• No results found

The existence of equilibria for the rank game

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2020

Share "The existence of equilibria for the rank game"

Copied!
6
0
0

Loading.... (view fulltext now)

Full text

(1)

R E S E A R C H

Open Access

The existence of equilibria for the rank game

Zhi Lin

*

Dedicated to Professor Shih-sen Chang on the occasion of his 80th birthday

*Correspondence:

linzhi7525@163.com College of Sciences, Chongqing Jiaotong University, Chongqing, 400074, China

Abstract

In this paper, we introduce the concept of the rank game and propose a

mathematical model for it. By a discrete fixed point theorem, we give the existence results of rank equilibria.

MSC: 91A10; 91A40

Keywords: rank game; rank-integer; rank-remainder; rank

1 Introduction

In [, ], Nash has proved the existence of an equilibrium for the non-cooperative game by using the fixed point theorem, which is called a Nash equilibrium. In a Nash game each player always maximizes his payoff value and does not pay attention to how much the other player’s payoff values are. In other words, each player looks after a high absolute number of his payoff value only and does not care about the rank of his payoff value. But the above assumption is often not true in practice when there exist competitive relationships among players. Since the stronger one is always in an advantageous position in a future game, each player often cares more about his rank of payoff value among all players than the payoff value itself. The game in which each player cares for his rank of payoff value among all players more than the payoff value is said to be a rank game. In this paper, we introduce the concept of the rank game and propose its mathematical model. By a discrete fixed point theorem, we give the existence results of rank equilibria. For other results of the rank game, we refer to [], and for discrete fixed point theorems, we refer to [–] and references therein.

() Four basic factors of the rank game.

The rank game belongs to the category of the non-cooperative game. The player, strategy set, and payoff function are three basic factors in a non-cooperative game, thus they are also essential factors in a rank game. Moreover, in a rank game, the payoff of each player is assumed to have an initial value before the game, which is called the initial payoff value of each player. Clearly, the stronger (the bigger of the initial payoff value) and the weaker (the smaller of the initial payoff value) have different options in a rank game; in other words, in a rank game, the choice of each player is not only related to the payoff value in the game, but it also is related to the initial payoff value before the game. Thus the initial payoff value of each player is the fourth key factor in a rank game.

() Several basic concepts of the rank game.

(2)

LetI={, , . . . ,n}denote the set of players. For eachiI, letKi,fidenote the strategy

set and initial payoff value of playeri, respectively, and let the real functionfi:KR

denote the payoff function of playeri. DenoteK=ni=Ki,Ki=

n

j=i,j=Kj. For eachxK,

we can writex= (xi,xi). For eachiI,xK, letQi={jI:fj+fj(x) >fi+fi(x)},Pi={j

I:fj+fj(x) =fi+fi(x)},mi=|Qi|+ ,li=|Pi|, where| · |denotes the element number of

the set, and let

hi=

li– 

li

, ui=mi+hi.

Clearly,miandliboth are integer andnmi,li,ui≥ >hi≥. Denotef= (f,f, . . . ,

f

n), f(x) = (f(x),f(x), . . . ,fn(x)) (briefly,f = (f,f, . . . ,fn)),F(x) = (F(x),F(x), . . . ,Fn(x)) =

f+f(x) = (f

 +f(x),f+f(x), . . . ,fn+fn(x)) (briefly,F= (F,F, . . . ,Fn)),∀xK. Note that

for eachiI,xK,ui(x) =ui(f,f(x)).

Definition . For each iI, xK, mi, hi, and ui are called the rank-integer, the

rank-remainder, and the rank of playeri atxK, respectively. For each xK,u(x) = (u(x),u(x), . . . ,un(x)) (briefly,u= (u,u, . . . ,un)),f(x), andF(x) are called the rank

vec-tor, the payoff vecvec-tor, and the accumulated payoff vector of players atxK, respectively. If for eachj(n≥j≥), there isiI such thatui=j, (u,u, . . . ,un) is called a complete

rank vector, otherwise a noncomplete rank vector of players.

It is easy to verify that for eachi,jI,xK,ui= (<, >)ujif and only ifFi(x) = (>, <)Fj(x).

() The rank game’s principle.

The rank game’s principle: each player always minimizes the number of players ranking before him (those accumulated payoff values are bigger than that of him) and, after this condition is satisfied, each player always minimizes the number of players ranking the same as he (those accumulated payoff values are the same as that of him), and after these two conditions are satisfied, each player always maximizes his payoff value. Equivalently, the rank game’s principle can also be expressed as follows: each player always minimizes the number of players ranking before himself, and after this condition is satisfied, each player always maximizes the number of players ranking after himself (those accumulated payoff values are less than that of his), and after these two conditions are satisfied, each player always maximizes his payoff value.

The rank game is a class of cooperative games. Thus, these assumptions of the non-cooperative game, for example, each player is rational, the information is symmetrical, and so on, are still necessary in the rank game. The main differences between a Nash game and the rank game are: in a Nash game, each player always maximizes his payoff value and does not care about how much the other player’s payoff values are, but in a rank game, each player always minimizes his rank, and after his rank reached minimum, the player always maximizes his payoff value.

A Nash game is suitable for the case that competitive relationships do not exist among players, and the rank game is suitable for the case that there exist competitions among players.

() The mathematical model of the rank game.

For each iI, letKi,fi,fidenote the strategy set and initial payoff value and payoff

(3)

The rank game is: findx∗= (x∗,x, . . . ,xn∗)∈Ksuch that for eachiI,yiKi,

ui

f+fxi,xˆ

i

=min

yiKi ui

f+fyi,xˆi

,

and ifui(f+f(xi∗,xˆ∗i)) =ui(f

+f(y

i,xˆi)), then

fi

xi,xˆ

i

fi

yi,x∗ˆi

.

x∗is called a rank equilibrium point (briefly, rank equilibrium) of the rank game. A rank game is denoted by={Ki,fi,fi}iI.

For eachiI, ifKiis a finite set, thenfimay be denoted by matrices, which are called

the payoff matrices; in this case, the rank gameis called a finite rank game, otherwise an infinite rank game.

2 Preliminaries

Throughout this paper, unless otherwise specified, assume that for eachiI, the strategy set isKi={, , . . . ,ki}of playeri, wherekidenotes a positive integer.Kis equipped with

a sign component-wise order,i.e.,Iis divided into two subsets (possibly empty)I+andI–, λj=± are allocated tojI+andjI–respectively, and for eachx= (xi)iI,y= (yi)iIK,

x yis defined byλjxjλjyjfor eachjI. For eachiI,Ki=

jI,j=iKjis also equipped

with the sign component-wise order. It is easy to verify that the sign component-wise order is a partial order. The symbolxymeansx yandx=y.

Consider the rank game={Ki,fi,fi}iI. For each iI, letρi(xi) ={xiKi:ui(f+

f(xi,xˆi)) =minyiKiui(f

+f(y

i,xˆi))}, and the best responses mapSi:Ki→Kiof playeriis

defined by

Si(xi) =

xiKi:f(xi,xˆi) = max yiρi(xi)

fi(yi,xˆi)

,

where Kidenotes the family of all nonempty subsets ofK

i.

The best responses mapS:K→Kof the rank gameis defined by

S(x) =

iI

Si(xi).

Note that for eachiI,xK,ρi(xi)=∅,Si(xi)=∅, thusS(x)=∅. Clearlyx∗∈Kis a rank

equilibrium point if and only ifx∗∈S(x∗).

We have the following lemma; see [] (Theorem .).

Lemma . Let(V, )be a partially ordered set and g:V→Va set-valued map.Assume

that

() there existx∈Vandx∈g(x)such thatxxand{xV:xx}is finite; () for eachxV andyg(x),

xy ⇒ ∃zg(y)s.t.y z.

(4)

3 The existence of equilibrium points for the rank game

Definition .(Monotonicity) A rank gameis called monotone if, for eachiI,xi,xi

Kiwithxix

i and for eachx

iSi(xi), there existsx

iSi(xi) such thatλix

iλixi.

Theorem . Any monotone n-person rank gamehas a rank equilibrium point.

Proof The following proof is analogous to that of Lemma ..

SinceKis a finite set and it has a minimum element, the condition () of Lemma . is trivially satisfied. In the following we verify that the condition () of Lemma . is also satisfied.

Assume thatxK andxS(x) satisfyxx. LetI

={iI:xi =xi},I={iI:

xix

i}. ThenI∩I=∅,I=I∪I. Note thatI=∅, otherwisex

=x, a contradiction.

Assume without loss of generality thatI=∅. For eachiI, byx≺x, we haveλixi <λixi.

Takex

i =xi, thenxi =xiSi(xi) =Si(xi). For eachiI, we havexixiandxiSi(xi),

thus, by monotonicity, there existsx

iSi(xi) such thatλixiλixi. Hencex= (xi)iI

S(x) andxx,i.e., the condition () of Lemma . is satisfied. By Lemma ., there

existsx∗∈S(x∗).

Definition . ForiI, a sequence{xji}t

j=⊂Ki, wheretis a positive integer, is called a

total-ordered sequence if, for eachj,j∈ {, , . . . ,t}withj<j, thenxji≺xji. Definition . A sequence{xj}t

j=is called a subsequence of{yj}

t

j= if{xj}

t

j=⊂ {yj}

t

j=and

t<t.

Definition . ForiI, a sequence{xj

i} t

j=⊂Ki is called a maximal total-ordered

se-quence (briefly, MTOS) if: () it is a total-ordered sese-quence; () there is no total-ordered sequence{yj

i} T

j=⊂Kisuch that{x j

i} t

j=is a subsequence of{y

j

i} T j=.

Definition . ForiI, let {xji}tj=Ki is a MTOS. For eachj∈ {, , . . . ,t}, let w j i=

max

yjSi(xji){yj},v

j

i=minyjSi(xji){yj}.{w

j

i}tj=and{v

j

i}tj=are called a best response maximal

ele-ment sequence (briefly, BRMAES) and a best response minimal eleele-ment sequence (briefly, BRMIES) of{xj

i} t

j=, respectively.

Note that for eachiI, there exists at least a MTOS inKi, and each MTOS has unique

BRMAES and BRMIES.

Lemma . The rank game={Ki,fi,fi}iIis monotone iff for each iI,each BRMAES

is nondecreasing when iI+,and each BRMIES is nonincreasing when iI–.

Proof ‘⇒’ For eachiI, assume that{xji}tj=Kiis a MTOS.

()iI+, and in the case,λi= . Let {wji}tj= denote the BRMAES of{x

j

i} t

j=. For each

j∈ {, , . . . ,t–},xjixij+,wjiSi(xji), sinceis monotone, there existswi j+S

i(xji+) such

thatλiwjiλiwij+,i.e.,wijwij+. Note thatwij+≤wji+, thusw j iw

j+

i ,i.e., the sequence

{wji}tj=is nondecreasing.

()iI–, and in the case,λi= –. Let{vji}tj= denote the BRMIES of{x

j

i} t

j=. For each

j∈ {, , . . . ,t– },xjixij+,vjiSi(xji), sinceis monotone, there existsvi j+S

i(xji+) such

thatλivjiλivij+,i.e.,vijvij+. Note thatvij+≥vji+, thusv j iv

j+

i ,i.e., the sequence{v j i}tj=

(5)

‘⇐’ For eachiI, assume thatxiyi,xiSi(xi). There exists a MTOS{x j

i} t

j=⊂Kisuch

thatxi,yi∈ {x j

i} t

j=. Denotexi=x ti ,yi=x

t

i . Byxiyi, we havet<t.

()iI+and we have the caseλi= . Let{wji}tj= be the BRMAES of{x

j

i} t

j= andw

t

i

Si(xti),w t

iSi(xti). Since{w j

i}tj=is nondecreasing, we havew

t

iw t

i . Note thatxiwti,

thusxiwti,i.e.,λixiλiwti, which implies that the rank gameis monotone.

()iI– and we have the caseλi= –. Let{vji}tj= be the BRMIES of{x

j

i} t

j= andv

t

i

Si(xti),v t

iSi(xti). Since{v j

i}tj=is nonincreasing, we havev

t

iv t

i . Note thatxivti, thus

xivti,i.e.,λixiλivti, which implies that the rank gameis monotone.

Theorem . For the rank game,assume that each BRMAES is nondecreasing when i

I+and each BRMIES is nonincreasing when iI–,then forthere exists a rank equilibrium

point.

Proof By Lemma ., the rank gameis monotone. By Theorem ., the result follows.

Example . Consider the following -persons rank game, whereK=K={, , },

f

 = ,f= , and the payoff matrices are

Gf=

⎛ ⎜ ⎝

(, ) (, ) (, ) (, ) (, ) (–, ) (, ) (, ) (, )

⎞ ⎟ ⎠.

Thus the accumulated payoff matrices are

GF=

⎛ ⎜ ⎝

(, ) (, ) (, )R (, ) (, ) (, ) (, ) (, ) (, )

⎞ ⎟ ⎠.

Take (λ,λ) = (–, ). Fori= , there exists an unique MTOS{, , }inK=K. It is easy

to verify thatρ() ={},S() ={},ρ() ={, },S() ={, },ρ() ={, },S() ={}.

Thus, the BRMIES{v}={, , }, and it is a nonincreasing sequence.

Fori= , there exists an unique MTOS{, , }inK=K. It is easy to verify thatρ() = {},S() ={},ρ() ={, },S() ={},ρ() ={, , },S() ={}. Thus, the BRMAES {w}={, , }, and it is a nondecreasing sequence.

By Theorem ., forthere exists a rank equilibrium. It is easy to verify that (, ) is a rank equilibrium.

Example . Consider the following -persons rank game, whereK=K=K={, },

f

 = ,f= ,f= , and the payoff matrices are

when player  chooses strategy , Gf=

(, , ) (–, , –) (, , –) (, , )

,

when player  chooses strategy , Gf=

(, , ) (, , ) (, , ) (, , )

(6)

Thus the accumulated payoff matrices are

when player  chooses strategy , GF=

(, , ) (–, , –) (, , –) (, , )

,

when player  chooses strategy , GF=

(, , ) (, , ) (, , ) (, , )R

.

Take (λ,λ) = (, , ). Fori= , there exist two MTOS{(, ), (, ), (, )}and{(, ), (, ),

(, )}inK. It is easy to verify thatρ(, ) ={},S(, ) ={},ρ(, ) ={},S(, ) ={}, ρ(, ) ={},S(, ) ={},ρ(, ) ={, },S(, ) ={, }. Thus, their BRMAES{w}= {w}={, , }, and it is a nondecreasing sequence.

Fori= , there exist two MTOS{(, ), (, ), (, )} and{(, ), (, ), (, )}inK. It is

easy to verify thatρ(, ) ={, },S(, ) ={},ρ(, ) ={, },S(, ) ={},ρ(, ) ={},

S(, ) ={}, ρ(, ) ={}, S(, ) ={}. Thus, for MTOS{(, ), (, ), (, )}, the

BR-MAES {w}={, , }, and for MTOS {(, ), (, ), (, )}, the BRMAES {w}={, , }. Clearly,{w}and{w}are nondecreasing sequences.

Fori= , there exist two MTOS{(, ), (, ), (, )} and{(, ), (, ), (, )}inK. It is

easy to verify thatρ(, ) ={, },S(, ) ={},ρ(, ) ={},S(, ) ={},ρ(, ) ={},

S(, ) ={},ρ(, ) ={},S(, ) ={}. Thus, their BRMAES{w}={w}={, , }, and

it is a nondecreasing sequence.

By Theorem ., forthere exists a rank equilibrium. It is easy to verify that (, , ) is a rank equilibrium.

Competing interests

The author declares that they have no competing interests.

Acknowledgements

This work was supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (No. 11271389).

Received: 17 February 2014 Accepted: 8 October 2014 Published:16 Oct 2014 References

1. Nash, J: Equilibrium points inN-person games. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA36, 48-49 (1950) 2. Nash, J: Noncooperative games. Ann. Math.54, 286-295 (1951)

3. Lin, Z: Rank game. Oper. Res. Fuzziol.2, 42-52 (2012)

4. Asto, J-i, Kawasaki, H: Discrete fixed point theorems and their application to Nash equilibrium. Taiwan. J. Math.13(2), 431-440 (2009)

5. Yang, ZF: Discrete fixed point analysis and its applications. J. Fixed Point Theory Appl.6, 351-371 (2009) 6. Chen, X, Deng, XT: A simplicial approach for discrete fixed point theorems. Algorithmica53(2), 250-262 (2009)

10.1186/1029-242X-2014-416

Cite this article as:Lin:The existence of equilibria for the rank game.Journal of Inequalities and Applications

References

Related documents

In addition, for a square duct downstream of an elbow with fully developed velocity inlet, the dimensionless developing length based on velocity gradient profiles were found to be

When tn3270 is specified as the command, or in the case of AIX, any of the three TELNET commands ( telnet , tn , or tn3270 ), and a IBG 3270 block mode capable host is

Having considered the cases of pancreas transplant loss due to immunological factors in the early postoperative period (irreversible antibody-mediated rejection in Pa- tient 29) and

Within the Hutong community, the inhabitants managed the space with sophistication, both at a physical level and a social level, to live a harmonized life. Hutong did not

The overall aim of this dissertation is to apply stated preferences techniques to study the willingness to pay for physician services in six Central and Eastern European countries

Allied health professionals (AHP) are key providers of falls prevention services in the community, insufficient dissemination of best practice evidence amongst AHP has been

From observation of a number of blood test consultations, it can be seen that the amount of knowledge imparted to patients (or indeed demanded by them) is variable. When

To be successful, the community required its members to obey established rules and created networks horizontally and vertically to diverse groups to provide health