making implications of the debt sustainability concepts dis-cussed so far are quite straightforward: debt-service sustainability often requires government action and adjustment at the direct government public budget level (revenue and spending behavior), influencing fiscal balances and/or actions to enhance a country’s capacity to generate for-eign exchange and influencing trade balances and current accounts. At the same time, governments should aim at stimulating economic growth (important also for endogenous debt dynamics), as well as reducing poverty. This very well may lead to situations of inherent conflict, where-by debt service is prioritized and debt sustainability is achieved or main-tained at the expense of growth and/or poverty reduction. Moreover, it may lead to situations in which debt itself acts as an obstacle to growth and poverty alleviation. This difficult trade-off or dilemma has given rise to a number of alternative definitions of or approaches to debt sustain-ability—notably the debt overhang approach and the human develop-ment approach. These alternative approaches are more normative in na-ture than the preceding ones because they more explicitly hint at some optimal debt levels that could be targeted.

Debt Overhang

One alternative way to define debt sustainability refers to the presence of

(22)

sus-tainability could be defined as the level just before debt starts to have a negative impact on economic growth. This level might differ from the debt sustainability thresholds used in traditional fiscal and external ap-proaches because the absence of debt-servicing problems does not neces-sarily mean that there is no negative effect of debt on growth.

Debt overhang occurs when an excessive debt stock introduces nega-tive externalities in the economy beyond the transfer of resources, first on investment and adjustment and then on economic growth. This is be-cause high (current and future) debt transfers lead to anticipation by do-mestic and foreign investors of future higher taxes and increased uncer-tainty, both of which create a disincentive effect on the present investment or adjustment decisions of an indebted country. The concept of “investment” has to be viewed broadly here. It refers to accumulation in human capital—through spending on education and health care—as well as in physical capital, such as machinery and infrastructure. It also captures many types of policy reforms, including structural reforms and macroeconomic stabilization, whose long-term benefits may come at the expense of short-term costs.

(23)

Apart from the investment disincentive effect, debt overhang also will scare off potential new foreign lenders. In the absence of seniority, new loans enter the same pool as old loans and instantly metamorphose into as poor a financial claim as the old loans. Furthermore, as long as the old claims stand undiminished, the new lenders will have to share the fruits of any improved creditworthiness with the old lenders. This depresses the return to the potential new lenders, and keeps them from doing business with the debtor countries. As a consequence, these countries are shunned in international credit markets and cannot borrow as they otherwise could. Some high-yielding investments, which investors would undertake notwithstanding the disincentive effect described earlier, may thus go un-exploited because of a lack of financing (Diwan and Rodrik 1992).

Through those various channels, debt overhang therefore acts as a brake on economic growth, beyond siphoning off public resources for debt service. This line of reasoning then generally is turned into an argu-ment in favor of debt relief because it can be claimed that debt reduction has a more beneficial effect than an equivalent amount of aid injected in a debt-ridden economy. The difference resides in the stimulating effect on the private sector stemming from debt relief, made possible by the reduced foreign claim on future gains. By selecting debt relief, the donor ensures that the proceeds of economic growth remain within the econo-my. Political features also are important: debt relief increases domestic ac-ceptance of austerity because the burden of reforms is perceived to be shared with creditors.

(24)

re-sults from the general dismal state of the economy in some countries where a large debt overhang is just another reflection of the conditions. Results from most early studies using a linear relationship between debt and growth show that the strength of the association between debt and growth varies substantially according to the selection of the debt indica-tor and the model specification. Upon suggestion that this relationship between debt and growth might follow a nonlinear inverted U—that is, following the Laffer curve argument—nonlinear specifications are better. The more recent studies do seem to point to a higher effect of debt on growth. But the magnitude of the effect varies substantially across speci-fications, and it presents large cross-country variation. Patillo, Poirson, and Ricci (2002) showed that the average effect of external debt on growth is negative when the debt stock exceeds 160–170 percent of exports or 35–40 percent of GDP; they also found that the marginal effect of exter-nal debt on growth is negative in a very wide range of 30–115 percent of exports for nominal debt (or 30–295 percent of exports with debt ex-pressed in present value), or between 5 percent and 90 percent for the nominal stock-to-GDP ratio (and between 5 percent and 50 percent for present value of the debt-to-GDP ratio). Patillo, Poirson, and Ricci (2004) showed that this debt overhang effect is stronger in countries with poli-cies and institutions of weak quality, and with lower aid flows. In a way that is similar to the World Bank and IMF framework that will be dis-cussed below, this would call for a country-specific determination of debt sustainability thresholds. Finally, Clements, Bhattacharya, and Nguyen (2004) showed that a substantial reduction in the debt stock for HIPCs is associated with an annual increase of approximately 1.0 percent in per capita income, and that it could accelerate growth indirectly by about 0.5 percent a year in some HIPCs if a substantial percentage of the debt re-lief were directly channeled into public investment. The study also hint-ed that this effect will be largely realizhint-ed when envisaghint-ed HIPC debt re-lief is executed.

Debt Sustainability from a Human Development Perspective

(25)

service, current debt service might crowd out public spending of resources needed to reach substantial poverty reduction or the achievement of the other MDGs. As such, debt sustainability is defined as that level where debt service no longer crowds out MDG-priority public spending. This in-troduces a concept of “affordable” debt service linked to the MDGs, and the notion is translated into an argument in favor of debt relief—prefer-ably in terms of debt-service relief. Clearly, reducing debt service can ben-efit the recurrent expenditure budget directly. In most LICs, if we postu-late the existence of a recurrent-fiscal gap, applying this alternative debt sustainability concept might be very effective in relaxing this gap.

In practice, the approach can be operationalized in many different ways. The crowding-out effect on priority spending by debt service could be minimized by establishing upper limits on debt-service ratios (debt service related to government revenue or GDP). One prominent propos-al propos-along these lines was suggested by Birdspropos-all and Williamson (2002). An-other was pioneered in a Catholic Agency for Overseas Development (CAFOD) article by Northover, Joyner, and Woodward (1998), and ex-tended by Berlage et al. (2003). We describe below the basic algebra of this approach.

The CAFOD proposal works in the following way. Define for each country the tax-revenue base as Y A,where Y is GDP and A is nontax-able income. The proposal suggests taking as A all incomes below the poverty line of $1 a day per person, and then defining the standard rev-enue as equal to a(Y A). This is obtained by applying to Y a standard-tax rate a.The “net feasible revenue” is then the standard revenue minus

B,where B is an allowance for basic human needs. Net feasible revenue measures the government resources available to meet other public expen-ditures, including debt service. When the net feasible revenue is negative, any amount of debt is “unsustainable” and should be cancelled outright. When the net feasible revenue is positive, sustainable debt service is de-fined as an acceptable proportion b of net feasible revenue to be devoted to debt service. Therefore, the sustainable debt service is equal to (b.a) (Y – A) – bB.This can be rewritten as c(Y C), with c = b.a, C* = b.a.A + b.B,

(26)

SDS = c.max [0,Y C]. (2.10)

Instead of computing this on an annual basis, Berlage et al. (2003) turned this into a 15-year scheme (until 2015) to make sure that debt is fully extinguished after 2015 and that it stays sustainable throughout the period by including an insurance scheme. For this, the authors first com-puted net feasible revenue. If negative, the country’s debt is cancelled outright. If positive, one must calculate SDS according to equation (2.7) and go to the next step. That next step consists of multiplying the calcu-lated SDS by 15 to obtain the net present value of debt that will be amor-tized in 15 years by that SDS(using a real discount rate equal to the rate of growth of real GDP). One then compares the result with the country’s net present value of outstanding debt (call it NPV), and retains the lower of the two figures, which can be denoted by NPV*.The corresponding debt service,SDS*,is equal to NPV* divided by 15.

The final step consists of comparing SDS* with SDS.If SDS*= SDS as given by equation (2.6), then by construction it is equal to c(YC). The country benefits from a debt reduction equal to the difference between

NPV and NPV*.For each of the next 15 years (each year being t), the country will transfer into a trust fund (called PAIR) an amount equal to

SDS*t = c.max[0,YtCt]. At the end of the 15 years, no further service will be required on the initially outstanding debt. That debt will be ex-tinct. If SDS* <SDS,the country does not benefit from a debt reduction because its outstanding debt is sustainable. However, it is still desirable to let the country benefit from the embedded insurance mechanism. If we define d = NPV*/NPV (=SDS*/SDS), with d<1, the country’s annual service then will be SDS*t = d.c.max[0,YtCt]. Again, no further service will be required after the year 2015.

Thus, the basic conceptual setup by Northover, Joyner, and Woodward (1998) is to determine the resources needed for the country to attain the MDGs first, and then attempt to achieve them with the resources gener-ated by the public sector in the government budget (on the basis of an objective minimal “tax rate” on GDP, to avoid moral hazard). The afford-able debt service is determined on the basis of the resources left after spending everything needed to achieve the MDGs and other priority spending (rather than de facto prioritizing debt service).

(27)

for-ward such an alternative approach, however, has influenced actual debt relief practices in a more indirect way. Applying this approach has shown that, for a number of countries (although not for all of them), no re-sources would be left for debt service. Related to these proposals are calls for a more “independent” determination of debt sustainability or “insol-vency.”16Finally, the more ethical approach to debt sustainability uses the

concept of odious debt, again to advocate for full debt repudiation (Bird-sall and Williamson 2002, appendix C; Kremer and Jayachandran 2002). Several of these approaches and concepts have been used by advocates, especially within the nongovernmental organization community, to call for full debt cancellation across the board. It can be argued that these ap-proaches have contributed to the international community recently hav-ing granted additional debt relief through the MDRI.

An Explicit MDG Perspective in the MDRI

One requirement of the HIPC Initiative is for participating countries to increase their poverty-reducing expenditure after receiving the debt re-lief. This means that some countries may struggle to meet poverty reduc-tion and MDG goals while maintaining debt sustainability (Fedelino and Kudina 2003). This has been documented by country-case research. Ed-wards provided an interesting example by introducing a model that ex-plicitly considers the role of domestic debt and computes the fiscal policy path that is compatible with aggregate fiscal sustainability (2002b) and with external sustainability (2002a) in the post-HIPC era. Applying the model to the case of Nicaragua illustrates the challenges in the post-HIPC period. Under a reasonable set of assumptions regarding future GDP growth, concessional loans, and donations, the required fiscal adjustment appears to be severe and threatens to jeopardize implementation of the country’s poverty reduction strategy. Such case studies and, more gener-ally, some countries’ continued difficulty in remaining on a sustainable debt path even after implementing the HIPC Initiative have reinforced the call for a broadened framework. It was this call that became the basis for the additional debt relief granted in the MDRI.

(28)

HIPC Initiative. Later, this proposal became officially referred to as the Multilateral Debt Relief Initiative. Since then, the governing boards of these institutions have responded positively to the proposal, and imple-mentation has started.17

This additional debt relief is limited to post–completion point HIPC Initiative countries,18and its purpose was not to allow countries to regain

debt sustainability in a conventional sense because, in principle, HIPC debt relief already had achieved this. As such, at least in theory, MDRI debt cancellation refers explicitly to a human development type of debt sustainability concept, linking the debt relief explicitly to the need to pro-vide additional resources to selected LICs to meet the MDGs. The entry conditions for the recipient countries refer to (1) broad macroeconomic stability, (2) overall commitment by the recipient government to imple-ment a poverty alleviation strategy in the framework of the PRSP initia-tive, and (3) a minimal quality of public expenditure management in the recipient country. These requirements should facilitate the use of the resources freed by this additional debt cancellation for expenditures that actually further the MDGs or similar objectives put forward in the coun-try’s PRSP.

As of the date of writing, all completion point HIPC countries have been benefiting from the MDRI (as have two non-HIPCs, Cambodia and Tajikistan, which receive only additional IMF debt relief). This has re-sulted not only in close to $19 billion19in additional debt relief in

pres-ent value terms, but also in a considerable reduction in the recipipres-ent country’s debt sustainability indicators. One concern among donors is that this reduction in debt ratios might trigger a new buildup of debt in the future, posing additional challenges to the forward-looking debt sus-tainability framework for LICs in place (see IMF and World Bank 2006).

Conclusion

(29)

sub-stantial amounts of official grants that reduce the foreign exchange gap and supplement domestically generated government revenues, and there-by relax the fiscal gap and, potentially, the recurrent-fiscal gap. This is more the case when grants are in the form of budget support and when fungibility of spending is not hampered by earmarked aid flows. On the other hand, given its relative importance in the government budget, aid uncertainty and volatility may complicate debt sustainability analysis.

LICs also receive sometimes highly concessional official financing apart from grants. This makes it more likely that the return on investment does exceed its cost, and the debt dynamic is sustainable. It also introduces a potentially large difference between the nominal debt stock (book value) and the present value of future debt service, and it increases the appeal of looking at debt sustainability indicators based on present value concepts of debt. Some LICs often rely on substantial amounts of exceptional fi-nancing to cover both fiscal and foreign exchange gaps. Exceptional financing refers here particularly to the use of arrears on (external) debt, debt rescheduling, and/or debt forgiveness (possibly including noncon-cessional IMF lending).20Also, government’s use of domestic debt to

fi-nance fiscal gaps generally is limited in LICs, even if domestic debt mar-kets are developing rapidly in some countries. Moreover, private sector external debt generally is limited. Given all these factors, LICs typically experience a large vulnerability to external shocks of all kinds. Therefore, it is important to look for mechanisms that may link debt service more explicitly to the capacity to pay.

(30)

serv-icing problems from those that have not, regardless of the measures that were used.

The empirical studies using these frameworks rely on limited depend-ent variable models, such as discriminant analysis or logit and probit analysis; or on more sophisticated methods, such as binary recursive trees (as in Manasse and Roubini 2005). When judged against the target of pro-viding unified, absolute thresholds, the success of these models to date has been fairly modest. Results typically are being used as guiding values rather than as absolute threshold values, especially when determining debt sustainability on the basis of one or a few indicators only. This conclusion was reaffirmed by recent analysis (Kraay and Nehru 2006). The authors started from a novel way of defining a problem situation of debt sustain-ability, labeled “debt distress,” and configured it as a situation in which a country resorts to exceptional finance in any of three forms: (1) building significant arrears on external debt; (2) rescheduling the debt, notably in the Paris Club; and (3) using nonconcessional IMF lending. Using probit analysis, they showed that cross-country and time variations in the inci-dence of debt distress are explained not only by debt burden indicators but also by differences in the quality of institutions and policy (for exam-ple, as measured by the World Bank’s CPIA Index), and by vulnerability to external shocks. IMF analysis basically has confirmed those results, which have directly fed into the new forward-looking debt sustainability framework of the IMF and the World Bank (IMF and IDA 2005; IMF and World Bank 2006). Indicative threshold values, however, have been and will continue to be used in operational work.

(31)

Beyond the issue of the choice of indicators for DSA, what ultimately matters for policy is trying to assess how much “fiscal space” a country has to pay for public spending and what its sources of financing could be without compromising the country’s solvency in the long run. The con-cept of fiscal space, which is broader than that of debt sustainability, refers to a government’s ability to undertake spending without impairing its solvency—that is, without compromising its present and future ability to service its debt (Heller 2005). In recent years, this concept has emerged as an important subject for debate in the international commu-nity. It was used initially to advocate for traditional fiscal deficit targets not limiting the ability of a government to finance growth-enhancing projects. More broadly, it refers to any constraints to particular public ex-penditures that could lead to higher growth and better achievements of poverty reduction and social goals, such as the MDGs. Fiscal space can be created by improving the effectiveness of public expenditure, increasing fiscal revenues, mobilizing grant aid, and/or issuing new internal or exter-nal debt. A country thus can create fiscal space within or outside its exist-ing borrowexist-ing parameters.

(32)

Notes

1. A fiscal gap is a special subcategory of the savings gap. Its existence assumes that it is impossible to transfer the private savings slack into budgetary re-sources either by increased taxation or by the inflation tax. Otherwise, there can be only one overall savings gap.

2. As the abstract of Ley’s article nicely states, there is “nothing new here—just a concise yet detailed presentation of the simple but inexorable algebra of sus-tainability.”

3. See Borensztein and Mauro (2004) for an extensive analysis in favor of issu-ing GDP-linked debt, and the comment to their proposal by Claessens (Borensztein and Mauro 2004, pp. 208–10) that focuses mainly on practical difficulties. Other recent proposals focus on the establishment of a new IMF facility to provide insurance or contingency financing to protect against these shocks.

4. There is actually a small body of related literature on the concept of “original sin”—that is, a situation in which the domestic currency cannot be used to borrow abroad and sometimes even domestically (see Eichengreen and Haus-mann 1999). Proposals to allow countries to borrow abroad in domestic cur-rency are discussed in Hausmann and Rigobon (2003).

5. For some Francophone African countries, one might use the euro instead. 6. For detailed solvency constraint models, see Agénor and Montiel (1996). 7. Although many economists view “net worth” as the right fiscal concept to

fo-cus on, most of them agree that it is difficult to measure. Easterly (1999) has tested empirically the implications of a fiscal model introducing the net worth concept, but has not provided an operational estimate of this variable, given existing difficulties.

8. A notable example is the situation that exists in Uganda. For more informa-tion, see IMF (2003, p. 26).

9. For an early review of the program, see IDA and IMF (2002).

10. Simple indicators, such as the exports-to-GDP ratio (c) or the government revenues-to-GDP ratio (r), can help a lot in determining the key constraints: low values (relative to group averages) on these simple indicators already de-tect a key vulnerability. For an application in Bolivia, see IMF (2003, p. 23). 11. The templates together with country applications can be found at the World

(33)

12. For detailed reviews, see Birdsall and Williamson (2002), Gunter (2002), World Bank (2003, 2006a), Sun (2004), UNCTAD (2004), Chauvin and Kraay (2005, 2006), and IDA and IMF (2006).

13. Exclusion of domestic debt is consistent with the treatment by the Paris Club, and it is explained by the difficulties involved in including in the analysis the HIPCs’ rather narrow internal financial markets.

14. Hjertholm (2003) has shown that the thresholds used for the two windows are not analytically comparable.

15. Beginning in 2005, the CPIA is fully disclosed, and it has been renamed the IDA Resource Allocation Index.

16. These proposals generally are known as referring to a “fair and transparent arbitration procedure.” For an early proposal along these lines, based on the internationalization of the U.S. Bankruptcy Code, see Raffer (1990); for a more recent proposal, see Sachs (2002).

17. For details, see African Development Bank Group (2006), IMF (2006), and IDA (2005b), respectively. See especially IDA and IMF (2006) for an overview of the current status of implementation. Recently, the Inter-American Devel-opment Bank also decided to join the MDRI and grant additional debt relief to its post-HIPCs.

18. An exception to this limitation is IMF debt relief for which LICs with a per capita annual income of less than $380 also qualify (IMF 2006).

19. A billion is 1,000 millions.

20. The extensive use of exceptional financing itself can be used as an indicator to identify unsustainable debt. Kraay and Nehru (2006) denoted this as “debt distress” and used the concept to derive sustainable debt thresholds.

References

African Development Bank Group. 2006. “Multilateral Debt Relief Initiative by the African Development Fund—At a Glance.” http://www.afdb.org.

Agénor, Pierre-Richard, and Peter J. Montiel. 1996.Development Macroeconomics.

Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

(34)

Berlage, Lode, Danny Cassimon, Jacques Drèze, and Paul Reding. 2003. “Prospec-tive Aid and Indebtedness Relief: A Proposal.”World Development31 (10): 1635–54.

Birdsall, Nancy, and John Williamson. 2002.Delivering on Debt Relief: From IMF Gold to a New Development Architecture.Washington, DC: Center for Global Development and Institute for International Economics.

Borensztein, Eduardo, and Pablo Mauro. 2004. “The Case for GDP-indexed Bonds.”Economic Policy 19 (38): 165–216.

Buiter, Willem, and Urjit Patel. 1992. “Debt, Deficits, and Inflation: An Application to the Public Finances of India.”Journal of Public Economics47: 171–205. Chauvin, Nicolas D., and Aart Kraay. 2005. “What Has 100 Billion Dollars Worth

of Debt Relief Done for Low-Income Countries?” Photocopy. World Bank, Washington, DC. http://econ.worldbank.org/staff/akraay.

———. 2006. “Who Gets Debt Relief?” Discussion Paper 4000, World Bank, Washington, DC.

Claessens, Stijn. 1990. “The Debt Laffer Curve: Some Estimates.”World Develop-ment18 (12): 1671–77.

Clements, Benedict, Rina Bhattacharya, and Toan Quoc Nguyen. 2004. “External Debt, Public Investment, and Growth in Low-Income Countries.” In Helping Countries Develop: The Role of Fiscal Policy,ed. S. Gupta, B. Clements, and B. In-chauste, 105–29. Washington. DC: International Monetary Fund.

Cohen, Daniel. 1985. “How to Evaluate the Solvency of an Indebted Nation.” Eco-nomic Policy1: 139–67.

———. 1991.Private Lending to Sovereign States: A Theoretical Autopsy.Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

———. 1996. “The Sustainability of African Debt.” Policy Research Working Paper 1621, World Bank, Washington, DC.

Cuddington, John T. 1997. “Analyzing the Sustainability of Fiscal Deficits in De-veloping Countries.” Policy Research Working Paper 1784, World Bank, Wash-ington, DC.

Diwan, Ishac, and Dani Rodrik. 1992. “External Debt, Adjustment, and Burden Sharing: A Unified Framework.”Princeton Studies in International Economics73. Easterly, William. 1999. “When Is Fiscal Adjustment an Illusion?”Economic Policy

14 (28): 57–86.

(35)

———. 2002b. “Debt Relief and Fiscal Sustainability.” Working Paper 8939, Na-tional Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.

Eichengreen, Barry, and Ricardo Hausmann. 1999. “Exchange Rates and Financial Fragility.” Working Paper 7418, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cam-bridge, MA.

EURODAD (European Network for Debt and Development). 2001. “Putting Poverty First.” http://www.eurodad.org.

Fedelino, Annalisa, and Anna Kudina. 2003. “Fiscal Sustainability in African HIPC Countries: A Policy Dilemma?” Working Paper WP/03/187, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.

Gunter, Bernhard G. 2002.”What’s Wrong with the HIPC Initiative and What’s Next?”Development Policy Review20 (1): 5–24.

Haque, Nadeem Ul, and Peter Montiel. 1994. “Pakistan: Fiscal Sustainability and Macroeconomic Policy.” In Public Sector Deficits and Macroeconomic Perfor-mance,ed. W. Easterly, C. Rodriguez, and K. Schmidt-Hebbel, 413–57. New York: Oxford University Press.

Hausmann, Ricardo, and Roberto Rigobon. 2003. “IDA in UF: On the Benefits of Changing the Currency Denomination of Concessional Lending to Low-Income Countries.” http://ksghome.harvard.edu/~rhausma/new/Hausmann RigobonWBOS.pdf.

Heller, Peter S. 2005. “Understanding Fiscal Space.” Policy Discussion Paper PDP/05/4, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.

Hjertholm, Peter. 2003. “Theoretical and Empirical Foundations of HIPC Debt Sustainability Targets.”Journal of Development Studies39 (6): 67–100. IDA (International Development Association). 2005a. “Additions to IDA

Re-sources: Fourteenth Replenishment—Working Together to Achieve the Mil-lennium Development Goals.” Report from the Executive Directors of IDA to the Board of Governors, March.

———. 2005b. “The Multilateral Debt Relief Initiative: Implementation Modali-ties for IDA.” November 18.

IDA and IMF (International Monetary Fund). 2002. “External Debt Management in Heavily Indebted Poor Countries (HIPCs).” Washington, DC. http://www. imf.org/external/np/hipc/2002/edm/032102.htm.

———. 2006.”Heavily Indebted Poor Countries (HIPC) Initiative and Multilateral Debt Relief Initiative (MDRI)—Status of Implementation.” August. Washing-ton, DC.

(36)

———. 2003. “Debt Sustainability in Low-Income Countries—Towards a For-ward-looking Strategy.” Policy Development and Review Department, Wash-ington, DC.

———. 2006.“A Factsheet:The Multilateral Debt Relief Initiative.”Washington, DC. IMF and IDA. 2005. “Operational Framework for Debt Sustainability Assessments

in Low-Income Countries—Further Considerations.” Washington, DC. IMF and World Bank. 2006. “Review of Low-Income Country Debt Sustainability

Framework and Implications of the MDRI.” Washington, DC.

Kraay, Aart, and Vikram Nehru. 2006. “When Is External Debt Sustainable.”World Bank Economic Review20 (3): 341–65.

Kremer, Michael, and Seema Jayachandran. 2002. “Odious Debt.” Policy Brief 103, Brookings Institution, Washington, DC.

Krugman, Paul. 1988. “Financing versus Forgiving a Debt Overhang.”Journal of De-velopment Economics29 (3): 253–68.

Ley, Eduardo. 2004. “Fiscal (and External) Sustainability.” http://econwpa.wu stl.edu:80/eps/pe/papers/0310/0310007.pdf, December 2004 version. Manasse, Pablo, and Nouriel Roubini. 2005. “‘Rules of Thumb’ for Sovereign

Debt Crises.” Working Paper WP/05/42, International Monetary Fund, Wash-ington, DC.

Northover, Henry, Karen Joyner, and David Woodward. 1998. “A Human Develop-ment Approach to Debt Sustainability for the World’s Poor.” Catholic Agency for Overseas Development, London.

Parker, Karen, and Steffen Kastner. 1993. “A Framework for Assessing Fiscal Sus-tainability and External Viability, with an Application to India.” Working Paper 93/78, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.

Patillo, Catherine, Helène Poirson, and Luca Ricci. 2002. “External Debt and Growth.” Working Paper WP/02/69, International Monetary Fund, Washing-ton, DC.

———. 2004. “What Are the Channels Through Which External Debt Affects Growth?” Working Paper WP/04/15, International Monetary Fund, Washing-ton, DC.

Raffer, Kunibert. 1990. “Applying Chapter 9 Insolvency to International Debts: An Economically Efficient Solution with a Human Face.”World Development

18 (2): 301–11.

Sachs, Jeffrey D. 2002. “Resolving the Debt Crisis of Low-Income Countries.”

Brookings Papers on Economic Activity2002 (1): 257–86.

(37)

UNCTAD (United Nations Conference on Trade and Development). 2004. “Debt Sustainability: Oasis or Mirage?” Geneva.

World Bank. 2003. “The Heavily Indebted Poor Countries (HIPC) Debt Initiative. An OED Review.” Operations Evaluation Department, World Bank, Washing-ton, DC.

———. 2006a. “Debt Relief for the Poorest: An Evaluation Update of the HIPC Initiative.” Independent Evaluation Group, World Bank, Washington, DC. ———. 2006b. “How to Do a Debt Sustainability Analysis for Low-Income

Figure

Table 2.1. Debt Sustainability Thresholds and Policy Performance for IDA14

References

Related documents

WALL CONTROL BLACK WIRE 120 VAC HOT BLACK WIRE WALL CONTROL WIRE CONNECTOR TO 120VAC SOURCE HOT TO FAN MOTOR LOAD Figure 24 6.8.. Securely connect the GREEN ground wire from

Irrigation with outflow water from an undiluted inflow wetland filter significantly ( p &lt; 0.05) increased soil total coliform levels compared with those of diluted inflow

U ovome radu razmatrana je tema problema mentalnog zdravlja kod studenata. Radi boljeg razumijevanja teme, najprije su obrađene definicije zdravlja, mentalnog zdravlja i

For in-situ testing, the primary test method references in BS EN 1997-2:2007 are to new CEN /ISO standards and this will require the withdrawal of some sections of BS

convex A set is called convex if the connecting line between any two points in the set is also in the set; a function is called convex if the connecting line between any two points

Recurrent neural network (RNN) is one powerful method to extract and update the correlations of sequential data, owing to its structure by augmenting recurrent links to hidden

When interpreted the findings of two applications of the TPACK Survey, TPACK levels of Turkish teacher candidates who participated in the study have been differentiated

We have generated a GRS for CHD based on 49 310 SNPs and, using three prospective FINRISK and two FHS prospective cohorts, dem- onstrated that the GRS is associated with incident