• No results found

Company Taxation in New Zealand

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Company Taxation in New Zealand"

Copied!
25
0
0

Loading.... (view fulltext now)

Full text

(1)

Company Taxation in New Zealand

Matt Benge and David Holland

Tax Policy Conference 2009 New Zealand tax reform -

where to next?

(2)

Introduction

¾ In late 1980s NZ adopted clear and simple tax paradigm.

¾ Broad base and low rate income tax.

¾ Supported by full imputation classical

company tax system with rate alignment.

¾ Broad-based and low-rate GST.

¾ Since then external pressures (especially

worldwide reductions in company rate) and

policy decisions have created pressures on

this paradigm .

(3)

Introduction

¾ The government has announced longer term goal of 30:30:30.

¾ Is this achievable or will goal posts keep moving?

¾ If this goal is to be achieved, what do we do in the interim if getting there takes time?

¾ What are key alternatives?

¾ Pros and cons.

(4)

Key facts

¾ NZ highly reliant on corporate tax base (5.8%

of GDP cf OECD average of 3.9%).

¾ NZ geographically isolated but open economy with mobile capital and labour:

inbound FDI 52% of GDP (of which 28% of GDP equity);

inbound portfolio equity 8% of GDP;

in 2000 approx 16% of NZers and 24% of skilled NZers lived abroad. Highest ratio for OECD.

¾ Highly integrated economy with Australia:

approx 55% of inbound and outbound FDI;

free labour market.

(5)

1980s NZ Policy Paradigm

¾ Alignment of company and top personal marginal tax rates.

¾ Reasonably flat personal tax system:

top marginal rate 33% and no tax free threshold.

¾ Broad tax base.

¾ Imputation system:

with alignment, aim was to get reasonable proxy for fully integrated tax system.

but taxation of unimputed dividends: base protection.

¾ International taxation:

company tax is used to tax non-resident on NZ source income;

imputation taxes foreign-source income on

distribution to domestic shareholders. This reduces incentives for multinationals to avoid NZ tax and likely step towards encouraging NZ firms to

invest to maximise national welfare

(6)

Where are we in 2009?

¾ NZ done reasonably well in avoiding base-eroding tax incentives.

¾ International: at company level

move from taxing foreign income on accrual with tax credits to exemption of active income.

¾ Tax rates:

company rate 33% to 30%;

top personal rate 33% to 39% going to 37%;trust tax rate remained at 33%;

PIE rate capped at company rate.

(7)

Effects of Current Rules

¾ Changes to tax rates have made it very easy for people to shelter

incomes from higher personal marginal tax rates:

accumulation of profits in companies;

growth in income of trusts (in 2006, 12.5% of imputation credits flowed to individuals while 24.6% flowed to trusts);

PIEs: heavily marketed to lower tax rates on interest.

¾ This undermines basic paradigm.

(8)

Aggregate Taxable Income of individuals by $1,000 bands of taxable income

0 500 1000 1500 2000 2500

0 5000 10000 15000 20000 25000 30000 35000 40000 45000 50000 55000 60000 65000 70000 75000 80000 85000 90000 95000 1E+05 1E+05 1E+05 1E+05 1E+05 1E+05 1E+05 1E+05 1E+05 1E+05 2E+05

Taxable Income $

Aggregate taxable income

1999 2002 2005 2007

$M

(9)

Determining policy choices

¾ Arguably, necessary condition for current paradigm is reasonable alignment between company and top personal rate.

¾ Does policy of alignment still make sense?

¾ Is alignment achievable and will it continue to be so with international pressures on company rates?

¾ Would a shift from income taxation to

increased taxation under GST be a way to achieve and maintain alignment?

¾ If not, or if achieving alignment takes time

what is the second best (possibly temporary?)

alternative?

(10)

Whither the company tax rate?

¾ In late 1980s, NZ company tax rate was low relative to other OECD countries;

¾ Since then, rates have decline in OECD whereas no change in NZ until 2008/09.

¾ Even given NZ rate reduction, NZ has relatively high company tax rate.

¾ Within OECD company tax rate reductions have been accompanied by base

broadening and company tax as % of GDP has not declined.

¾ What will happen in future?

(11)

Whither the company tax rate?

Historical trends in statutory corporate tax rates (in percent)

25 30 35 40 45 50 55

1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008

Australia EU-15 average New Zealand United States OECD average

Source: OECD

(12)

Whither the company tax rate?

Company income tax rates and revenues (in percent)

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8

1985 1990 1995 2000 2005

0 7 14 21 28 35 42 49 56

OECD average: Company income tax revenue as % of gross domestic product (left axis) New Zealand: Company income tax revenue as % of gross domestic product (left axis) Australia: Company income tax revenue as % of gross domestic product (left axis) OECD average: Company income tax rate (right axis)

New Zealand: Company income tax rate (right axis) Australia: Company income tax rate (right axis) Source: OECD

(13)

Irish system – go for broke!

¾ One possibility would be a deep cut in NZ’s company tax rate;

¾ Encourage capital formation (boosting labour productivity and growth), FDI

(possible technological spillovers), reduce investment distortions, make NZ a more attractive place in which to do business.

¾ Ireland cut its rate to promote FDI.

¾ Could NZ emulate Ireland?

(14)

Irish system – go for broke!

Ireland New Zealand

Small Island Small Island

Educated English-speaking

workforce Educated English-speaking

workforce

Member of EU (GDP $19.2 trillion) Member of CER (GDP $1.2 trillion)

EU subsidies No subsidies

On EU’s doorstep Middle of nowhere Competing against high wage EU

countries for FDI Competing against low wage SE Asian countries for FDI

(15)

Irish system?

¾ Major reduction in company tax rates could boost investment and also TFP growth.

¾ OECD has suggested a cut in company rate from 35% to 30% could boost TFP by 0.4% per annum over 10-year period (OECD, 2008).

¾ Are these results necessarily relevant for NZ?

¾ Would a cut in company rate increase integrity

problems and create a windfall for foreign shareholders requiring higher taxes on NZers?

¾ Extensive other modifications likely to be required.

¾ General conclusion to date has been not to introduce deep company rate cut but should this be

reconsidered?

(16)

Addressing integrity problems

¾ Three key alternatives :

¾ i. alignment approach:

30:30:30 option;

¾ mind-the-gap approach

accept a company tax rate that is lower than higher rates of personal tax;

integrity measures to prevent diversion of personal income to companies;

¾ Nordic approach:

split-rate system with lower flat rate on capital income.

(17)

Alignment approach

¾ Most direct return to original paradigm and arguably preferred approach:

biases in ways income earned removed;

marginal tax rates reduced;

complex distinctions necessary for other approaches eliminated.

¾ Can 30% rate be sustained?

¾ Revenue raisers? Increase in GST and reduction in all marginal rates?

¾ Increasing GST at same time as reducing

marginal income tax rates may not improve

incentives to work but would reduce savings

biases.

(18)

Mind the gap approach

¾ Allows for a lower company rate than top personal marginal rate.

¾ Backed up by rules to prevent deferral of tax on personal wage and investment income earned through companies .

– active/passive distinction in domestic

context;

– beefed up attribution rules.

¾ Allows flexibility and independence of

company and personal tax rates .

(19)

Mind the gap approach

¾ Biggest disadvantage is effects on economic efficiency.

Biases between company and non-company income;

Encouragement to active income over potentially higher return passive income.

¾ Operational issues:

Difficulties in policing borderlines between active and passive income (e.g., real estate).

Would a CGT be necessary?

(20)

Nordic approach

¾ Would apply lower company tax rate to all capital income.

¾ Are we almost there already?

¾ Norway leading proponent but very large gaps between rates of tax on labour and on capital income.

¾ NZ has lower differences between company rate and top personal rate.

¾ Also no payroll tax to fund social security contributions.

¾ Alignment more feasible for NZ.

(21)

Simplified Nordic

¾ Would a possible temporary measure be to extend current PIE capped rate to all capital income using list approach.

¾ Interest and dividend income subject to cap.

¾ Attribution rules to prevent salary-like income being sheltered in closely-held companies.

¾ But no other attempt to prevent labour component of closely-held company’s

income from benefiting from company rate.

¾ Capital component of unincorporated

business income taxed at personal rates.

(22)

Simplified Nordic

¾ Biases would remain.

¾ Different tax rates on business income of companies and unincorporated enterprises.

¾ Passive investment income all subject to cap.

¾ Arbitrage issues?

¾ Reduction in tax rates on capital income would tend to be regressive.

¾ Inefficiencies could be reduced if seen as an intermediate step with more general

personal tax rate reductions over time to

restore alignment.

(23)

Issues for discussion

¾ Paper suggests deep company rate cut is unlikely to be preferred option for NZ.

Is there a best company tax rate?

Is investment more sensitive to high

company rates than to low company rates?

Is there a significant tax base risk from high company rates?

(24)

Issues for discussion

¾ The paper suggests alignment as arguably the best approach.

– Is this true or is there a case for reducing the

company tax rate while keeping personal tax rates higher?

– What is the future direction of the company

tax rate? Is alignment sustainable?

– Could an increase in the rate of GST be used

to fund across-the-board personal rate cuts?

(25)

Issues for discussion

¾ If rate alignment cannot be achieved (or if it can only be achieved with a protracted delay), what is the second-best (possibly temporary) alternative?

– Nordic?

– Mind the gap?

¾ Would a simplified Nordic tax system be interim step towards alignment?

¾ Should investment income be subject to same progressive rates as labour income?

Fairness Trade-offs Efficiency.

References

Related documents

Centricity Cardio Enterprise Solution empowers cardiologists and the cardiovascular department to enhance patient care through full clinical access, improved productivity,

Comparison of bend over sheave fatigue behaviour of different ropesP. ire rope are cornpared ~ith tholie of different wire

Whilst this will ensure that a car benefit charge will not arise if the vehicle is used privately, you may not want to drive the modified vehicle privately in any case.. The

• All phase 3 combination studies should ideally be a 2 years and there may be some advantages in 3 years studies in order to ensure we have a clear idea of durability and do not

There are two main contributions in this paper: (i) the introduc- tion of a probabilistic formulation to incrementally model temporal and spatial context to improve activity

Where a lender is not required to send a continuing disclosure statement because the borrower has agreed to access information on a website under section 21 of the Act, then

The following are considered authority for purposes of determining whether there is substantial authority for the tax treatment of an item: Applicable provisions of the

background noise improvement in quantitative content with respect to standard OSEM fast convergence Qualitative validation:. improved uniformity