• No results found

Venture capital investments and the technological performance of portfolio firms

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Venture capital investments and the technological performance of portfolio firms"

Copied!
17
0
0

Loading.... (view fulltext now)

Full text

(1)

Open Research Online

The Open University’s repository of research publications

and other research outputs

Venture capital investments and the technological

performance of portfolio firms

Journal Item

How to cite:

Lahr, Henry and Mina, Andrea (2016).

Venture capital investments and the technological performance of

portfolio firms. Research Policy, 45(1) pp. 303–318.

For guidance on citations see FAQs.

c

2015 The Authors

Version: Version of Record

Link(s) to article on publisher’s website:

http://dx.doi.org/doi:10.1016/j.respol.2015.10.001

Copyright and Moral Rights for the articles on this site are retained by the individual authors and/or other copyright

owners. For more information on Open Research Online’s data policy on reuse of materials please consult the policies

page.

(2)

ContentslistsavailableatScienceDirect

Research

Policy

j ou rn a l h om ep a g e :w w w . e l s e v i e r . c o m / l o c a t e / r e s p o l

Venture

capital

investments

and

the

technological

performance

of

portfolio

firms

Henry

Lahr

a,b,1

,

Andrea

Mina

c,∗

aCentreforBusinessResearch,CambridgeJudgeBusinessSchool,UniversityofCambridge,TrumpingtonStreet,CambridgeCB21AG,UK bDepartmentofAccountingandFinance,TheOpenUniversity,TheOpenUniversityBusinessSchool,WaltonHall,MiltonKeynesMK76AA,UK cCambridgeJudgeBusinessSchool,UniversityofCambridge,TrumpingtonStreet,CambridgeCB21AG,UK

a

r

t

i

c

l

e

i

n

f

o

Articlehistory: Received11July2014

Receivedinrevisedform13May2015 Accepted6October2015 JELclassification: O31 G24 L26 Keywords: Venturecapital Patenting Selection Signalling Innovation

a

b

s

t

r

a

c

t

Whatistherelationshipbetweenventurecapitalists’selectionofinvestmenttargetsandtheeffectsof

theseinvestmentsonthepatentingperformanceofportfoliocompanies?Inthispaper,wesetouta

modellingandestimationframeworkdesignedtodiscoverwhetherventurecapital(VC)increasesthe

patentingperformanceoffirmsorwhetherthiseffectisaconsequenceofpriorinvestmentselectionbased

onfirms’patentoutput.WedevelopsimultaneousmodelspredictingthelikelihoodthatfirmsattractVC

financing,thelikelihoodthattheypatent,andthenumberofpatentsappliedforandgranted.Fully

accountingfortheendogeneityofinvestment,wefindthattheeffectofVConpatentingisinsignificant

ornegative,incontrasttotheresultsgeneratedbysimplermodelswithindependentequations.Our

findingsshowthatventurecapitalistsfollowpatentsignalstoinvestincompanieswithcommercially

viableknow-howandsuggestthattheyaremorelikelytorationalise,ratherthanincrease,thepatenting

outputofportfoliofirms.

©2015TheAuthors.PublishedbyElsevierB.V.Allrightsreserved.

1. Introduction

Newfirmscanrarelyrelyoninternalcashflowsintheirpursuit

ofentrepreneurialopportunities.Amongthesourcesofexternal

financeavailabletoentrepreneurs,venturecapital(VC)canprovide

notonlythefinancialresourcestheyrequire,butalsoassistance

toenhancethedesign,development,andperformanceofportfolio

companies(Lerner,1995;BergemannandHege,1998;Gompers

and Lerner,2001;De Clercqet al.,2006; Schwienbacher,2008; Cumming,2010).

Amongthedifferentdimensionsofentrepreneurialgrowththat

theliteraturehasnoted,astrongassociationhasbeenidentified

betweenVCinvestmentsandinnovation,oftenmeasuredbythe

firm’spatentingoutput.Aprominentthesisisthatventure

cap-italistsimproveinvesteefirms’innovativeperformancethrough

theirabilityto‘coach’newbusinessesandtonurturethemto

pro-ducegreatertechnologicaloutput(KortumandLerner,2000;Popov

and Roosenboom, 2012).An alternativeargument has received

Correspondingauthor.Tel.:+441223765330.

E-mailaddresses:h.lahr@cbr.cam.ac.uk(H.Lahr),a.mina@jbs.cam.ac.uk

(A.Mina).

1 Tel.:+441908332648.

relativelylessattentionasyet,althoughitsvaliditymayleadto

adifferentconclusion:thatventurecapitalistsareexceptionally

goodatidentifyingnewfirmswithsuperiortechnological

capabili-ties,whichtheyseeasthebestinvestmentopportunities.Seenfrom

thisangle,themostdistinctivetraitofVC,andthereforethemost

salientexplanationforthestrongertechnologicalperformanceof

VC-backedfirmsrelativetootherfirms,wouldbetheventure

capi-talists’superiorselectioncapabilities(BaumandSilverman,2004).

Venturecapitalistsfacearesourceallocationproblem

charac-terisedbyhighriskandstronginformationasymmetries.Inorder

todecreasetheseinformationasymmetries–giventhatpotential

investeeshavelittleornotrackrecordsofmarketperformance–

investorshavetorelyonothersignalsoffirmquality.Theseinclude

theexantepatentingperformanceofpotentialinvestees(Häussler

etal.,2012;Contietal.,2013b;HsuandZiedonis,2013),so

patent-ingcanbeseenasanantecedentofVCinvestmentdecisions,aswell

asalikelyconsequence.Disentanglingtherelationshipbetween

VCinvestment and firms’technologicalperformance involvesa

significanttheoreticalaswellasempiricalchallengebecauseof

endogeneityandreversecausationbetweentheinvestmentand

innovationprocesses.

Thisisanimportantproblem,notonlyfromascholarly

perspec-tivebutalsofromapolicyviewpoint.EventhoughtheVCsector

financesonlyaminorityofnewfirms,itplaysaveryprominent

http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2015.10.001

(3)

roleinpoliciesdesignedtoovercomefinancegapsand togrow

entrepreneurial,innovation-driveneconomies(OECD,2014).This

rolehasnotgoneunquestioned:criticalissueshavebeenraised

aboutscaleandskillsinthedemandandsupplyofventurefinance

(Nightingaleet al.,2009), governance (Lerner, 2009), cyclicality

andstagedistributionofinvestments(KaplanandSchoar,2005;

Cummingetal.,2005;LahrandMina,2014),andtheoverallreturns

andlong-termsustainabilityoftheVCinvestmentmodel(Mason,

2009;Lerner,2011;Mulcahyetal.,2012).Thesemakeitevenmore

importanttogainaclearandaccurateunderstandingofthe

VC-innovationnexus.

InthispaperwemodeltherelationbetweenVCandpatenting

usingsimultaneousequationstoconsiderboththedeterminants

ofVCinvestments,includingpatentsassignalsoffirmquality,and

theeffectofVConfirms’post-investmentpatentingperformance,

controllingfortheirpriorperformance.Weusedatafroman

orig-inalsurveyof3669USandUKcompanies.Weextractinformation

onthe940firmsthatsoughtfinancebetweentheyears2002and

2004andmatchthese recordswithpatent dataextractedfrom

theEuropeanPatentOffice’sWorldwidePatentStatisticalDatabase

(PatStat)fortheperiodsconcurrenttoandfollowingthesurvey

years.Controllingforotherfirmcharacteristics(e.g.size,age,R&D

expenditure,andmarketsize),weestimatesimultaneousmodels

for(1) thelikelihood that firms’patenting activitiespredictVC

investmentsand(2)thelikelihoodthatsuchinvestmentsleadto

patentinginthefollowingperiod.Weemployabivariate

recur-siveprobitmodelanddevelopasimultaneouszero-inflatedPoisson

modelforcountdata,usingbothtocontrolfortheendogenous

natureoftheselectionandcoachingprocesses.

Wedemonstrate that,oncewe accountfor endogeneity,the

effectofVConthesubsequentpatentingoutputofportfolio

compa-niesiseithernegativeorinsignificant.Theseresultsindicatethat,

whileventurecapitalistspositivelyreacttopatentsassignalsof

companieswithpotentially valuableknowledge,confirmingthe

‘selection’hypothesis,thereisnoevidenceofapositiveeffectofVC

investmentonfirms’subsequentpatentingperformance.Itis

plau-siblethatVCwillpositivelyinfluenceotheraspectsofnewbusiness

growth(i.e.commercialisation,marketing,scalingup,etc.),butthe

contributionofVCdoesnotseemtoinvolveincreasinginvestee

firms’technologicaloutputs.Importantly,thefactthatthe

techno-logicalproductivityofafirmmayslowdownafterVCinvestment

doesnotimplythatthefirmwouldbebetteroffwithoutVC:onthe

contrary,aninsignificantornegativeeffectofVConfirmpatenting

suggeststhatventurecapitalistsrationalisetechnologicalsearches

andfocusthefirm’sfiniteresources,includingmanagerial

atten-tion,ontheexploitationofexistingintellectualproperty(IP)rather

thanfurthertechnologicalexploration.

This paper advances our understanding of the financing of

innovativefirms by modelling thedeterminants of investment

choicesbyVCandthepatentingoutputoftheirportfolio

compa-niesatthetimeofandafterVCinvestment.Insodoing,thepaper

alsointroducesanoriginalmethodologythatcandisentanglethe

endogenousrelationshipbetweenVCandpatentingefficiently,and

hasthepotentialforfurtherusesintreatinganalogoustheoretical

structures.

2. VCinvestmentsandpatenting:Theoryandevidence

Investmentsinsmallandmedium-sizedbusinesses,andin

par-ticularnew technology-basedfirms, posespecificchallenges to

capitalmarketsbecausetheyinvolvehighrisksandstrong

infor-mationasymmetries(Lerner,1995;Hall,2002).Fromaninvestor’s

viewpoint,the economic potential of these firmsis difficultto

assess given their short history and the lack of external

sig-nalsabouttheirquality(e.g.auditedfinancialstatements, credit

ratings),orofmarketfeedbackaboutnewproductsandservices

atthetimeofinvestment.Onlyfewinvestorsareableand

will-ingtobackthesebusinesses.Theydosowiththeexpectationof

satisfactoryreturnsbyapplyingaspecificsetofcapabilities,and

oftensector-specificbusinessknowledge,thatenablethemtomake

betterchoicesrelativetocompetinginvestors,handle

technolog-icaland marketuncertainty,and activelyinfluencetheoutcome

oftheirinvestments(Sahlman,1990;Gompers,1995;Hellmann,

1998;Gompersand Lerner,1999,2001;Kaplanand Strömberg, 2003,2004).

IntheextantstudiesthathaveaddressedthelinksbetweenVC

andinnovation,onestreamhasfocusedontheabilityofventure

capitaliststoassistportfoliocompaniesbygivingthemformaland

informaladvice,thusaddingvalueinexcessoftheirfinancial

con-tributions(GormanandSahlman,1989;Sapienza,1992;Busenitz

etal.,2004;ParkandSteensma,2012).Asecondandmorerecent

streamhasinsteademphasisedtheabilityofVCstousepatents

assignalsoffirmqualityandtomakesuperiorchoices,relativeto

otherinvestors,amongtheinvestmentoptionsthatareavailable

tothem.Ifwhatmattersforthesubsequentperformanceof

portfo-liocompaniesisthequalityoftheinitialinvestmentdecision,the

sourceofventurecapitalists’competitiveadvantagerestsontheir

selectioncapabilities,definedastheirabilitytoidentifytheinvestee

companieswiththegreatestgrowthpotential(Dimovetal.,2007;

Yangetal.,2009;Fitzaetal.,2009;ParkandSteensma,2012).In

thefollowingtwosectionswereviewtheargumentsandevidence

behindthesetwoperspectives.

2.1. TheeffectsofVConpatenting

Theproposition that venture capitalistsare ableto increase

firmvaluebeyondtheprovisionoffinancialresourceshasgained

considerable support in the literature (Gorman and Sahlman,

1989;Sahlman,1990;BygraveandTimmons,1992;Lerner,1995; KeuschniggandNielsen,2004;Croceetal.,2013),andisespecially

clearwhentheyarecompared,forexample,tobanksinthesupply

ofexternalfinancingtosmallandmedium-sizedenterprises(Ueda,

2004).Venturecapitalistscantakeactive rolesin manyaspects

ofthestrategic andoperationalconductoftheirportfoliofirms,

includingtherecruitmentofkeypersonnel,businessplan

devel-opment,andnetworkingwithotherfirms,clientsandinvestors,

oftenonthebasisofin-depthknowledgeoftheindustry(Florida

and Kenney,1988; Hellmann and Puri,2000, 2002;Hsu, 2004; Sørensen,2007).

SeveralstudiesfindlinksbetweenVCinvestmentsandfirms’

patentingperformance,andgenerallyinterpretapositive

associa-tionbetweenthetwoasaresultofthe‘value-adding’or‘coaching’

effectsofVC.Oneofthemostprominentstudiesonthistopicis

KortumandLerner’s(2000)paper,inwhichtheauthorsmodeland

estimateapatentproductionfunctioninaninvestmentframework.

Aggregatingpatentnumbersbyindustry,theyfindapositiveand

significanteffectofVCfinancingon(log)patentgrants1.Uedaand

Hirukawa(2008)showthatthesefindingsbecomeevenmore

sig-nificantduringtheventurecapitalboominthelate1990s.However,

estimationsoftotalfactorproductivity(TFP)growthrevealthat

thiswasnotaffectedbyVCinvestment,aresultthatcontrastswith

Chemmanuretal.’s(2011)study,whichrevealsapositiveeffect ofVConTFP.PopovandRoosenboom(2012)alsofindsimilar

posi-tive,althoughweaker,resultsforsucheffectsinEuropeancountries

1Bothpatentingandventurefundingcouldberelatedtounobserved techno-logicalopportunities,therebycausinganupwardbiasinthecoefficientonventure capital,butregressionsthatuseinformationaboutpolicyshiftsinventurefund legislationtoconstructaninstrumentalvariablealsoshowpositiveimpactsofVC investmentsonpatenting(KortumandLerner,2000).

(4)

andindustries.Furtherestimationsofautoregressivemodelsfor

TFPgrowthand patentcountsbyindustryseemtosuggestthat

TFPgrowthispositivelyrelatedtofutureVCinvestment,butthere

isweaker evidencethat VCinvestmentsprecedeanincrease in

patentingattheindustrylevel,andthereareindicationsthatlagged

VCinvestmentsareoftennegativelyrelatedtobothTFPgrowthand

patentcounts(HirukawaandUeda,2008).

Empirical firm-level studies on venture capital investments

tendtoconfirmtheexistenceofapositiverelationbetweenVC

andpatentingperformance(Arqué-Castells,2012;Bertonietal.,

2010;Zhang,2009).Thispattern isnotonlyfoundfor

indepen-dentbutalsoforcorporateventurecapital(Alvarez-Garridoand

Dushnitsky,2012;ParkandSteensma,2012).Lerneretal.(2011)

estimate various models, includingPoisson and negative

bino-mial models, for patents granted and patent citations in firms

thatexperiencedprivateequity-backedleveragedbuyouts(LBOs).

Theyfindanincreasednumberofcitationsforpatentapplications

post-LBOandnodecreaseinpatentoriginalityandgeneralityafter

suchinvestments. Patentcounts do notseem tovary ina

uni-formdirection.AstudybyEngelandKeilbach(2007)foundthat

VC-backedfirmsapplyfortentimesasmanypatentsasmatched

non-VCbacked firms: theauthorsusepropensityand balanced

scorematchingtocompareventure-fundedtonon-VCfunded

Ger-man firms in terms of theirtechnologicaloutputs and growth,

althoughthisdifferencewasonlyweaklysignificant.Casellietal.

(2009)useasimilarmatchingproceduretoassessthedifference

inthepatentingandgrowthperformancesintheventure-backed

IPOsofItalianfirms.Theirresultsshowahigheraveragenumber

ofpatentsintheventure-backedfirmsthanintheircontrolgroup.

Importantly,however,noneofthesestudiesprovidessolutionsto

thefundamentalproblemoftheendogeneityofinvestmentrelative

tofirms’technologicalperformance2.

2.2. Investmentselection

The second hypothesis that might explain the correlation

betweenVCinvestmentandfirms’technologicalperformanceis

thatventurecapitalistshavedistinctiveselectioncapabilities.This

impliesamodellingframeworkinwhichtheinnovativeprofilesof

potentialinvesteefirmsaffecttheprobabilitythattheyreceiveVC

investment.Fromthisperspective,patentscanfunctionassignals

toinvestorsaboutfirmquality(BaumandSilverman,2004;Mann

andSager,2007;Häussleretal.,2012;Audretschetal.,2012;Conti etal.,2013a,b;HsuandZiedonis,2013).

Thereareseveraldimensionstotheinvestmentevaluation

pro-cessemployedbyventurecapitalists(Shepherd,1999),andthere

isgrowinginterestinthetechnologicaldeterminantsofventure

financing.BaumandSilverman(2004)exploredthelinksbetween

VCfinancing,patentapplications,andpatentsgranted.Their

find-ingssuggestthattheamountofVCfinanceobtaineddependson

laggedpatentsgranted andappliedfor,R&D expenditures,R&D

employees,governmentresearchassistance,theamountof

sector-specificventurecapital,horizontalandverticalalliances,andthe

investeefirmbeingauniversityspin-off.Ageisnegativelyrelated

toventurecapital,asarenetcashflows,diversification,and

indus-tryconcentration.Mann and Sager (2007) confirmthe positive

impactofpatentingonVC-relatedperformancevariables,including

thenumberoffinancingrounds,totalinvestmentandexitstatus.

2Tothebestofourknowledge,Croceetal.(2013)istheclosestattempttodate toaddresssampleselectionproblemsinthecontextofthevalue-added hypoth-esis.However,thisinterestingstudydoesnotconsideranyinnovationindicators anditsanalysisofportfoliocompanies’productivitygrowthislimitedbytheuse ofonlyasmallsetofbasicfirmcharacteristics.OurpaperdoesnotfocusonTFP estimates—insteadweexploreinsomedetailthetechnologicaloutputoffirmsin relationtoentrepreneurialfinancedecisions.

Similarly,astart-upfirm’spriorpatentingattractgreateramounts

ofVCfundsinCaoandHsu’s(2011)studyofventure-backedfirms.

Häussleretal.(2012)elaborateonSpence’s(2002)signalling

theorytoarguethatthefoundersofentrepreneurialfirmsare

bet-terinformedaboutthequalityoftheventurethanarepotential

investors,andthattheyusepatentsascommunicationdevicesto

bridgethisinformationgap.Patentsareeffectivesignalsof

qual-ityonthegroundsthat, astheyareproducedat acost (inthis

casethefeesassociatedwiththepatentingprocess),low-quality

agentswilltendtobeweededout.Theirempiricalanalysis

con-firmsthatpatentapplicationshaveapositiveeffectonthehazard

rateofVCfundinginasampleofBritishandGermanbiotech

com-panies. Thesefindings resonate withprior resultspresentedby

EngelandKeilbach(2007),whoseprobitmodellingofVC

invest-mentrevealsapositiveassociationwithpatentsandthefounder’s

humancapital. Alonga similarlineof enquiry –albeit setin a

broaderPenrosian framework thanthat usedby Häussleretal.

(2012)–HsuandZiedonis(2013)analyseVC-financedstart-ups

intheUSsemiconductorsector.Theyshowthat,bybridging

infor-mationasymmetries,patentsincreasethelikelihoodofobtaining

initialcapitalfromaprominentVC,andhavepositiveeffectson

fundraisingandIPOpricing(conditionalonIPOexit).

Bybringingthesestreamsofcontributionstogether,weaimto

answerthequestion:Doesventurecapitalpositivelycontributeto

thepatentingperformanceoffirmsorisitaconsequenceof

ven-turecapitalists’abilitytoidentifythebestcompaniesatthetimeof

investment?Resultsbasedonfirm-levelinformationaremixed,

which suggeststhatpositive findingscouldbeatleastpartially

drivenbyVC’sselectionofcompaniesonthebasisoftheircurrent

patentoutput.Wecanonlyshedlightontheeffectsofcoaching

vis-à-vistheselectionfunctionofVCifwetakeintoaccountthe

endogeneityoftherelationbetweenVCinvestmentandthe

tech-nologicalperformanceoffirms.Ourresearchstrategyisthereforeto

model,test,andevaluateinasimultaneoussetting(1)theeffectof

VConthepatentingperformanceofportfoliofirmspostinvestment

and(2)theeffectoffirms’patentingperformanceontheprobability

ofattractingVC.

3. Dataandmethodology

3.1. Data

ThispaperbuildsonauniquecomparativesurveyofU.K.andU.S.

businessescarriedoutjointlybytheCentreforBusinessResearch

attheUniversityofCambridgeandtheIndustrialPerformance

Cen-teratMITin2004–2005.ThebasisforthesamplingwastheDun&

Bradsheet(D&B)database,whichcontainscompany-specific

infor-mationdrawnfromvarioussources,includingCompaniesHouse,

Thomson Financial, and press and trade journals3. The sample

coveredallmanufacturingandbusinessservicesectors,andwas

stratifiedbysectorandemploymentsize(10–19;20–49;50–99;

100–499;500–999;1000–2999;and3000+),withlarger

propor-tionstaken in the smallersize bands,as in both countries the

vastmajority(over98%)offirmsemployfewerthan100people.

ThedatawerecollectedviatelephonesurveysbetweenMarchand

November2004(responserates:18.7%fortheU.S.and17.5%for

theU.K.),followedbyapostalsurveyoflargefirmsinspring2005

leadingtoatotalsampleof1540U.S.firmsand2129U.K.firms.

3ThechoiceoftheDun&Bradstreetdatabasewasmotivatedbyitsbroadcoverage ofsmallfirms,whicharekeyforstudyingventurecapitalinvestments.Good cover-ageofSMEsisalsothereasonwhytheEuropeanCentralBankusesthisdatabasefor itssurveyontheaccesstofinanceofSMEsintheeuroarea(SAFE);seehttp://www.

(5)

Werestrictoursampletofirmsthatactivelysoughtfinance

dur-ingthetwo yearspriortobeinginterviewed,whichproduces a

workingsampleof940firms(513intheU.S.and427intheU.K.).

ThesurveylistsVCfundsandbusinessangelsaspossiblesources

ofexternalfinance.Despitesomedifferencesinstagesandsizes

ofinvestments,geographicproximity,andmotivationfor

invest-ments(Ehrlichetal.,1994), bothventurecapitalistsandangels

spendconsiderabletimewithfirms’managementteams,andmake

substantialnon-financialcontributionsinadditiontotheir

finan-cialcommitments,includingworkinghands-onintheirday-today

operations(Kerret al., 2014;Haines et al.,2003; Harrison and

Mason,2000).Sincebothformalandinformalventurecapitalists

canperformsimilarfunctionsfromourstudy’sviewpoint,wepool

observationsfor thesetwo classes of activeinvestors, although

when we perform robustness tests with separate samples,the

resultsareconsistentwithourmainanalyses(Section5.3).

Infor-mationabouttheeventofaVCinvestmententersourmodelsasan

endogenousbinaryvariable.

Firms answered the survey questions almost completely,

althoughminorgapsinthedatawouldhavepreventedusfrom

usingabout10% ofthesurvey responses.In ordertoavoid the

lossofobservationsduetomissingvalues,weuserandom

regres-sionimputationtoapproximatethem(GelmanandHill,2006).The

numberofsuchimputationsisgenerallyverylow—alwayslessthan

2%pervariable.Wheredependentvariablevaluesaremissing,we

dropthoseobservations.

PatentdataaretakenfromtheEuropeanPatentOffice’s(EPO)

WorldwidePatentStatistical Database(PatStat), which contains

informationon68.5millionpatent applicationsby17.3million

assigneesandinventorsfrom1790to2010.Sincetherearenofirm

identifiersavailableinPatStat,wematchpatentinformationtoour

surveydatabyfirmname.Weconsiderfirms’globalpatent

port-folios,andcountallapplicationstodifferentpatentauthoritiesfor

similaroroverlappingknow-howasmultiplepatentingevents.To

alignpatentdatawiththethreeyearperiodaddressedinthe

sur-vey,wecountthenumberofpatentsappliedforandgrantedwithin

athree-yearperiodpriortotheinterview(calculatedfromexact

surveyresponsedates),anddetermineeachfirm’spatentingstatus

fromthisnumber.Morespecifically,weuseapplicationfilingand

publicationsdatesforthefirstgrantofanapplicationtodetermine

thetimingsofpatentingevents.Forourdependentvariables,we

countapplicationsandgrantsforthewholepost-surveyperiodin

ordertocapturethelong-termeffectsofVCinvestment.Finally,

weincludeadummyvariableforthefirmbeingbasedintheUSor

theUKtocontrolfordifferentpropensitiestopatent–and

likeli-hoodofgrant–indifferentdomesticinstitutionalenvironments.

Weabstainfromusingforwardcitation-weightedindicators for

patents,acontrolforpatentqualitythatisespeciallyusefulin

stud-iesofperformance,becausesuchcitationsmaybeaffectedbythe

likelihoodofinvestment,andmaythusintroduceafurthersource

ofendogeneityintothisanalyticalcontextthatwouldbeimportant

toavoid.

Table1showsdescriptivestatisticsforoursamplefirms’

patent-ingactivitiesandourindependentvariables.146firmsfromour

sampleappliedforpatentsduringthethree-yearsurveyperiod(t),

and168filedpatentapplicationsinthenextperiod(t+1).We

iden-tifiedpatentgrantsin115and141firmsintheserespectiveperiods.

96firmsgainedventurecapitalorbusinessangelfinancinginabout

equalproportionsinthetwoyearspriortothesurvey.Asimple

cross-tabulationofindicatorsforVCfinancingandforpatenting

activityatt(seeTable2)highlightsthestronglinkbetween

ven-turecapitalandpatenting.Itshowsthat56.2%ofVC-financedfirms

appliedforpatentsinanyoftheperiods,whereasonly18.2%of

thosewithoutVCfundingdidso.Butthispicturebeginstolook

differentwhenweconsiderchangesinthepatentingstatusacross

periods.Inthenon-VCfinancedgroup,firmsseemtostartpatenting

attimet+1moreoftenthantheystopapplyingafterpatentingat

timet.Incontrast,thenumbersoffirmsintheVC-financedgroup

thatstart patentingat timet+1balancethose thatdiscontinue

theirpatentingactivitiesafterperiodt4.Includingadditional

con-trolvariablesinourmultivariateanalysesgivesusamuchmore

preciseassessmentofthesestatetransitions.

Theinclusionofexplanatoryvariablesbuildsonpriorstudies

intotherelationshipbetweenVCandpatenting,whichhaveoften

usedaverylimitednumberofco-determinants,sometimesonly

R&Dexpenditures.Weextendthescopeoftherelevantpredictors

forthepropensitytopatent,ofwhichR&Dintensityisthepreferred

choiceaccordingtostandard practiceintheliterature(Scherer,

1965,1983;PakesandGriliches,1980;Pakes,1981;Hausmanetal.,

1984).Since prior research hasused various measures for this

intensity,includingthelogofR&D expenditures,R&D

expendi-turesscaledbysizevariables,orthenumberofR&Demployees,

wechooseasuitablecombinationoftheseindicators.Weproxyfor

sizebytakingthelogarithmofemploymentandcontrolforR&D

intensitybyincludingthepercentageofR&Dstaffandadummy

indicating thepresence ofR&D expenditures. Thisallows usto

avoidtheuseofmultiplesize-dependentmeasures,sincevariables

entertheexpectedmeaninPoissonspecificationsmultiplicatively.

Furthervariablescontrolforage,countryandindustry.Following

Scherer(1983),weusetheamountofinternationalsalestomeasure

marketsizeandcontrolforindustryconcentrationbythenumberof

competitors.WemeasureCEOeducationbyadummyvariable

indi-catingwhethertheCEOhasauniversitydegreeornot.Thelength

oftheaverageproductdevelopmenttimeinthefirms’principal

productmarketisalsocontrolledfor,sinceitarguablyplaysarole

inattractinginvestment(HellmannandPuri,2000).Finally,given

thehighlycumulativenatureoftechnicalchange(Dosi,1988)we

includelaggedpatentapplicationsandgrantsasproxiesforthe

firm’sknowledgestocksthatitusestoproducenewpatents5.

3.2. Modelsandestimation

The structure of firms’ patenting decisions presents several

econometric challenges. Previous research shows that the vast

majorityoffirmsdonotpatent,whichcausesobservationsofzero

patentsin alargeproportion offirms leadingin turntomodel

instabilityanderrordistributions thatdo notmeet themodel’s

assumptions if these excess zeroes are not properly addressed

(Boundetal.,1984;Hausmanetal.,1984).Atthesametime,

unob-servableheterogeneityis highlylikelytobecorrelated between

VC investment and patenting performance: for example, firms

mightdisclosepatentingactivitiestoprospectiveinvestors,which

increasesthelikelihoodthatweobserveVCinvestmentsin

com-bination with more patenting in the future. When using VC

investment to explain patenting, this endogeneity complicates

modelestimationandmaymakeitanalyticallyintractable6.

We suggest that patenting involves a two-step process, in

which firmsfirstdecidewhethertousepatenting asa suitable

IPprotectionstrategy and then producepatentsaccording toa

Poisson orsimilardistribution (seeFig.1).Followingthis logic,

wemodelpatentingactivityasabinaryvariablethatdependson

firmandindustrycharacteristicsandaugmentourmodelswithan

4Lesssurprisingly,forpatentgrantstheproportionoffirmsthatstart receiv-inggrantscomparedwiththosethatstopafterreceivingatleastonegrantinthe previousperiodishigherforVC-fundedfirms.

5Inclusionoflaggeddependentvariablesalsohelpstoaccountforunobserved heterogeneity.

6Asimilarchallenge,also associated with mixedempirical evidence, char-acterisesstudiesofVCinvestmentsandthefinancialperformanceofportfolio companies.Confront,forexample,SteierandGreenwood(1995)andBusenitzetal. (2004)withFitzaetal.(2009),andMatusikandFitza(2012).

(6)

Table1

Descriptivestatistics.

Variable Mean Median Std.Dev. Min Max Description

Anyapplicationsint+1 0.179 0 0.383 0 1

Patentapplicationsint+1 4.118 0 34.241 0 779 Numberofpatentapplicationsbythefirmintheperiodafter

thesurvey

Anygrantsint+1 0.150 0 0.357 0 1

Patentgrantsint+1 2.746 0 30.337 0 889 Numberofpatentgrantstothefirmintheperiodafterthe

survey

Anyapplicationsint 0.155 0 0.362 0 1

Patentapplicationsint 3.266 0 25.347 0 526 Numberofpatentapplicationsbythefirmintheperiodthree

yearspriortothesurvey

Anygrantsint 0.122 0 0.328 0 1

Patentgrantsint 1.176 0 9.972 0 273 Numberofpatentgrantstothefirmintheperiodthreeyears

priortothesurvey

VCinvestment 0.102 0 0.303 0 1 Thefirmobtainedformalorinformalventurecapitalinthe

three-yearperiodpriortothesurvey

Age(log) 2.937 2.996 0.858 0.693 5.720 Thenaturallogarithmofthefirm’sageinyears.

Size(log(employees)) 3.848 3.714 1.059 1.099 6.804 Thenaturallogarithmofthenumberofemployeesinthemost

recentfinancialyear

U.S.firm 0.546 1 0.498 0 1 ThefirmhasitsheadquartersintheUnitedStates.Dummy

variable

Medium-hightechmanuf. 0.310 0 0.463 0 1 Thefirmisamedium-hightechmanufacturingfirmaccording

totheOECD(2005)Science,TechnologyandIndustry Scoreboard

Medium-lowtechmanuf. 0.381 0 0.486 0 1 Thefirmisamedium-lowtechmanufacturingfirm

R&Dservices&software 0.117 0 0.322 0 1 ThefirmisanR&Dserviceorsoftwarefirm.

Otherservices 0.153 0 0.360 0 1 ThefirmisaservicefirmotherthanR&Dorsoftware

Otherindustry 0.039 0 0.195 0 1 ThefirmoperatesunderaSICcodenotcoveredabove

R&Dexpend.(yes/no) 0.732 1 0.443 0 1 ThefirmhasR&Dexpenditures.Dummyvariable

R&Dstaff 0.073 0 0.175 0 1 Full-timeR&Dstaffasaproportionoftotalstaff.

CEOhasadegree 0.637 1 0.481 0 1 Thefirm’sChiefExecutiveorMDhasadegree.Dummyvariable

Marketsize 1.747 2 0.912 0 3 Sizeofthefirm’smarket.Codedasordinal0=local,

1=regional,2=national,3=international,treatedascardinal

Competitors(log) 1.987 1.792 1.012 0 6.909 Numberofcompaniesthatthefirmregardsasserious

competitorsplusone,inlogs

Productdev.time 0.971 1 1.048 0 4 Averagetimeittakestodevelopanewproductfrom

conceptiontothemarket.Codedasordinal0=lessthan6 monthsto4=morethan5years,treatedascardinal

Table2

Venturecapitalandpatentingstatus.

NoVC(n=844):Applicationsint+1 VC(n=96):Applicationsint+1 NoVC(n=844):Grantsint+1 VC(n=96):Grantsint+1

Applicationsint No(%) Yes(%) No(%) Yes(%) No(%) Yes(%) No(%) Yes(%)

No 81.8 6.0 43.8 11.5 85.4 4.7 51.0 15.6

Yes 3.4 8.8 11.5 33.3 2.7 7.1 6.3 27.1

Notes.Thistablepresentsthefractionoffirmsineachpresentandfuturepatentingstatusdependentonventurecapitalinvestment.Rowentriesarethenumberoffirms withanynumberofpatentapplicationsattimet.Columnsshowthenumberoffirmsapplyingfororbeinggrantedanynumberofpatents.

Fig.1.Modelframework.Notes.Dependentvariablesareventurecapitalinvestmentattimetandthenumberofpatentapplicationsorgrantsattimet+1.Inthebinary bivariatecase,“Patents(yes/no):”measureswhetherweobserveanynumberofpatentsforthefirmattimet+1.Inzero-inflatedPoissonmodelsthatalsoincludethenumber ofpatentsatt+1,thisvariableindicatesfirms’latentpatentingstatus.

(7)

endogenousbinaryvariablethatindicateswhetherornotafirm receivesventurecapitalfinancing.Insteadofrelyingon propen-sityscorematchingorcomparablealgorithmstoidentifyacontrol groupofnon-VCbackedfirms,wehavetheadvantagethatwecan workwith‘treatment’and‘control’datathataregenerated contem-poraneouslybythesurvey7.Ourdataallowustoidentifyfirmsthat

soughtexternalfinance,andthoseofthemthatobtainedventure

finance.Theexplicitconsiderationoffinance-seekingbehaviours,

usuallyneglectedintheliterature,strengthensthequalityofour

sampleandtheprecisionofourresults.

Weestimatetwo setsofsimultaneousequations:Inthefirst

set,whichcontainstwoprobitequationsforpatentingandventure

capitalinvestments,weignoreinformationaboutthenumberof

patentsandtreatfirms’patentingbehavioursasbinaryoutcomes.

Inthesecondsetweintroducethenumberofpatentsina

zero-inflatedPoissonmodel.

Thepatentingequationintherecursivebivariatesystemis

Pati,t+1=I

Xit0+1Patit+2ln (PatNit)+1VCit+εit>0

, (1)

wherePatitisadummyvariableindicatingwhetherfirmiapplied

foroneormorepatentsor,dependingoncontext,wasgrantedat

leastonepatentperiodt.PatNitdenotesthenumberofpatent

appli-cationsorpatentsgranted.TheindicatorfunctionI(·)equalsoneif

theconditioninparenthesesholdsandzerootherwise.Sincepatent

applicationsandgrantscanbezero–inwhichcasethenatural

log-arithmwouldnotexist–wesetln(PatNit)tozeroanduseadummy

variable(Patit)toindicatepatentingstatus.Endogenousventure

capitalinvestmentiscapturedbyanindicatorvariable(VCit),and

Xitrepresentsexogenousvariables.Thesimultaneouslydetermined

venturecapitalinvestmentis:

VCit=I

Zitˇ0+ˇ1Patit+ˇ2ln (PatNit)+it>0

, (2)

whereZitisavectorofexogenousexplanatoryvariableswhichcan

containsomeoralloftheelementsinXit.Endogeneityofventure

capitalfinancingisaccountedforbyallowingarbitrarycorrelation

betweentheerrorterms.Sincevarianceoferrortermsisnot

iden-tifiedinbinarymodels,theerrortermsεitanditarenormalisedto

haveavarianceofunity.

Asimilarsimultaneousmodelstructurecanbeusedtopredict

thenumberofpatents.Sincepatentdatashowalargenumberof

non-patentingfirms,wemodelthisempiricalregularity usinga

zero-inflatedPoissondistribution.Inthismodel,firmsself-select

intothepatentingregime,andathirdequationmodelsthenumber

ofpatentapplicationsorgrantsproducedaccordingtoaPoisson

distribution.AsinLambert’s(1992)zero-inflatedPoissonmodel,

thenumberofpatentsisdistributedas:

PatNi,t+1 =

0 withprobability pit+ (1−pit)e−it k withprobability (1−pit)e−ititk/k!, k=1,2,... (3)

7 ThisapproachdiffersfromParkandSteensma’s(2012)andContietal.’s(2013b). Incontrasttothesestudies,wehavedataonfirmsthatreceivedinvestmentandfirms thatdidnot,becauseoursamplingwasnotguidedbyVCinvestmentevents.This enablesustospecifyanappropriatetestforselection(investment)insteadofatest forthetypeofinvestmentafirmmayhavereceivedwhenallthefirmsintheirsample havereceivedsomeinvestments(i.e.wherethereisnocounterfactualof‘noVC investment’).Contietal.(2013a),instead,haveno-VCinvestmentcounterfactuals attheirdisposal,buttheirfocusisdifferent,astheyareinterestedintherelative sensitivityofVCandbusinessangelinvestorstoheterogeneousinvestmentsignals. Moreover,theyoptforamoretraditionaltwo-stageleastsquareslinearprobability modeltotreatendogeneityofinvestment.

Thelikelihoodthatafirmchoosesnottopatentinthenextperiod

is pit=I

Xit0+1Patit+2ln (PatNit)+1VCit+εit

, (4)

whiletheconditionalmeanofthePoissonprocessinthepatenting

stateis it=exp

Xitı0+ı1Patit+ı2ln (PatNit)+NVCit+ωit

(5)

Anovelfeatureofourmodelisthatafirm’slikelihoodof

obtain-ingventurecapitalisdeterminedbyanadditionalequation:

VCit=I

Zitˇ0+ˇ1Patit+ˇ2ln (PatNit)+it>0

(6)

asinthebivariateProbitcaseabove.

Weallowforarbitrarycontemporaneouscorrelationbetween

it and εit,as well asbetween it and ωit, which are assumed

tofollowbivariatenormaldistributions.Specifyingthemodelin

thiswayallowsforcorrelationbetweenheterogeneityinexpected

meansofpatentcounts,thedecisiontopatentandVCfinancing.The

varianceofindividual-levelerrors(ωit)introducesafree

parame-terthataccountsforover-dispersioninPoissonmodels(Miranda

andRabe-Hesketh,2006).Identificationinsemiparametric

mod-elsofbinarychoicevariablesoftenreliesonexclusionrestrictions

(Heckman,1990;Taber,2000)—inourparametriccase,however,

thefunctionalformissufficientforidentification.Infact,imposing

additionalrestrictionsonourmodelcouldcausespuriousresults,

sincevariablesincludedintheVCequationbutexcludedfromthe

patentingequationswouldaffecttheoutcomeequationthrough

VCitif thosevariables werenottrulyindependentfrom

patent-ing.Wethereforechoosetheexogenousvariablestobeidentical

inallequations(Xit=Zit).Section5.4describesadditionalresults

obtainedfromrobustnessteststhatuseexclusionrestrictionsin

thepatentingequation(s).

Inthefollowingsectionwepresenttheresultsofbivariate

recur-siveprobit modelsfor VCfinancing and patenting (i.e., results

forthesimultaneousestimationofEqs.(1)and(2)andthenthe

resultsweobtainfromthesystemofequationscompletewiththe

zero-inflatedPoissonmodel(i.e.,Eqs.(3)to(6)),estimatedby

max-imumsimulatedlikelihood(GouriérouxandMonfort,1996;Train,

2009)8. We alsoreport results of zero-inflated Poisson models

thatincludeinformationaboutthenumberofpatents,butexclude

simultaneousVCinvestmentasourbaselineresultsforthe

com-pletesystemofequations(seeTable5).Astermsofcomparisons

andtoshowhowkeyresultsdifferwhenendogeneityisnottaken

intoaccount,weincluderesultsofindependent(single-equation)

probitmodelsasrobustnesschecks(Table6).

4. Results

Wefindthatthecorrelationsbetweenventurecapital

invest-ment and subsequent patenting are substantial and highly

significant, ranging between 0.21 for (log) patent applications

and 0.26 for a dummyvariablemeasuring whethera firm was

grantedanypatentsafterreceivingVCinvestment.Thispositive

linkcouldbeduetotechnologicalcoachingorselection.Aswe

con-structincreasinglycompletemodelsfortherelationbetweenVC

investmentandpatenting,thecoachingeffectdisappears.Table3

presentstheresultsfromoursimultaneousmodelthatjointly

pre-dictspatentingandventurecapitalinvestment.

8Weusesubscriptstandt+1todistinguishbetweentheperiodsconcurrent toandfollowingthesurvey.Weuse200randomdrawsinallmodelsestimated bymaximumsimulatedlikelihood.Furtherestimationdetails,includinglikelihood functionandMSLmethodology,areavailablefromtheauthors.

(8)

Table3

PatentingandVCinvestment—simultaneousequations.

Dependentvariableinpatentingequation Applicationsint+1 Grantsint+1 Grantsint+1

Model 1 2 3

Dependentvariableinpatentingequation Patenting(yes/no) VCinvestment Patenting(yes/no) VCinvestment Patenting(yes/no) VCinvestment

VCinvestment −0.673(0.34)** 0.175(0.52) 0.444(0.37)

Patentapplications(log) 0.455(0.12)*** 0.095(0.08) 0.568(0.13)*** 0.098(0.08)

Patentapplications>0 1.059(0.21)*** 0.609(0.20)*** 1.635(0.22)*** 0.614(0.20)***

Patentgrants(log) 0.534(0.16)*** 0.170(0.12)

Patentgrants>0 1.206(0.22)*** 0.434(0.23)*

Age(log) 0.083(0.08) −0.344(0.09)*** 0.010(0.11) 0.344(0.09)*** 0.088(0.10) 0.342(0.09)***

Size(log(employees+1)) 0.155(0.06)*** 0.197(0.07)*** 0.058(0.07) 0.213(0.07)*** 0.027(0.07) 0.206(0.07)***

U.S.firm 0.053(0.14) −0.334(0.13)** 0.279(0.17)* 0.327(0.14)** 0.320(0.18)* 0.332(0.14)**

Medium-hightechmanuf. 0.095(0.29) −0.226(0.29) −0.084(0.34) −0.203(0.30) −0.254(0.27) −0.251(0.28)

Medium-lowtechmanuf. −0.223(0.30) −0.375(0.29) −0.463(0.35) −0.389(0.29) −0.566(0.28)** 0.400(0.29)

R&Dservices&software −0.131(0.33) 0.271(0.30) −0.152(0.40) 0.276(0.30) −0.260(0.35) 0.267(0.29)

Otherservices 0.068(0.32) −0.098(0.31) −0.757(0.40)* 0.127(0.31) 0.782(0.36)** 0.132(0.31)

R&Dexpend.(yes/no) 0.468(0.18)*** 0.424(0.21)** 0.318(0.20) 0.439(0.21)** 0.467(0.21)** 0.425(0.22)*

R&Dstaff(in%) 0.356(0.35) 0.701(0.33)** 0.755(0.44)* 0.838(0.32)*** 0.134(0.44) 0.650(0.33)**

CEOhasadegree 0.145(0.14) 0.363(0.17)** 0.201(0.16) 0.347(0.17)** 0.214(0.17) 0.344(0.17)**

Marketsize 0.260(0.09)*** 0.191(0.09)** 0.319(0.10)*** 0.203(0.09)** 0.280(0.11)*** 0.206(0.09)**

Productdev.time 0.160(0.06)*** 0.043(0.07) 0.138(0.06)** 0.055(0.07) 0.120(0.07) 0.045(0.07)

Competitors(log) −0.125(0.06)** 0.084(0.08) 0.119(0.06)* 0.087(0.08) 0.203(0.07)*** 0.075(0.07) Intercept −3.070(0.46)*** 1.845(0.44)*** 2.313(0.54)*** 1.903(0.43)*** 2.408(0.52)*** 1.905(0.44)*** Observations 940 940 940 Log-Likelihood −486.4 −454.7 −393.3 Chi-sq.test 354.1 296.1 374.8 P-value 0.000 0.000 0.000 (vit,εit)

p-Valuefor(Waldtest) 0.010 0.130 0.002

Pseudo-R2 0.334 0.357 0.444

Notes.Thistablepresentsbivariaterecursiveprobitmodelsforpatentapplications,patentgrantsandforthelikelihoodofobservingventurecapitalinvestments.Robust standarderrorsareinparentheses.

Significancelevels:***p<0.01;**p<0.05;*p<0.1.

4.1. Patenting

Venture capital does not increase patenting activity (Table 3—first column of Models 1–3)—rather, it decreases

thelikelihoodofafirmfilingpatentapplicationsafterthe

invest-ment, in contrastto prior firm level (e.g.Arqué-Castells, 2012)

and industry level studies (e.g.Kortum and Lerner, 2000) that

foundpositiveassociations.Theeffectonfuturepatentgrantsis

insignificant.Correlationsofunobservedeffects inthepatenting

and selection equations are positive, supporting ourmodelling

strategy.

Wefindstrongpersistenceinpatenting,forbothapplications

andgrants.Iffirmspatentinoneperiod,ittendstodosointhe

next.Anindicatorforprior-periodpatentingissignificantinall

specifications,whileapplyingfororreceivingalargenumberof

patentsinoneperiodincreasesthelikelihoodofobservingatleast

onepatentinthenext.Theseeffectscanbeinterpretedintwoways:

Ontheonehand,priorpatentingcanbeaproxyforunobserved

heterogeneitybetweenfirmsin theirabilitytoproduce

innova-tions(othervariablesinourmodelsmightnotcaptureallaspectsof

firms’internalprocessesandexternalmarketcharacteristicsthat

leadtopatentingbehaviour).Ontheotherhand,knowledge–in

theformofexistingpatents–isaninputfornewpatents.

Exist-ingpatentscansignalthesizeoffirms’knowledgestocks,which

areotherwisedifficulttomeasure.Astheseproductivecapacity

stocksdepreciateovertime,itisreasonabletoassumethatrecent

additions tothepatent stockare thebestpredictorsof present

and future patenting activities, which is essentially what we

find.

StrongevidenceoftheproductivityeffectsofR&Dexpenditures

isconsistentwithpriorstudies(Cohen,2010).Thepercentageof

R&Dstaffweaklypredictspatentingactivity,onlyshowing

posi-tivecoefficientsinmodel2.Humancapital–asmeasuredbythe

CEO’seducation– doesnotappear toincreasethelikelihoodof

patent applicationsorgrants.Firmage doesnot seem toaffect

patenting9,whilefirmsizehasapositiveeffectonfuture

appli-cations,butnoeffectongrants,asBoundetal.(1984)found.Other

variablesdonotexplainthevariationsinpatentingthatsizewould

explainiftheywereexcluded.Collinearity islowinourmodels

(varianceinflationfactorsarewellbelow5),anddropping

signif-icantvariablesfromthemodelsdoesnotsignificantlychangethe

effectofsize.Industryeffectscollectivelyexplainpatenting,but

ontheirownareonlyweakpredictors.SignificantWaldtests

con-firmtheimportanceofcontrollingforindustryeffects.However,

individualeffectsarerarelysignificantinourpatentingmodels,

asmightbeexpected,sinceourestimationsincludedetailed

firm-level variables suchasR&D and humancapital. Unsurprisingly,

firmscategorisedasmedium-hightechnologymanufacturingtend

toapplyforpatentsmoreoftenandobtaingrantsmorefrequently

thanlow-techmanufacturingandservicefirms.

FirmsbasedintheU.S.exhibitahigherchanceofsuccess(in

termsoftheirapplicationsbeinggranted)thanthoselocatedin

theU.K.,anindicationofknowninstitutionaldifferencesbetween

the two countries’ patenting regimes10. As expected,patenting

activityisstronglyassociatedwithproductmarketcharacteristics.

Firmsthatoperatenationallyorinternationallyaremorelikelyto

engageinformalIPprotectionthanlocalorregionalfirms.Thereis

9Ifpatentingwastodependonfirmage,wewouldexpectastart-upeffectearlyin thelifeoffirmsthatarefoundedtoexploitsometechnologicalopportunity.Wetried adummyvariableindicatingwhetherafirmwasonlyfoundedduringthesample periodbutfoundnoinfluenceonpatentingactivity.

10Thenon-obviousnessstandardinU.S.patentlawattheapplicationstagehas beenweakened,leadingtothegrantofpatentsonincreasingnumbersoftrivial inventions(Barton,2003;Gallini,2002).Structuraldifferencesinpatenting pro-cessesalsoaffectpatentopposition,re-examinationandrevocationrates,which aresignificantlyhigherforEuropeanandU.K.patentsthanforU.S.patents(Harhoff andReitzig,2004;Grahametal.,2002).

(9)

littledifferencebetweenmodelsforfutureapplicationsandgrants.

Productsthatneedlongleaddevelopmenttimesaremoreoften

protectedbypatentsthanthosewithashorttimetomarket.Again,

thisisreasonablefromtheviewpointofafirmthatneedsmore

pro-tectionoverlongerR&Dcycles.Finally,protectionfromimitation

shouldbemoreprominentinindustriescharacterisedbyintense

competition, although it is possible that firms in concentrated

marketstrytodeterentrythroughthestrategicuseofpatenting

(Scherer,1983).WhileScherer(1983)onlyfindsevidenceforalink

betweenindustryconcentrationandthenumberofpatentsin

mod-elsthatdonotcontrolforsectors,BaumandSilverman(2004)find

fewerpatentsinconcentratedindustries.Incontrast,theeffectof

highcompetitiononpatentingisnegativeinourmodels11.

4.2. VCinvestment

Afirm’sknowledgestockisagoodpredictorofventurecapital

investment(seeTable3).PatentingattractsVCinvestments—more

specifically,itisthefactthatacompanyispatent-active,notthe

number of applicationsor grants, that predicts VC investment.

Resultsareparticularlystrongfortheapplicationindicator,which

signalsstronginnovationpotentialinportfoliocompanies.

R&Dexpenditures and R&D stafflevelsare both strong

pre-dictors of VC investments, as is the CEO’s education level. VC

involvementismorelikelytobefoundinyoungfirms,echoingthe

findingsofpriorresearch.Interestingly,however,venturecapital

fundsappeartoinvestinlargerfirmsmoreoftenthaninsmaller

ones.Thisfindingcanbeexplainedbyinterpretingsizeasa

mea-sureofinvestmentrisk,withverysmallfirmstypicallybeingmore

opaquethanlargerones.Butitisalsoimportanttobearinmindthat

oursampleincludesfirmswith10to1000employees,andis

there-foreasampleofSMEs,asdemandedforastudyofVCinvestment.

Industryeffectspointtoapreferenceamongventureinvestorsfor

R&Dservicesorsoftware.Firmsoperatinginlarger(international)

marketsseemtobeattractiveinvestments,whilecoefficientsfor

theintensityofcompetitionareinsignificant.Firmswithlong

prod-uctdevelopmenttimesare neithermorenorless likelyto gain

venturecapital12.

4.3. Two-stagepatenting—Patentcounts,patenting,andventure capital

The large number of zeroes in patent counts suggests that

patentingisatwo-stageprocess,consistingofthebinarydecision

whethertousepatentingasanIPprotectionstrategyandadecision

abouthowmanypatentstoapplyfor.Twopopularmethodsusedto

modelthenumberofpatentsproducedbysuchprocessesarebased

onazero-inflatedPoissondistributionandazero-inflatednegative

binomialdistribution.Inorder tofurtherrefineourfindingswe

integrateazero-inflatedPoissonprocessinoursystemofequations,

whichnowincludesanequationforpatentcounts,onefor

patent-ing,andoneforventurecapitalinvestment.Table4presentsthe

resultsfortheseestimations.Forcompleteness,weincluderesults

11 Wealsotestthehypothesisthatcompetitionismorerelevantifthefirm opera-tesinternationally,butdonotfindthatthisinteractioneffectissignificant.Prior studieshavefoundconflictingevidenceontheimpactofprofitabilityonpatenting:

Bertonietal.(2010)showapositiverelationbetweennetcashflowandpatents,

whereasBaumandSilverman(2004)reportanegativeone.Wealsotriedusinga proxyforprofitabilityconstructedfrompre-taxprofitsscaledbyassets,butdidnot findsignificantresults.Consequently,wedecidedtodropthisvariablefromour models,duetothelargeamountofmissingvaluesinsurveyresponsesonprofits.

12 Althoughcollinearityisnotaprobleminthesemodels,thereissomecorrelation betweenproductdevelopmenttimeandR&Defforts,whichcausesdevelopment timetobecomeasignificantpredictorofVCinvestmentsifR&Dvariablesare droppedfromtheregression.

fromamodelwithonlythepatentcountsandpatentingequations

asTable5,whichprovidesthebaselineforthefull(three-equation)

modeldiscussedinthissection.

Thepositiveeffectonfirms’latentpatentingstates,whichwould

beexpectedifventurecapitalistsadded totheirpatenting

per-formance,disappearsacrossallmodels,whilethenegativeeffect

onthenumberofgrantedpatentsremains.Moreover–andasin

thesimultaneousbinarypatentingmodels–thenumberofpatent

applicationsdropsafterVCinvestments.

Ifwelookatthenumberofpatentsbeingappliedfororgranted,

ourresultssupporttheviewthatVCfinancefollowspatentsignals

toinvestincompanieswithexistingcommerciallyviable

know-how.WhiletheeffectofVCinvestmentonboththeuseofpatents

andontheirnumbersseemsnegligible,VChasanegativeimpacton

patentgrantsandapplicationsinsomemodels.Venturecapitalists

areattractedtofirmsthatproducepatents,butdonotcontributeto

theexpansionoffirms’knowledgestocks—instead,theyarelikely

toshiftfirmresourcesfromproducingnewpatentapplicationsto

exploitingexistingknowledge.

Controlvariables for future patent counts behave mostly as

expected,andgivefurtherinsightsintofirms’patentingdecisions.

While manufacturingfirms andservice firms appear– perhaps

counterintuitively–equallylikelytopatent(seemodel1inTable3),

wefindthatbeingamanufacturingorR&Dfirmincreasesthe

num-berofpatentapplicationsrelativetootherservicefirms(seemodel

1 in Table4).The estimation algorithm for three simultaneous

equationspickstherelevantequationsforourtwoR&Dvariables:

TheexistenceofR&Dprogrammesmainlypredicts patentingin

general,whiletheproportionofR&Dstaffexplainsthenumberof

applicationsandgrantsawarded.InlinewithBaumandSilverman’s

(2004)results,wefindthatcompetitionhasanegativeimpacton

thedecision topatent (inbivariatemodelsin Table3)andthe

numberofpatentsappliedfororgranted(intrivariatemodelsin

Table4).However,firmstendtoprotecttheirpositioninthe

mar-ketbychoosingtopatentiftheirmarketsarelargeorhavelong

productdevelopmenttimes.

EstimatedmodelparametersprovidesupportformodellingVC

investment,patenting,andthenumberofpatentssimultaneously.

Inmostofthemodelstestedforpatentapplicationsandgrants,

errorcorrelationsbetweenthefirst(VC)equationandthesecond

and third are substantial and significant. External shocks

lead-ingtoVCinvestmentcorrelatewiththelikelihoodtopatentwith

theexpectedpositivesign(andnegativesignfornotpatenting).

EstimatederrorcorrelationsbetweenVCinvestmentandpatent

numbersareagainlargeandsignificant.Wealsotestmodel

stabil-itybycheckinginfluentialobservationsandcross-tabulationsfor

firmsthatstartorstoptheirpatentingactivitiesdependingonVC

investment,butfindnoabnormalities.

5. Robustnesstests

5.1. Independentequations

Ourfirstrobustnesscheckshowstheadvantagesofour

estima-tionstrategyoversimpleralternatives.Wecomparetheresultsof

oursimultaneousestimationswiththoseobtainedfrom

indepen-dentregressionsforVCinvestmentand patenting(seeTable6).

Whilethereis nochangeintheVCequation,thereisastriking

differenceinthepatentingequations(Table6,columns1–3):

With-outcontrollingforendogeneity,venturecapitalappearstoincrease

thelikelihoodofpatentsbeinggranted.Thisarguablybiasedresult

notonlydisappearsinthesimultaneousestimationstrategy,but

thefindingemergesthatVCinvestmentcanreducethelikelihood

thatfirmsapplyfornewpatentsintheperiodimmediatelyafter

(10)

Table4

Patenting,patentnumbers,andVCinvestment.

Dependentvariableinpatentingequations Applicationsint+1 Grantsint+1 Grantsint+1

Model 1 2 3

Dependentvariable Notpatenting

(zeroinflation)

VCinvestment Notpatenting (zeroinflation)

VCinvestment Notpatenting (zeroinflation)

VCinvestment

VCinvestment 0.186(0.58) −0.976(0.66) −0.815(0.85)

Patentapplications(Log) −0.313(0.22) −0.083(0.08) −0.371(0.18)** 0.103(0.08)

Patentapplications>0 −1.779(0.51)*** 0.560(0.20)*** 2.460(0.43)*** 0.591(0.20)***

Patentgrants(Log) −0.586(0.21)*** 0.173(0.13)

Patentgrants>0 −1.110(0.27)*** 0.400(0.24)*

Age(Log) −0.161(0.12) −0.346(0.10)*** 0.233(0.12)* 0.343(0.09)*** 0.111(0.14) 0.338(0.09)***

Size(log(employees+1)) −0.167(0.09)* 0.206(0.07)*** 0.006(0.08) 0.203(0.07)*** 0.022(0.10) 0.201(0.07)***

U.S.firm 0.075(0.20) −0.342(0.13)** 0.400(0.18)** 0.318(0.14)** 0.351(0.24) 0.342(0.14)**

Medium-hightechmanuf. −0.151(0.44) −0.216(0.29) −0.061(0.38) −0.125(0.30) 0.162(0.36) −0.228(0.29)

Medium-lowtechmanuf. 0.188(0.45) −0.375(0.29) 0.295(0.39) −0.346(0.30) 0.465(0.34) −0.384(0.29)

R&Dservices&software 0.159(0.49) 0.280(0.30) −0.094(0.48) 0.320(0.30) −0.111(0.42) 0.266(0.30)

Otherservices −0.652(0.57) −0.107(0.31) 0.634(0.46) −0.074(0.32) 0.711(0.49) −0.116(0.31)

R&Dexpend.(yes/no) −0.613(0.25)** 0.425(0.21)** 0.288(0.23) 0.440(0.21)** 0.487(0.28)* 0.432(0.21)**

R&Dstaff(in%) 0.359(0.51) 0.752(0.32)** 0.485(0.56) 0.881(0.32)*** 1.123(0.67)* 0.665(0.33)**

CEOhasadegree −0.282(0.22) 0.345(0.17)** 0.313(0.22) 0.333(0.17)* 0.355(0.23) 0.341(0.17)**

Marketsize −0.366(0.14)*** 0.186(0.09)** 0.299(0.13)** 0.199(0.09)** 0.388(0.15)*** 0.194(0.09)**

Productdev.time −0.176(0.09)* 0.045(0.07) 0.208(0.10)** 0.052(0.07) 0.226(0.11)** 0.050(0.07)

Competitors(Log) 0.109(0.09) −0.081(0.07) 0.148(0.09) −0.087(0.07) 0.164(0.11) −0.082(0.07)

Intercept 3.655(0.70)*** 1.859(0.44)*** 2.780(0.62)*** 1.897(0.44)*** 2.703(0.65)*** 1.867(0.44)***

Dependentvariable Applications(number) Grants(number) Grants(number)

VCinvestment −0.780(0.15)*** 0.136(0.25) 0.886(0.29)***

Patentapplications(Log) 0.815(0.05)*** 0.962(0.05)***

Patentapplications>0 −0.160(0.23) −0.411(0.32)

Patentgrants(log) 0.615(0.06)***

Patentgrants>0 0.820(0.23)***

Age(log) −0.032(0.06) −0.441(0.12)*** 0.042(0.11)

Size(log(employees+1)) 0.017(0.05) 0.186(0.09)** 0.014(0.10)

U.S.firm 0.289(0.10)*** 0.061(0.15) 0.119(0.19)

Medium-hightechmanuf. −0.027(0.34) −0.246(0.27) 0.074(0.40)

Medium-lowtechmanuf. 0.071(0.36) −0.282(0.32) 0.130(0.44)

R&Dservices&software −0.106(0.34) −0.799(0.30)*** 0.199(0.45)

Otherservices −1.136(0.53)** 0.664(0.46) 0.285(0.59)

R&Dexpend.(yes/no) 0.224(0.42) −0.128(0.41) 0.544(0.32)*

R&Dstaff(in%) 1.215(0.12)*** 0.850(0.30)*** 1.059(0.37)***

CEOhasadegree −0.158(0.17) 0.012(0.34) 0.031(0.20)

Marketsize −0.055(0.09) 0.166(0.11) −0.211(0.12)*

Productdev.time 0.096(0.05)** 0.103(0.06) 0.054(0.07)

Competitors(log) −0.210(0.05)*** 0.042(0.14) 0.239(0.09)*** Intercept 0.259(0.62) 0.914(0.53)* 0.531(0.53) Var(ωit) 1.307(0.12)*** 0.656(0.10)*** 0.483(0.07)*** (vit,εit) −0.338(0.24)* 0.076(0.29) −0.092(0.44) (vit,ωit) 0.290(0.03)*** −0.108(0.06)** 0.444(0.11)*** Observations 940 940 940 Waldtest 25697 25356 8424 p-Value 0.000 0.000 0.000 Log-likelihood −968.4 −846.0 −762.8

Notes.Thistablepresentszero-inflatedPoissonmodelsforpatentapplicationsandpatentgrantsduringtheperiodfollowingthesurveyperiod,includinganendogenous equationforventurecapitalinvestment.Robuststandarderrors(estimatedusingthesandwichestimator)areshowninparentheses.

Significancelevels:***p<0.01;**p<0.05;*p<0.1.

capitalarecausedbyestimationuncertaintyduetotheadditional parameterforerrorcorrelationbetweenequations.Waldtestsof thejointsignificanceofthiscorrelationandthecoefficientof ven-turecapitalonpatentingaresignificantatthefivepercentlevelin allmodelsinTable3.Theimpactofpositiveerrorcorrelationscan

beseeninthecoefficientsforventurecapital,whichchange

consid-erablywhenestimatedsimultaneously.Introducingcross-equation

correlationalsoharmonisescoefficientsforsomevariablesacross

modelsand causesno majorchanges in theresultsfor control

variables.

Whetherornotafirm obtainsfinancecouldhaveanimpact

onitsabilitytostartorsustainpatentingactivities.Sincewe

per-formourregressionsonasample offirmsthat soughtexternal

finance,ratherthanonlyonthosethatobtainedit,weaddasetof

robustnesstestsforthissubsample.Resultsofseparateregressions

(not reported here) confirm ourfindings in Table 3. However,

two smallchangesappear inthepatenting equations.First, the

effectsize ofdevelopmenttime decreasesslightly and losesits

significance.Second,coefficientsonproductmarketcompetition

allincreaseinmagnitude,andtheonepredictingfuture

applica-tionsbecomesslightlysignificant.Estimatingourmodelsonthe

fulldataset(includingthose96firmsthatdidnotobtainexternal

finance)hastwoadvantagesoverthesmallersample.First,adding

theseobservationsincreasesthestatisticalprecisionofourresults.

Second,ourfindingsareconservative,thatis,theeffectofobtaining

venturecapitalonpatentingcanbeupwardbiasedifitincludesa

(positive)effectofobtaininganykindoffinance,whichwouldbe

ignorediffirmsgainingnofinancewereexcluded.Inthissense,the

negativeorinsignificantcoefficientsforventurecapitalrepresent

(11)

Table5

Patentingandpatentnumbers—zero-inflatedPoissonmodel.

Dependentvariablein patentingequations

Applicationsint+1 Grantsint+1 Grantsint+1

Model 1 2 3

Dependentvariable Patents(number) Notpatenting

(zeroinflation)

Patents(number) Notpatenting (zeroinflation)

Patents(number) Notpatenting (zeroinflation)

VCinvestment −0.5030.29)* 0.342(0.22) 0.287(0.22) 0.689(0.22)*** 0.696(0.26)*** 1.130(0.36)***

Patentapplications(log) 0.805(0.10)*** 0.448(0.14)*** 0.990(0.09)*** 0.419(0.18)**

Patentapplications>0 −0.756(0.34)** 1.150(0.27)*** 0.916(0.43)** 2.372(0.37)***

Patentgrants(log) 0.682(0.11)*** 0.545(0.16)***

Patentgrants>0 0.314(0.30) −1.167(0.24)***

Age(log) −0.098(0.17) −0.177(0.08)** 0.318(0.17)* 0.143(0.10) 0.143(0.15) 0.078(0.14)

Size(log(employees+1)) −0.125(0.14) −0.150(0.07)** 0.244(0.14)* 0.019(0.07) 0.138(0.15) 0.015(0.10)

U.S.firm 0.401(0.34) −0.073(0.16) 0.583(0.24)** 0.262(0.16) 0.164(0.17) 0.381(0.22)*

Medium-hightechmanuf. 0.260(0.32) −0.159(0.34) −0.510(0.58) −0.041(0.37) −0.269(0.46) 0.101(0.34)

Medium-lowtechmanuf. 0.126(0.36) 0.133(0.34) −0.162(0.59) 0.390(0.37) −0.223(0.47) 0.372(0.33)

R&Dservices&software 0.392(0.40) 0.255(0.38) −0.443(0.62) 0.163(0.42) −0.459(0.47) −0.128(0.40)

Otherservices −0.498(0.43) −0.232(0.37) −0.415(0.67) 0.726(0.42)* 0.684(0.62) 0.696(0.45)

R&Dexpend.(yes/no) 0.470(0.39) −0.420(0.19)** 0.100(0.57) 0.284(0.23) 0.389(0.45) 0.484(0.26)*

R&Dstaff(in%) 1.324(0.72)* 0.020(0.37) 0.752(0.48) 0.474(0.46) 1.551(0.42)*** 1.292(0.62)**

CEOhasadegree −0.048(0.28) −0.105(0.16) −0.193(0.32) 0.234(0.18) 0.249(0.35) 0.459(0.25)*

Marketsize 0.055(0.32) −0.243(0.09)*** 0.487(0.22)** 0.233(0.11)** 0.157(0.17) 0.336(0.15)**

Productdev.time −0.225(0.10)** 0.189(0.07)*** 0.072(0.10) 0.161(0.08)** 0.248(0.09)*** 0.281(0.11)**

Competitors(log) −0.163(0.15) 0.101(0.07) −0.307(0.18)* 0.046(0.09) 0.568(0.22)** 0.069(0.14) Intercept 1.674(1.21) 3.451(0.50)*** 0.498(1.11) 2.385(0.55)*** 1.974(0.90)** 2.967(0.65)*** Observations 940 940 940 Waldtest 2204.7 469.0 480.9 p-Value 0.000 0.000 0.000 Log-likelihood −1537.8 −982.8 −819.3

Notes.Thistablepresentszero-inflatedPoissonmodelsforpatentapplicationsandpatentgrantsduringtheperiodafterthesurvey.Whencomparingcoefficientsfromthe patentingequationwithpriormodelsforthelikelihoodtopatent,allsignsmustbereversedasthe“patenting”equationinthistablepredictsthelikelihoodofnotpatenting. Asarobustnesstest,wetriedzero-inflatednegativebinomialmodels.Testsforoverdispersionareallinsignificantinthesemodels,whileVuongtestsagainstthealternative hypothesisofastandardPoissonprocessarehighlysignificant.Robuststandarderrorsareinparentheses.

Significancelevels:***p<0.01;**p<0.05;*p<0.1.

Table6

Patentingactivityandventurecapitalinvestment—independentequations.

Patenting(yes/no) VCinvestment

Model 1 2 3 4 5 6

Dependentvariable Applicationsint+1 Grantsint+1 Grantsint+1 VCinvestment VCinvestment VCinvestment

VCinvestment 0.267(0.20) 0.598(0.20)*** 0.445(0.25)*

Patentapplications(Log) 0.513(0.13)*** 0.627(0.14)*** 0.094(0.08)

Patentapplications>0 0.980(0.22)*** 1.594(0.23)*** 0.574(0.20)***

Patentgrants(log) 0.584(0.16)*** 0.166(0.12)

Patentgrants>0 1.182(0.22)*** 0.393(0.23)*

Age(log) 0.164(0.07)** 0.073(0.09) 0.167(0.09)* 0.331(0.09)*** 0.345(0.09)*** 0.339(0.09)***

Size(log(employees+1)) 0.123(0.06)** 0.028(0.06) 0.012(0.07) 0.202(0.07)*** 0.205(0.06)*** 0.193(0.07)***

U.S.firm 0.132(0.14) 0.344(0.15)** 0.409(0.18)** 0.327(0.14)** 0.324(0.14)** 0.323(0.14)**

Medium-hightechmanuf. 0.177(0.32) −0.045(0.34) −0.202(0.27) −0.235(0.29) −0.138(0.29) −0.142(0.29)

Medium-lowtechmanuf. −0.127(0.32) −0.407(0.35) −0.500(0.28)* 0.405(0.29) 0.351(0.30) 0.347(0.29)

R&Dservices&software −0.235(0.36) −0.229(0.39) −0.352(0.36) 0.259(0.29) 0.312(0.30) 0.312(0.30)

Otherservices 0.122(0.34) −0.761(0.40)* 0.786(0.36)** 0.127(0.31) 0.084(0.31) 0.099(0.31)

R&Dexpend.(yes/no) 0.430(0.18)** 0.278(0.20) 0.432(0.22)** 0.419(0.21)** 0.442(0.21)** 0.464(0.21)**

R&Dstaff(in%) 0.170(0.36) 0.563(0.46) −0.352(0.46) 0.696(0.33)** 0.878(0.32)*** 0.874(0.31)***

CEOhasadegree 0.085(0.14) −0.261(0.16)* 0.288(0.18) 0.335(0.17)** 0.339(0.17)** 0.362(0.17)**

Marketsize 0.239(0.09)*** 0.300(0.10)*** 0.260(0.11)** 0.198(0.09)** 0.196(0.09)** 0.214(0.09)**

Productdev.time 0.163(0.06)*** 0.136(0.07)** 0.119(0.08) 0.044(0.07) 0.053(0.07) 0.057(0.07)

Competitors(log) −0.119(0.06)* 0.111(0.07)* 0.202(0.08)*** 0.077(0.07) 0.089(0.07) 0.092(0.07) Intercept −3.311(0.46)*** 2.448(0.52)*** 2.588(0.52)*** 1.883(0.44)*** 1.887(0.44)*** 1.889(0.44)*** Observations 940 940 940 940 940 940 Log-Likelihood −252.3 −218.3 −159.3 −235.2 −237.1 −238.9 Chi-sq.test 235.7 186.4 265.8 111.0 114.6 101.5 p-Value 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 Pseudo-R2 0.428 0.451 0.599 0.241 0.235 0.229

Notes.Thistablepresentsprobitmodelsforthelikelihoodofobservinganynumberofpatentapplicationsorgrants,respectively,incolumns1–3andprobitmodelsforthe likelihoodofobservingventurecapitalinvestmentsincolumns4–6.Robuststandarderrorsareinparentheses.

(12)

Table7

Likelihoodofbecomingamergeroracquisitiontarget.

Dependentvariable M&ATarget M&ATarget M&ATarget M&ATarget

Model 1 2 3 4

VCinvestment×applications(log) −0.013(0.19)

VCinvestment×grants(log) 0.303(0.26)

VCinvestment×(applications>0) −0.433(0.38) −0.406(0.55)

VCinvestment×(grant>0) −0.215(0.39) −0.700(0.55)

VCinvestment 0.619(0.24)** 0.547(0.23)** 0.619(0.24)** 0.537(0.23)**

Patentapplications(log) 0.020(0.09) 0.024(0.11)

Patentapplications>0 0.509(0.26)** 0.502(0.27)*

Patentgrants(log) 0.183(0.12) 0.108(0.13)

Patentgrants>0 0.184(0.28) 0.302(0.28)

Age(log) −0.181(0.09)** 0.191(0.09)** 0.181(0.09)** 0.190(0.09)**

Size(log(employees+1)) 0.266(0.07)*** 0.257(0.06)*** 0.266(0.07)*** 0.257(0.06)***

U.S.firm −0.124(0.15) −0.143(0.15) −0.125(0.14) −0.145(0.15)

Medium-hightechmanuf. −0.157(0.33) −0.134(0.33) −0.157(0.33) −0.171(0.33)

Medium-lowtechmanuf. −0.257(0.34) −0.234(0.34) −0.258(0.34) −0.258(0.34)

R&Dservices&software −0.289(0.37) −0.294(0.36) −0.292(0.36) −0.278(0.36)

Otherservices −0.525(0.37) −0.514(0.37) −0.525(0.37) −0.527(0.37)

R&Dex

References

Related documents

The most effective mentors in the HSBC/OB project were those, like Nick, who: were fully involved in all aspects of the mentoring process; were committed to actively engaging with

Trend in drug abuse and addiction is the main issues in the field of social harms that has preoccupied minds of many researchers .Regarding the importance of this issue, the aim of

Vivian Huang from APEN talks about the importance of communicating with communities that are marginalized from the political process, “ At APEN we are really trying to create

Brazil, Russia, India, China and South Africa – the so-called BRICS countries – all show high economic growth rates.. They suffered only shortly under the turbulences of

Although many efforts have been devoted to design models of web-based applications, the development, engineering and management of such kind of applications are still not

2 With this Request for Qualifications, MCA-Indonesia is seeking a senior level consultant to assist LKPP procure, develop, implement and manage the Procurement Management