• No results found

Payroll Taxes, Social Insurance and Business Cycles

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Payroll Taxes, Social Insurance and Business Cycles"

Copied!
42
0
0

Loading.... (view fulltext now)

Full text

(1)

The University of Adelaide

School of Economics

Research Paper No. 2010-17

August 2010

Payroll Taxes, Social Insurance and Business

Cycles

(2)

Payroll Taxes, Social Insurance and Business

Cycles

Michael C. Burda

Humboldt Universit•

at zu Berlin

10099 Berlin

Germany

Mark Weder

University of Adelaide

Adelaide SA 5005

Australia

August 20, 2010

Abstract

Payroll taxes represent a major distortionary in uence of govern-ments on labor markets. This paper examines the role of payroll taxa-tion and the social safety net for cyclical uctuataxa-tions in a nonmonetary economy with labor market frictions and unemployment insurance, when the latter is only imperfectly related to search e ort. A bal-anced social insurance budget renders gross wages more rigid over the cycle and, as a result, strengthens the model's endogenous propaga-tion mechanism. For convenpropaga-tional calibrapropaga-tions, the model generates a negatively sloped Beveridge curve as well as substantial volatility and persistence of vacancies and unemployment.

Keywords: Business cycles, labor markets, payroll taxes, unemployment, consumption-tightness puzzle. JEL Classi cation: E24, J64, E32. We are grateful to Chris Ed-mond, Francisco Gonzalez, Bob Gregory, Dan Hamermesh, Tom Krebs, Nir Jaimovich, Ian McLean, Christian Merkl, Alex Meyer-Gohde, Bruce Preston, Dennis Snower, Lutz Weinke, Jake Wong and to seminar participants at ANU, Humboldt, Kiel, Mannheim, Melbourne, Utrecht, EALE/SOLE 2010 and SED 2010 for very useful comments. Patrick Bunk, Hong Lan and Susanne Sch•oneberg provided excellent research assistance. The au-thors acknowledge generous support from the Alexander von Humboldt Foundation, the Netherlands Institute of Advanced Study, and the Collaborative Research Center 649 of the German Science Foundation.

(3)

1

Introduction

Payroll taxes represent a major in uence of governments on labor markets. In 2005, OECD member governments collected about $3 trillion from em-ployers and employees, representing 9:2 percent of GDP and, given a wage share of two-thirds, roughly 15 percent of the total wage bill. In some Eu-ropean countries, the share of "contributions to social insurance" in total

compensation is as high as 40 to 45 percent.1 Payroll taxes drive a wedge

between the hiring decisions of rm and the labor supply decisions of house-holds, and are likely to spur the untaxed, informal economy. A less-studied aspect is the e ect of time-varying labor taxation on intertemporal decisions of employers and employees. Not only do payroll taxes impact the long-run functioning of labor markets and the macroeconomy, but they may also a ect the magnitude and persistence of business cycle uctuations.

This paper investigates the interaction of payroll taxes, the social insur-ance system and the business cycle. We begin with an empirical examination

of the cyclical behavior of payroll taxation. We nd evidence that payroll

taxation is countercyclical in a number of OECD countries: employer and em-ployee contributions to social insurance, measured relative to the total wage bill, tend to fall in recoveries and rise in recessions. This countercyclical labor tax burden arises for at least two reasons. First, most OECD governments rely on payroll taxation to fund their social welfare systems, sometimes on a near-balanced budget basis. Second, payroll taxation is usually capped, implying a relatively higher e ective rate of taxation for low-productivity workers at the extensive margin.

Next, we study the e ects of countercyclical payroll taxation in an equi-librium business cycle model with labor market frictions. We show that in

(4)

this class of models, the elasticity of search activity on both sides of the market is in uenced by the intertemporal path of the wedge between costs paid by rms and income received by households. The endogeneity of the tax burden to cyclical conditions reinforces the intertemporal response of labor market activity and thus increases the endogenous propagation of shocks in the model economy. By distinguishing between search and leisure, we ac-count for the possibility that non-working time is not used for active search and create an additional margin for time use. There are two other features central to the model: unemployment bene ts are nanced by payroll taxation on a balanced budget basis and unemployment bene t provision is only

im-perfectly related to search e ort.2 This latter is due to the extent of general

social welfare in the model economy, which is can be thought of as "Type II" classi cation error { paying unemployment bene ts to those in fact taking leisure. Combined with the endogeneity of labor taxation, these e ects sig-ni cantly distort the labor-search-leisure decision and increase the internal propagation of the model economy.

Although models with labor market frictions have proliferated in recent years, Shimer (2005) and Hall (2005) showed that they generally do not generate su cient volatility and persistence in labor market quantities, i.e. vacancies and unemployment. They argue that wage rigidity is the most promising solution to the puzzle. To this end, Hagedorn and Manovskii (2008) raise the fallback position and lower the bargaining power of workers in wage bargaining (see also Cole and Rogerson, 1999), while Gertler and Tri-gari (2009) employ overlapping Nash-bargained wage contracts. Hornstein, Krusell and Violante (2005) and Costain and Reiter (2008) and show that these approaches, however successful, can generate a number of unwanted

2Tripier (2003), Ravn (2008) and Ebell (2009) examine similar setups, but they do

not examine the impact of unemployment bene t on the search-leisure margin and do not consider unemployment bene ts nanced by distortionary payroll taxation.

(5)

side e ects.3 Ravn (2008) shows that with endogenous participation, the

search model predicts a counterfactual positively-sloped Beveridge relation and procyclial unemployment.

The central nding of this paper is that the interaction of endogenous

payroll taxation with the social insurance system can reduce the volatility of gross labor costs in a real equilibrium business cycle model and match key macro stylized facts, which include persistence in vacancies, high cyclical volatility of labor market quantities, and negative correlation of vacancies and unemployment (the Beveridge curve). Time-varying payroll taxes a ect the both cost of labor and the value of vacancies to the rm, as well as the value of time spent by workers in search. This intertemporal e ect of taxes on equilibrium models of unemployment is also a novel nding.

In Section 2, we document the level and intertemporal behavior of pay-roll taxes in the major OECD countries. For a number of Western European economies (Finland, France, and Germany in particular), e ective payroll taxes are signi cantly countercyclical; in the United States, a similar pattern has also emerged in the last two decades. Section 3 lays out a nonmonetary dynamic stochastic general equilibrium economy with a social insurance sys-tem, unemployment bene ts and endogenous search. The model is calibrated

in Section 4, while Section 5 presents our central nding: a

productivity-driven real equilibrium economy with search frictions can account for labor market facts and generate a pattern of countercyclical payroll tax burdens observed in many OECD countries. Robustness checks and more detailed interpretation of the results are laid out in Section 6. Section 7 concludes.

3Sticky wages are not easy to nd in the data (Bils 1985), and the standard model

predicts a counterfactually strong negative correlation between the labor share and labor productivity. Hall and Milgrom (2008) note that high values of fallback induce unrealis-tically high elasticities of labor supply response. More recent work by Shimer (2009) and others show how intratemporal non-separability in utility over consumption and nonwork can induce similar e ects.

(6)

2

Payroll taxes in the OECD

2.1

Magnitude of payroll taxes

Payroll taxation represents a signi cant, yet frequently overlooked interven-tion in labor markets in developed economies. In 2008, the total contribuinterven-tion of households and enterprises to social security (i.e. payroll taxes) repre-sented 33.7 percent of total compensation in Germany and 25.2 percent in Sweden, as compared with 11.3 percent in the United States. Table 1 re-ports a longer-term perspective on payroll taxation. The payroll tax rate ( ) is de ned as the ratio of all "contributions to social insurance" divided by total compensation of employees, and represents the average burden posed by payroll taxes and other social contributions as a fraction of total labor costs paid by rms. Our data are taken from the OECD Economic Outlook and Main Economic Indicators databases. Contributions to social insurance consist of payments by rms or employees for pension, health, unemployment and disability insurance, and some other minor elements of social insurance. Total compensation is de ned as gross wages, salaries and other payments made by employers on behalf of their employees. The rst two columns of the table document levels and trends of payroll taxation in countries for which longer time series are available.

The average e ective payroll tax rate thus varies widely in OECD coun-tries, ranging from 5-15% of the wage bill in Canada, the US and Finland to 30% or more in France, Germany and Sweden. As evident from Figures 1 and 2, they also vary over time. Over the four decades of data available, average taxes have risen secularly in almost all countries. At the same time,

they uctuate around their respective trends, with standard deviations of

less than 0.2 percentage points in the US and Canada to more than 0.6% in Sweden, France, Finland, Greece, and the Netherlands. Such uctuations of

(7)

tax burdens are likely to important for labor markets, not only in continental Europe, but also in the United States.

Table 1: Payroll taxes in OECD countries

Ratio of payroll taxes Correlation of payroll tax rate

Country to total compensation with GDP*

1970-89 1990-08 1970:1-89:4 1990:1-08:4 1970:1-08:4 US 0.10 0.12 0.23 -0.28 0.15 Germany 0.28 0.34 -0.48 -0.56 -0.51 Netherlands 0.29 0.29 -0.13 -0.03 -0.10 UK 0.23 0.26 0.12 0.04 0.10 Sweden 0.25 0.32 -0.42 0.36 0.09 France 0.37 0.41 -0.04 -0.39 -0.23 Japan 0.17 0.24 -0.39 -0.10 -0.26 Canada 0.06 0.09 -0.27 -0.07 -0.21 Finland 0.14 0.17 -0.53 -0.48 -0.47

Source: OECD, authors' calculations based on quarterly data

*Real GDP and tax rates are HP- ltered with smoothing parameter =1600.

2.2

Function of payroll taxes

Payroll taxes are primarily used to fund social security systems. This con-cept of social insurance dates to social reforms in late-nineteenth century Germany, which served as a model for many industrial countries, including

the United States.4 This type of social system is characterized by a relatively

4In an e ort to de ect criticism of rising inequality in a time of rapid growth,

Chancel-lor Bismarck initiated wide-reaching reforms during the 1880s,culminating in the Health Insurance Act of 1883 (Gesetz betre end die Krankenversicherung der Arbeiter), the Ac-cident Insurance Act of 1884 (Unfallversicherungsgesetz) and the Old Age and Disability Insurance Act of 1889 (Gesetz betre end der Invalidit•ats- und Altersversicherung). These were important rst pillars of the current German social insurance system, which were augmented in 1927 by the Law on Employment and Unemployment Insurance (Gesetz •

(8)

low level of explicit redistribution; health, pension, and unemployment in-surance funds are established to honor entitlements based on past service or accrued eligibility. In theory, workers and rms contribute towards the costs of social insurance programs, which run on a near-balanced budget basis. Funding of such programs is thus susceptible to business cycle uctuations, with cyclical adjustments often required to bring contributions in line with outlays.

As a representative example, consider Germany's current system of un-employment bene ts, which was established in 1969 by the Employment

Promotion Act (Arbeitsf•orderungsgesetz). This law set up the Federal

Em-ployment Agency (Bundesagentur f•ur Arbeit) to provide income support for

unemployed as well as training and support in job nding and matching.

The activities of the agency are funded primarily by payroll tax contribu-tions. The government provides stop-gap assistance only under exceptional circumstances in the form of interest-free liquidity loans, which are generally repaid as soon as income exceeds spending in any given month. As a result, contribution rates vary considerably over time and are often reduced in times

of stronger economic growth, and raised in recessions.5 Similar funding

prin-ciples apply to other pillars of the social security system (health, pension, disability, old-age care, etc.).

The Bismarckian system stands in contrast to the concept of social in-surance promoted by Beveridge in the late 1940s and based on the notion of a su cient minimum bene t to be funded by the general public budget if necessary. In many European countries, de cits in social security programs

5In the period 2007-2009, for example, the statutory contribution rate for the German

unemployment insurance scheme decreased from 6.5 percent of gross eligible wage income to 2.8 percent. In the recession which followed, tax increases for unemployment insurance were avoided only by a discretionary expansion of the short-time work program, which exempts employees from social insurance contributions.

(9)

are regularly covered by budgetary transfers. The social security system of old-age bene ts in the United States combines Bismarckian and Beveridgean elements. It is funded by payroll taxes, with employers withholding 6.2% of employee wages and matching that amount in employer social security taxes until total earnings reach a xed earnings base (ceiling) for the year. above which no further tax is levied. Romer and Romer (2009) document that US Social Security tax increases tend to be preprogrammed and follow increases in bene ts, either in the form of increasing statutory rates or increases in the payroll tax base.

2.3

Cyclical behavior of payroll taxes

For at least two reasons, the average payroll tax rate - and thus the tax

burden for the representative worker moving from unemployment into em-ployment - is likely to be countercyclical. In recessions, budget shortfalls are di cult to close, especially when social expenditures have the nature of entitlements. As a result, tax rates may be raised in recessions and cut in expansions. While we focus on unemployment insurance and welfare bene-ts, countercyclical funding issues arise in systems of health services, public pensions and social programs in general. A second reason for countercycli-cal payroll tax rates is the truncated nature of payroll tax systems in most OECD countries, in which a cap on contributions limits total tax liability

of employers for a given employee.6 In expansions, when overall wages and

productivity are rising, more workers will earn gross pay exceeding the con-tributions cap, while in recessions, new jobs tend to pay less.

6In the United States, the ceiling on social security contributions, which is adjusted

annually for in ation, was $102,000 in 2008. This represents the roughly the 85th percentile of the annual grosshouseholdincome distribution in the US. In Germany, the ceiling was 5300 Euro per month in 2008. At the lower end of the pay spectrum, so-calledMini-Jobs

(de ned as jobs that pay less than 400 Euro per month) face a signi cantly lower payroll tax.

(10)

Figures 3 and 4 and the last three columns of Table 1 document that the

average e ective payroll tax rate ( t) is not constant. In fact, it is strongly

countercyclical in Germany, France, and the Netherlands, while less so in Sweden, the UK and the United States. To remove low frequency move-ments in the data, we applied the HP- lter to the payroll tax and real GDP series. The overall contemporaneous correlation of the payroll tax rate and

the business cycle in the period 1990-2008 was 0:56 in Germany, 0:39

in France, and 0:48 in Finland. While payroll taxation is acyclical in the

United States over the entire period, it has become more negatively correlated

with the cycle over the last two decades.7 Our nding is consistent with the

conclusion of the business cycle accounting literature and its concept of the "labor wedge" (see Chari, Kehoe and McGrattan, 2008), although researchers in this area have tended to focus on distortions based on government reg-ulation and other market imperfections. Rogerson and Shimer (2010) and Shimer (2009) argue that the labor wedge moves countercyclically, that is,

in the same direction as our payroll tax measure.8

Figures 1, 2, 3, and 4 about here

Evidently, policy can in uence the sign of this correlation by breaking the rigid link between payroll taxation and the business cycle which results from a balanced budget rule. Already in the 1930s, Kaldor (1936) and Meade (1938) proposed setting payroll taxes to covary positively with the state of the economy, and their ideas were endorsed by Keynes (1942) and Beveridge (1944). In smaller, open OECD countries such as the Netherlands and Swe-den, discretionary policy seems to have reduced the anticyclicality of payroll

7This nding is not an artifact of the detrending procedure. With rst-di erenced data,

the correlation in the US declines over the two subperiods from 0.36 to -0.48.

8The correlation between HP-detrended versions of Shimer's (2009) wedge measure and

our average payroll tax rate is 0.52 for the period 1990-2006 (for the period 1970-2006 it is only 0.10).

(11)

taxes or even made them procyclical. The increasing countercyclical behav-ior of the US payroll tax rate may also be due to increasing procyclicality in

both levels and variance of wages, given the contributions cap.9

In the next section, we examine the e ect of payroll taxation in a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model of the business cycle with labor mar-ket frictions along the lines of Tripier (2003), Veracierto (2008), and Ravn (2008), to which systems of unemployment bene ts and social assistance funded by distortionary labor taxation are added. To emphasize the e ects on dynamics, we will study the extreme case of a balanced-budget version of the model, in which payroll taxes are set passively by the government to fund unemployment bene t and social assistance payments due each period.

3

An equilibrium business cycle model with

payroll taxation

3.1

Labor market search

Subscripts refer to periods of discrete timet 0:The economy is populated

by a large number of in nitely-lived, identical consumer-worker households of measure one. Each household consists of a large number of individuals who derive utility from consumption and leisure. Workers (or family members) can spend their nonworking time in active unemployment (i.e., searching) or in leisure. If we normalize non-sleeping time to unity, the representative agent faces the following time budget:

ht+st+`t = 1 (1)

where ht, st, and `t are working time, search time, and leisure (which could

include home production). The threefold use of time re ects our interest in

(12)

the distinction between search and voluntary unemployment and its inter-action with labor market interventions described above: payroll taxes and

social insurance.10 Governments payroll tax receipts are used to subsidize

search (unemployment bene ts) and leisure (social welfare payments).

Workers and jobs search for each other in a decentralized labor market.11

Matching is modeled as a constant returns function of workers' search

ac-tivities, st, and rms' posted vacancies, vt, in the form of a matching

func-tion, M(st; vt) = stv

1

t . At the same time, lled jobs are broken up each

period at a constant rate, h, with 0 < h < 1.12 In the absence of

on-the-job search, the vacancy-unemployment ratio t vt=st is a su cient

statistic of market tightness. The vacancy placement rate qt, is linked to

the job- nding rate among the searching unemployed ft, by the relation

qt = M(st;vt) vt = M( st vt;1) = M(1;t1) t = ft

t: Employment ht; is a state variable

for the household. From the perspective of the individual searcher, ft is the

probability that a match will occur. For the aggregate economy, employment thus obeys

ht+1 =stft+ (1 h)ht: (2)

Similarly, qt is the probability that an open vacancy will be matched in a

period (the job matching rate per vacancy posted) so the following aggregate relationship also holds:

ht+1 =vtqt+ (1 h)ht: (3)

10Without loss of generality it is possible to modify this model to re ect more standard

time use assumptions as well as costly labor market state switching.

11See Merz (1995) and Andolfatto (1996) for the seminal contributions in this literature. 12Shimer (2005) argues that the cyclical variability of separations is dominated by that

(13)

3.2

Social insurance

The government collects social security contributions from gross factor

pay-ments to labor, wtht, at rate t. Government purchases of goods and

ser-vices are suppressed, so all revenues from payroll taxes are used to nance a

xed unemployment bene t b paid tost unemployed engaged in search, and

"b;paid to (1 st ht) household members enjoying leisure. The parameter

" 2(0;1) can be interpreted alternatively as a measure of "classi cation

er-ror", malfeasance in the unemployment system, or overall generosity of the

welfare state.13 A positive " means that household members not actively

searching still receive some social support, which is characteristic of many OECD social security systems. The government adjusts the payroll tax rate in each period to respect the budget constraint

bst+"b(1 st ht) = twtht: (4)

As " approaches 1, search time and leisure are "rewarded" equally in terms

of consumption goods. As "approaches zero, the system replicates the

stan-dard model, and leisure is not rewarded beyond its intrinsic utility value to individual households. Writing the payroll tax rate as

t=

(1 ")bst+"b(1 ht)

wtht

; (5)

we see that a su cient condition for countercyclical t is for wt and ht to be

procyclical and st countercyclical.

3.3

Households

Households choose their labor and capital market activities to maximize

ex-pected utility. Their labor ht is compensated at net rate (1 t)wt. They

(14)

own the capital stock used in production, kt and rent capital services

deriv-ing from it, t, to rms in a competitive market. These capital services are

de ned as the product of the capital stock and its utilization rate, ut, i.e.

t=utkt. The owners of capital choose t and ut subject to the dependence

of depreciation on capital utilization

k t = 1 !u ! t (6) where ! >1:14

Given sequences of market real wages, fwtg, and rental rates for capital

services, frtg, the problem faced by a representative household att= 0 is to

choose sequences of consumption fctg, search time fstg, labor fntg, capital

tomorrow fkt+1g and capital utilization futg to maximize expected utility

E0 1 X t=0 t " lnct+A `1+t 1 + # ;

given initial stock of capital (k0) and level of employment (h0), the

period-by-period budget constraint of the household for t = 0, 1,..:

kt+1+ct= (1 t)wtht+ (1 +utrt tk)kt+bst+ b(1 st ht);

(7) the evolution of employment (2) and the dependence of depreciation on

uti-lization (6). It is assumed that A >0, 0< <1, 0:

Let zt stand for an exogenous stationary stochastic process which

de-scribes the state of productivity in the economy, to be made more precise below. The maximized value of expected utility given current employment, capital stock and the state of the economy, V(ht; kt;zt), is governed by the

14Modeling depreciation as a convex function of capacity utilization is common and

follows Greenwood, Hercowitz and Hu man (1988) among others. This feature is included to track GDP better and is not essential to our ndings.

(15)

Bellman equation fort = 0, 1,:: V(ht; kt;zt) = max ct;st;ut;ht+1;kt+1 lnct+A (1 st ht)1+ 1 + + EtV(ht+1; kt+1;zt+1) subject to (2), (5) and (6), taking initial levels of employment and capital as given. Optimality is characterized by the following conditions:

1 ct = Et " 1 +rt+1 tk+1 ct+1 # (8) rt u!t 1 = 0 (9) and A(1 st ht) b ct (1 ) = ftEt 1 ct+1 [wt+1(1 t+1) b] (10) + ftEtft+11[ 1 h f t+1 A(1 st+1 ht+1) b 1 h (1 ) ct+1 ]: Condition (8) is the typical Euler equation for consumption while (9) equates the marginal return from capital utilization to its marginal (depreciation) costs. Equation (10) determines the optimal intertemporal search-labor sup-ply sequence. The left-hand side denotes the marginal utility of leisure time

lost from shifting time from non-search leisure to search activities. The

right-hand side is the expected discounted marginal gain from search, which

consists of the expected utility of earning wt+1(1 t+1) in wages tomorrow

less b, the loss of bene t received in leisure (note if = 0, leisure is not

sub-sidized), plus the utility gain from not having to search tomorrow. Search activity today is also in uenced by future taxes; higher expected taxes to-morrow reduces the net return from work and thus the incentive to search today.

(16)

3.4

Firms

Firms maximize expected pro ts on behalf of their owners, the households.

They produce output yt using a constant returns production technology

yt=zt th1t : (11)

Pro ts, t, are given each period by

t=yt wtht rt t avt: (12)

The termztdenotes total factor productivity and its logarithm is assumed to

follow a stationary rst-order autoregressive stochastic process. Firms maxi-mize the expected discounted value of pro ts, computed using the stochastic

discount factor t+1 = t+1= t, by hiring capital services from households,

posting vacancies at cost a and, given the transition equation for

employ-ment, by choosing the volume of employment in the next period ht+1: The

maximized value of the rm given current employment and the state of the

economy, W(ht;zt); is given by the Bellman equation

W(ht;zt) = max

f t;vt;ht+1g

t+Et[ t+1W(ht+1;zt+1)]

subject to (12) and the transition equation for employment from the rm's perspective (3).

First-order conditions for the rm for t = 0;1; :: can be expressed as

follows. Optimal choice of capital service input equates marginal product of capital services with the rental price:

yt t

rt = 0: (13)

Optimal vacancy decisions are determined by a qt =Et t+1 " (1 ) yt+1 ht+1 wt+1+ (1 h) a qt+1 # (14)

(17)

which equates expected costs of posting a vacancy to the expected discounted value of pro ts of lling it (recursively, the marginal surplus of a match today plus vacancy costs saved if it survives to the next period).

3.5

Wage bargaining

The two surpluses derived above determine the joint surplus from a match

between a worker and a rm. The surplus to a matched worker is Vht Vst,

since the fallback position of a matched worker is to resume search or spend time in leisure. At the optimum, these two alternatives yield equal utility. Optimality implies that the marginal contribution to the value of the utility maximization program of an additional unit of time in search equals zero:

Vst = 0. For rms, the surplus of an additional employed worker isWht Wvt.

At the optimum, it must also be the case that Wvt = 0. The joint surplus

in the symmetric equilibria we will study in this model is therefore equal to Wht +Vht.

The wage divides match surplus between worker and rm and is

deter-mined at the individual level (we abstract completely from collective

bargain-ing). Individual workers are hired by a representative rm, which employs

many workers. Labor's bargaining power is summarized by 2 [0;1], the

Nash bargaining parameter which determines the split of the match surplus going to the worker. The surplus to the worker is

Vht =

wt(1 t) b

ct

+ (1 h ft)EtVht+1: (15)

Note that as the solution to a standard Nash bargaining problem, the gross

(before tax) wage is continuously renegotiated and there are no ad hoc real

rigidities. In each period it solves max

(18)

subject to the de nitions of Vht and Wht and taking t as given. In the Appendix, we show that the wage which solves this problem is given by:

wt= (1 )b 1 t + (1 ) yt ht + (1 n)a qt Et( t+1 t) 1 t + ta Et(1 t+1) 1 t : (16) While the wage is in uenced by the unemployment bene t paid to searching unemployed, it is independent of the social safety net parameter , given the marginal product of labor, market tightness, and the intertemporal path of taxes. For a constant pro le of tax rates, the Nash-bargained wage depends positively on the level of taxes, but the extent of this forward shifting depends on worker's bargaining strength .

One novel feature of the wage equation (16) is the central role of payroll

taxation, and in particular, its intertemporal path. Ceteris paribus, a rising

expected tax rate will raise the gross-of-tax wage today, while the expectation of falling payroll taxes tomorrow will cause the bargained wage to decline

today. If taxes are constant at the wage equation reduces to

wt= (1 )b 1 + (1 ) yt ht + ta; (17)

and if t = t+1 = 0; the expression collapses to the wage equation derived

by, for example, Ebell (2008) or Ravn (2008). A second noteworthy aspect of (16) is the interaction of payroll taxation with worker bargaining power,

parametrized by : The greater workers' bargaining power, the greater will

be their ability to shift taxes forward onto rms, and this also applies to

the impact of the expected tax pro le on wages. In addition, wages be-come increasingly rigid as the workers' bargaining power approaches zero,

(19)

4

Equilibrium and calibration

An equilibrium in this decentralized economy is de ned as a set of sequences of wages wt; capital rental ratesrt, capital input t, capital stockkt, capital

utilization rate ut, employment ht, search st, vacancies vt, output yt;

con-sumption ct, investment it, and payroll tax rates t which satisfy optimality

conditions of households and rms, resource and budget constraints as well as a transversality condition for the capital stock, given the current values of the state variables employment, technology, and capital.

We begin by specifying the non-stochastic stationary state of this econ-omy and its calibration, which is summarized in Table 2. Given the ndings of Table 1, the German economy is a natural benchmark and we calibrate

our economy average over our sample period.15 The fundamental period is a

quarter.

Table 2: Calibration

Labor share, wh=y 0.7

Discount factor, 0.99

Supply elasticity of nonleisure time, 1= 0.2

Vacancy posting costs, av=y 0.005

Capital depreciation rate, k 0.025

Job separation rate, h 0.06

Replacement rate, b=w 0.6

Unemployment rate 0.07

Time working and searching, h+s 0.5

Matching elasticity, 0.5

AR coe cient of TFP process (zt) 0.95

While most parameter values are standard, our calibration and the steady state solution which is implied require more detailed discussion. We set the labor share at 70 percent and assume that steady state vacancy posting costs

(20)

are half a percent of output. Our choice of implies an annual risk free rate of four percent; physical capital depreciates at 2.5 percent per quarter. By

setting = 5, we make labor supply less elastic than usually assumed

in real business cycle models ( = 1 is associated with the log utility

case).16 The model is calibrated to match the replacement rate, b=w, at 60

percent. This value is signi cantly lower than that assumed by Hagedorn and Manovskii (2008); furthermore it corresponds to values found in Germany and other Western European countries. The steady state nonsleeping leisure

time 1 h s is set to 1=2 (Burda, Hamermesh, and Weil, 2008). The

average unemployment rate is seven percent and is equated to the average

of observed rate for Germany (30 percent). The government's steady state nancing constraint

wh

b =s+"(1 s h)

is used to x "= 0:41. The rm's vacancies equation and the wage equation

determineAand the relative bargaining power at = 0:5455.17 The elasticity

parameter ! relating depreciation to capacity utilization is pinned down by

the rst order conditions for the household (7) and (8):

! = 1= 1 +

k

k = 1:4040:

16This value is in line with micro studies of labor supply and de ects the usual criticism

of the labor market in real business cycle models. We will show below that a high labor supply elasticity is not needed to induce high employment volatility.

17Note that the last parameter does not coincide with the elasticity of the matching

function, hence, the Hosios (1990) condition is not satis ed in this economy. Given the severe tax and other distortions already present, it seems inappropriate to assume the e cient outcome of the search process.

(21)

5

Cyclical properties of the arti cial

econ-omy

In this section, we examine the central predictions of the model with re-spect to macroeconomic and labor market variables. In particular, we are interested in arti cial economies that display signi cant cyclical behavior of payroll taxes (see Table 1). To do this, we simulate the arti cial economy and compare the outcome to a representative Western European economy, Germany, for which the Hall-Shimer-Ravn labor market puzzles are even more pronounced than in the US (see Gartner, Merkl and Rothe (2009)). We begin by presenting key facts regarding the correlations of vacancies, un-employment, labor market tightness and labor productivity for the German economy in Table 3. All data are quarterly, Hodrick-Prescott detrended and cover the period 1970:I to 2008:IV.

We focus attention on three important empirical regularities in Table 3. The most well-known is the Beveridge curve, the empirical negative corre-lation between vacancies and unemployment. Secondly, the table features the inverse relationship of unemployment and labor market tightness, which is measured as the ratio of vacancies to unemployment. This measure of tightness rises in booms and declines in recessions. Third, unemployment

and labor productivity, p, are slightly negatively correlated; booms tend to

be periods of higher labor productivity.

We begin the analysis by characterizing the dynamics of our arti cial economy without payroll taxes. This model is close in spirit to those studied by Tripier (2003), Ravn (2008), and Veracierto (2008), who model distinct activities in unemployment, i.e. search versus leisure. All these authors were unable to replicate the negatively-sloped Beveridge curve, with

(22)

search activity, incentives to search are su ciently procyclical to generate

this counterfactual property.18 Table 4 con rms that our arti cial economy

-which is driven by a single technology shock process - also displays this

prop-erty when the payroll tax rate is set to zero and social insurance is nanced

via lump-sum taxation. Without payroll taxes, our arti cial economy fails to

replicate the Beveridge curve relationship, instead generating a s v

corre-lation of 0:87. While this version of the model predicts a positive correcorre-lation between productivity and market tightness, it is considerably stronger than in the data (model: 0:99, Germany: 0:29). Furthermore, it cannot generate the observed negative correlations between labor market tightness and labor

productivity with unemployment.19

Table 3: Labor market indicators and labor

productivity, Germany, 1970:I - 2008:IV

v s p

v 1.00 -0.81 0.96 0.30

s 1.00 -0.94 -0.24

1.00 0.29

p 1.00

Table 4 Labor market indicators and labor

productivity, arti cial economy ( = 0)

v s p

v 1.00 0.87 0.61 0.69

s 1.00 0.15 0.26

1.00 0.99

p 1.00

A key nding of this paper is that central robust correlations in the data are restored in the presence of payroll taxes and a self- nancing social security

18Ebell (2009) shows that some of these problems can be addressed by alternative

cali-bration assumptions.

19Ravn (2008) has called these results the "consumption-tightness puzzle." In what

(23)

system. Tables 5 through 9 document these results. In Table 5 we report the same labor market correlations for the calibrated economy with a positive and endogenous payroll tax rate and a social safety net of calibrated size

( = 0):The calibrated model is qualitatively and quantitatively much more

consistent with correlations from the German economy (Table 3). First,

the Beveridge curve is restored, with a correlation of 0:74, essentially the

value for the German economy. Second, the model economy produces a signi cant increase in the volatility of vacancies and unemployment (Table 6). Furthermore, unemployment and tightness are negatively correlated: the

correlation switches sign from 0:15 to 0:91, a value which is almost identical

to the correlation in the German data. Theory can now also account for a weakly negative correlation between unemployment and productivity.

Table 5: Labor market indicators and labor

productivity, arti cial economy ( >0)

v s p

v 1.00 -0.74 0.96 0.68

s 1.00 -0.91 -0.03

1.00 0.44

p 1.00

Before discussing the payroll-related propagation mechanism in detail, it is informative to consider other attributes of the arti cial economy. Tables 6 and 7 show that the introduction of payroll taxation generates unemploy-ment that not only moves countercyclically, but is also volatile and serially correlated, in line with German joblessness. Likewise, vacancies are strongly cyclical. The volatility of vacancies relative to productivity in the arti cial economy increases by about thirtyfold, also taking on a value similar to that in the data. Lastly, Table 7 also suggests that the intertemporal e ects of taxes (on search and vacancy choice as well as on wage setting) can help create labor market persistence commonly observed in data: in our arti

(24)

-cial economy, vacancies and unemployment exhibit autocorrelations much more consistent with empirical observation than the model without labor taxation.20

Table 6: Unemployment (s) and vacancies (v)

Germany Model: = 0 Model: >0

v= y 13.24 1.82 12.37

s= y 11.41 1.46 8.57

(v; y) 0.67 0.61 0.99

(s; y) -0.74 0.16 -0.81

Table 7: Labor market tightness and persistence

Germany Model: = 0 Model: >0

= p 34.52 0.99 31.47

( ; p) 0.29 0.79 0.51

(v; v 1) 0.95 0.31 0.82

(s; s 1) 0.95 0.25 0.91

The model's improved performance is evidently related to the counter-cyclical nature of payroll taxation, which follows directly from the balanced budget restriction and its e ect on the wage bargain. Table 8 shows that the introduction of taxes reduces (before tax) wage volatility signi cantly, with the relative standard deviation of wages declining by almost 50 percent. The wage rises less during booms, and the correlation with output is also cut by half. In e ect, the tax system induces rigidity in gross wages paid by employers, even though gross and net wages are perfectly exible. In Table 8, we show this directly by comparing wage behavior in the two models.

Table 8: Wages in the arti cial economy

= 0 >0

w= y 0.89 0.57

(w; y) 1.00 0.52

20When capital depreciation is held constant, (s; v) = 0:68, (s; y) = 0:76, and

= p = 27:93, hence while helpful, our results regarding the puzzles do not appear to

(25)

In Figures 5 to 8 we plot impulse responses of the model economy to a single productivity shocks with and without a payroll tax cum social security net. In the presence of taxes, the model becomes substantially more persis-tent, with output following a humped-shaped pattern. In particular, Figure 7 demonstrates the countercyclical pattern of taxes that arises endogenously in response to a the positive technology shock. Figure 8 displays the rela-tively rigid response of the wage, which is less volatile than output and dies out rapidly.

Figures 5, 6, 7, and 8 about here

6

Dissecting and interpreting the mechanism

Our main ndings thus far can be summarized as follows: a calibrated RBC model with labor market frictions combined with an endogenous payroll tax and a distortion of the search-leisure decision can signi cantly increase

en-dogenous propagation and restore the Beveridge curve without ad hoc

as-sumptions regarding sticky wages, extreme fallback positions or low worker bargaining power.

6.1

The central role of distortionary payroll taxation

We claim that the key factor accounting for our results is the dynamic path of payroll taxes as described in Section 2. This being said, it is useful to verify that our arti cial economy generates payroll tax sequences similar to those observed in the data. Table 9 shows that the payroll tax in the model economy exhibits relative volatility and countercyclical behavior consistent with the overall intertemporal pattern of payroll tax rates in the data noted in

Section 2. While the model's negative correlation of twith output is stronger

(26)

a single shock. Overall, the general mechanism of tax uctuations that we have uncovered in this paper is qualitatively and quantitatively relevant.

Table 9: Behavior of payroll tax rate

Germany Model with tax

= y 1.57 1.99

( ; y) -0.51 -0.92

To demonstrate the importance of the distortionary labor tax channel for generating the model's predictions, we now examine the behavior of our model economy under an alternative nancing regime consisting of a constant

payroll tax rate and lump sum taxes,Tt, adjusted each period to obey the

government funding constraint

bst+"b(1 st ht) = wtht+Tt: (18)

To maintain the comparability of both models and to isolate the level

ef-fect, we impose T = 0 in the steady state, so assumes the same long-run

value as in our baseline calibration. Under these assumptions, the model's previous attributes are restored: persistence falls signi cantly and the slope of the Beveridge curve changes sign. Vacancies and unemployment are now strongly positively correlated and unemployment is procylical. Characteris-tic of this outcome is a qualitatively di erent dynamic behavior of the gross

wage. Under the alternative nancing arrangement, the correlation of the

wage with output rises to 0:99 and its relative volatility nearly doubles. Evi-dently, the variability of payroll taxes is the central factor driving the results reported in Tables 5-8.

The level of unemployment insurance payments is also important for our results, however. Reducing the replacement rate attenuates the Beveridge curve correlation and ultimately renders it positive (as shown in Table 4). In addition, persistence and volatility of labor market quantities decline sharply.

(27)

The generosity of the social welfare system, parametrized by", plays a similar

role; reducing " lowers the volatility of vacancies and unemployment, while

preserving the Beveridge relation. Lower values of " reduce the size of the

payroll tax burden at any level of employment and the gross wage, thereby

reducing the amplitude of t necessary to maintain budget balance at any

value of the wage bill. The margin between leisure and search is crucial for

generating volatility of labor market quantities; while the e ect of lower "

is ambiguous in theory, the size of the welfare state in the calibrations we

study is important for generating our ndings.21

6.2

Interpretation

The model with variable labor taxation o er a better description of the labor market because it induces a relative rigidity of gross wages, i.e. employers'

costs, and supports Hall's (2005) claim that xed wages can align search

models and data.22 Yet gross and net wages in our arti cial economy are

endogenous and only appear rigid. Although net wages and the return to work rise in upturns when labor markets are tightening, the negative e ects on labor demand and vacancies are dampened by falling payroll taxes. Be-cause gross wages react less strongly, higher employment does not translate as rapidly into higher costs for rms.

Consider a rm which faces a higher realization of total factor

productiv-ity, zt. Because the posting of vacancies is a dynamic problem, present and

future wage labor costs determine the optimal policy via (14). If the gross wage paid by rms remains relatively at over time, the expected surplus of

21Note

t= b[st+"(1wthstt ht)], so for xed b; s, h, andw, @@"t = b(1wstththt) >0:However,

lower values of"will a ectst,htandwt, so the general equilibrium e ect is theoretically

ambiguous.

22In the extreme case of a zero workers' bargaining power, i.e. !0, the wage (15)

(28)

creating jobs will be higher, and rms post more vacancies, which raises their volatility as well. At the same time, countercyclical payroll taxes renders net after-tax wages much less procyclical. Hence, even with sticky wages, work-ers will see expected bene ts from search rise in booms (see Equation 9), but because vacancies respond so strongly, optimal strategy according to (10) involves less search in recessions, not more.

The dampened volatility of gross wages induced by payroll taxes is es-sential for bringing our model correlations in line with the data (i.e. the consumption-tightness puzzle). As Table 6 shows, the standard model can-not generate countercyclical unemployment. Households respond to a posi-tive productivity shock by moving out of leisure and into search activities, which raises the level of unemployment sharply. In our model, a atter la-bor cost pro le induces the creation of many more vacancies than in the standard formulation, so while a positive technological shock makes search more attractive, searching workers are moved more rapidly out of leisure and into employment. The result is that any stage of an expansion, fewer agents are unemployed, which is also consistent with empirical evidence that unemployment durations are strongly countercyclical. This is linked to the fact that vacancies become relatively more volatile than search (Table 6) so under the payroll tax regime search unemployment will be countercyclical { the combined e ect is a correctly sloped Beveridge curve.

7

Conclusions

It is well-known that payroll taxes represent a major long-run distortionary in uence of governments on labor markets. We have established that they also a ect business cycle dynamics. For a number of Western European economies as well as the United States for last two decades, the average

(29)

pay-roll tax burden has been countercyclical.23 Although we consider a speci c

type of labor tax here, its behavior is consistent with Rogerson and Shimer's (2010) description of a countercyclical labor wedge. Our study takes up the role of payroll taxation and the social safety net { modeled as a generous sys-tem of unemployment insurance { for cyclical uctuations in an nonmonetary economy with labor market frictions and unemployment insurance, when the latter is only imperfectly related to search e ort. A balanced social insur-ance budget renders gross wages more rigid over the cycle and, as a result, strengthens the model's endogenous propagation mechanism. The existence of social insurance strengthens this e ect, as does worker bargaining power. For conventional calibrations, the model can generate a negatively sloped Beveridge curve and match the high volatility of vacancies and unemploy-ment relative to labor productivity. While it is beyond the scope of this study, it would be useful to examine micro data and uncover the quantita-tive sources of countercyclical payroll taxation and to account for its behavior over time.

It was not the purpose of this paper to produce a general account of the high volatility of vacancies and unemployment in modern economies, but we have identi ed a new mechanism which can help us better understand the labor market and its interaction with the business cycle. Countercyclical taxation of labor can contribute towards resolving the Hall-Shimer puzzle and realign theory with many labor market facts, but need not be the only mechanism which does so, and evidence presented in Table 1 suggests that a large number of forces may be at work in creating observed outcomes. Our results for arti cial economies imply that payroll taxes combined with a

23If we set"so the model matches average in the US and steady state unemployment

equals ve percent, our arti cial economy's Beveridge correlation is (u; v) = 0:45 (versus 0:83 without variable payroll tax) and = p = 6:23 (versus 1:76 without variable payroll

(30)

high subsidy of leisure can signi cantly a ect the qualitative properties of an important class of equilibrium business cycle models, and it would be easy to identify other tax and transfer mechanisms that work in a similar fashion, in particular, more general systems of labor taxation in which a balanced budget constraint is operative in each period. The novel aspects of our model mimic a particular facet of many OECD labor markets, and for the US in the latter half of our sample. Without payroll taxes, our model would still exhibit the anomaly identi ed by Ravn (2008). The payroll tax mechanism, combined with a su ciently large social insurance system, represents a simple means of accounting for central relative variances in the data while incorporating an important feature of modern labor markets.

(31)

References

[1] Beveridge, William H. (1944): "The Government's Employment Policy,"

Economic Journal 54, 161-176.

[2] Bils, Mark (1985) \Real Wages over the Business Cycle: Evidence from

Panel Data" Journal of Political Economy 93: 666{89.

[3] Burda, Michael C. and Mark Weder (2002): "Complementarity of Labor Market Institutions, Equilibrium Unemployment and the Persistence of

Business Cycles", German Economic Review 3, 1-24.

[4] Burda, Michael C., Dan S. Hamermesh and Philippe Weil (2008): "The Distribution of Total Work in the EU and the US," in Tito Boeri, et

al. eds., Working Hour and Job Sharing in the EU and the USA: Are

Europeans Lazy or Americans Crazy?,Oxford: Oxford University Press.

[5] Chari, V. V., Patrick J. Kehoe and Ellen R. McGrattan (2008):

"Busi-ness Cycle Accounting", Econometrica75, 781-836.

[6] Cole, Harold L. and Richard Rogerson (1999): "Can the

Mortensen-Pissarides Matching Model Match the Business-Cycle Facts?,"

Interna-tional Economic Review 40, 933-59.

[7] Cooley, Thomas F. (1997): "Calibrated Models",Oxford Review of

Eco-nomic Policy 13, 55-69.

[8] Costain, Jim and Michael Reiter (2008): "Business Cycles,

Unemploy-ment Insurance, and the Calibration of Matching Models," Journal of

Economic Dynamics and Control 32:1120{1155.

[9] Ebell, Monique (2009): "Resurrecting the Participation Margin", mimeo.

(32)

[10] Gal , Jordi and Thijs van Rens (2010): "The Vanishing Procyclicality of Labor Productivity," mimeo, July 2010.

[11] Gartner, Hermann, Christian Merkl and Thomas Rothe (2009): "They are Even Larger! More (on) Puzzling Labor Market Volatilities", IZA Discussion Paper 4403.

[12] Gertler, Mark and Antonella Trigari (2009): "Unemployment

Fluctua-tions with Staggered Nash Wage Bargaining",Journal of Political

Econ-omy 117, 38-86.

[13] Greenwood, Jeremy, Zvi Hercowitz and Gregory Hu man (1988):

"In-vestment, Capacity Utilization, and the Real Business Cycle",American

Economic Review 78, 402-417.

[14] Hagedorn, Marcus and Iourii Manovskii (2008): "The Cyclical

Behav-ior of Equilibrium Unemployment and Vacancies Revisited", American

Economic Review 98, 1692-1706.

[15] Hall, Robert (2005): "Employment Fluctuations with Equilibrium Wage

Stickiness", American Economic Review 95, 50-65.

[16] Hall, Robert and Paul R. Milgrom (2008): "The Limited In uence of

Unemployment on the Wage Bargain",American Economic Review 98,

1653-1674.

[17] Hornstein, Andreas, Per Krusell and Giovanni L. Violante (2005): "Un-employment and Vacancy Fluctuations in the Matching Model:

In-specting the Mechanism", Federal Reserve Bank of RichmondEconomic

Quarterly 91, 19-51.

[18] Hosios, A. (1990): "On the E ciency of Matching and Related Models of

(33)

[19] Kaldor, Nicholas (1936): \Wage Subsidies as a Remedy for

Unemploy-ment," Journal of Political Economy 44, 721-742.

[20] Keynes, John M. (1942): letter to James Meade in: Kenyes, John

Maynard (1980). The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes

Vol-ume 27. Edited by Donald Moggridge. Macmillan, Cambridge University Press, 217-8.

[21] Meade, James (1938): Consumers' Credits and Unemployment, Oxford:

Oxford University Press.

[22] Merz, Monika (1995): "Search in the labor market and the real business

cycle," Journal of Monetary Economics 36, 269-300.

[23] Ravn, Morten (2008): "The Consumption-Tightness Puzzle", in:

Reich-lin, Lucrecia and West, Kenneth (eds.) NBER International Seminars

in Macroeconomics, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

[24] Rogerson, Richard and Robert Shimer (2010): "Labor Search", in

Hand-book of Labor Economics, forthcoming.

[25] Romer, David and Christina Romer (2009): "A Narrative Analysis of Postwar Tax Changes", (Appendix to "The Macroeconomic E ects of Tax Changes: Estimates Based on a New Measure of Fiscal Shocks.") [26] Shimer, Robert (2005): \The Cyclical Behavior of Equilibrium

Unem-ployment and Vacancies," American Economic Review 95, 25{49.

[27] Shimer, Robert (2009): Labor Markets and Business Cycles,manuscript,

University of Chicago.

[28] Tripier, Fabien (2003): "Can the Labor Market Search Model Explain

(34)

[29] Veracierto, Marcelo (2008): "On the Cyclical Behavior of Employment,

Unemployment and Labor Force Participation", Journal of Monetary

(35)

8

Appendix: Wage equation

The rst order condition from the Nash bargaining problem is

(1 t)

ctVht

= (1 )

Wht

or, given that the value of an additional employed worker to the rm is given by ctVht = (1 t) 1 " (1 )yt ht wt+ (1 n) a qt # (A1) Lead this expression by one period and premultiply by the pricing kernel

t+1: t+1ct+1Vht+1 = (1 t+1) 1 t+1 " (1 )yt+1 ht+1 wt+1+ (1 n) a qt+1 # :

Take expectation of both sides conditional on t;and the fact that t+1ct+1 =

ct to rewrite the last expression as

Et t+1ct+1Vht+1 = ctEtVht+1 =

Et(1 t+1)

1

a qt

Premultiply both sides of the household surplus from employment by ct,

substitute the last expression and use t+1 = ct=ct+1 to obtain

ctVht = (1 t)wt b+ t+1(1 n f t)ct+1EtVht+1 and ctVht = (1 t)wt b+ (1 n f t) Et(1 t+1) 1 act qt

Now insert this and (A1) into the Nash bargaining rst-order condition:

(1 t) " (1 ) yt ht wt+ (1 n) a qt # = (1 ) " (1 t)wt b+ (1 n ft) Et(1 t+1) 1 a qt #

(36)

which can be solved to obtain wt= (1 )b 1 t + (1 )yt ht + (1 n)a qt (1 n ft) a qt Et(1 t+1) 1 t or wt= (1 )b 1 t + (1 )yt ht + (1 n)a qt Et( t+1 t) 1 t + ta Et(1 t+1) 1 t :

(37)

Figure 1: Payroll taxes as a fraction of total compensation, United States, 1970:I-2008:IV

Figure 2: Payroll taxes as a fraction of total compensation, Germany 1970:I-2008:IV

(38)

Figure 3: HP-detrended payroll taxes and GDP per capita, United States, 1970:I-2008:IV

Figure 4: HP-detrended payroll taxes and GDP per capita, Germany 1970:I-2008:IV

(39)

Figure 5: Impulse response functions (IRF) of the model economy without payroll taxes and social insurance system to a positive 1% technology shock (z): Output, unemployment, labor share

(40)

Figure 6: Impulse response functions (IRF) of the model economy without payroll taxes and social insurance system to a positive 1% technology shock (z): Vacancies, employment, wages, labor market tightness (v/s)

(41)

Figure 7: Impulse response functions (IRF) of the model economy with payroll taxes and social insurance system to a positive 1% technology shock: Output, unemployment, tax rate, labor share

(42)

Figure 8: Impulse response functions (IRF) of the model economy with payroll taxes and social insurance system to a positive 1% technology shock: Vacancies, employment, wages, labor market tightness (v/s)

Figure

Table 1: Payroll taxes in OECD countries
Table 2: Calibration
Table 3: Labor market indicators and labor productivity, Germany, 1970:I - 2008:IV
Table 5: Labor market indicators and labor productivity, arti cial economy ( &gt; 0)
+7

References

Related documents

MINNIE-HA-HA MINERAL CLAIM.. THE

in particular, payroll in Germany includes the collection of different taxes and mandatory contributions to social insurance schemes.. personal information earninGs other

Specifi- cally, Hypothesis 5 states that a dictator is more likely to eliminate rival elites as the current probability that an elite can successfully oust a dictator via a

Specifi- cally, the paper aimed at giving an overview of e-lawyering and virtual law practice, characteristics of e-lawyering and virtual law practice, law library system in the era

To identify the root cause of failure in design parameters three main challenges have been identified: (i) identifying the Key Failure Characteristics (KFCs) which defines the

Desde esa preocupación principal nos proponemos, en primer término, deter- minar los diversos emprendimientos mineros entre fines del siglo XIX y la década de 1930; en segundo

Mechatronics education took place in a two-year Mechatronic Designer programme, in specialisations in Electrical and Mechanical Engineering and in an international MSc

We use linked data on over 20,000 individuals and almost 1,500 workplaces from the British Workplace Employee Relations Survey 1998 WERS98 to analyze the perceived and