• No results found

the most promising sources of renewable energy. Solar energy resource is widely abundant

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "the most promising sources of renewable energy. Solar energy resource is widely abundant"

Copied!
32
0
0

Loading.... (view fulltext now)

Full text

(1)

Residential Solar Photovoltaic Technology Adoption: An Empirical Investigation of State Policy Effectiveness

Christine Lasco Crago∗ and Ilya Chernyakhovskiy

Abstract

State policy incentives for solar power have grown significantly in the past several years. This paper uses county level panel data to investigate whether state policy incentives are effective in increasing residential solar PV capacity. Empirical findings show that tax incentives, rebates, solar-specific mandates, and loan financing programs are important drivers of residential PV adoption. These results suggest that policy incentives play a significant role in encouraging wider use of solar energy. Results also point to a significant positive relationship between hybrid vehicle sales and residential PV adoption, indicating the importance of pro-environmental preference as a predictor of solar PV demand.

Renewable energy has received growing support in the past several years due to concerns

about climate change and energy security. Solar photovoltaic (PV) technology is one of

the most promising sources of renewable energy. Solar energy resource is widely abundant

in the United States, and solar power generation produces less greenhouse gas emissions

relative to energy sources from fossil fuels. According to Lopez et al. (2012), customer-cited

rooftop solar PV has the technical potential to supply roughly 20% of annual electricity

demand in the United States. In 2010 the United States federal government spent $1.1 billion in financial support for solar energy development, representing more than a 5-fold

increase from 2007 levels.1 States have also played a larger role in incentivizing renewables

like solar by establishing mandates broadly for renewable energy and specifically for solar.

In addition to solar energy generation goals and mandates, generous financial incentives

Corresponding author. Assistant Professor, Department of Resource Economics, University of

Mas-sachusetts Amherst. Address: 217C Stockbridge Hall, 80 Campus Center Way, Amherst, MA 01003. Phone: +1 413 545-5738. Email addresses: ccrago@resecon.umass.edu (C.L. Crago), ichernya@umass.edu (I. Chernyakhovskiy).

1United States’ federal spending to promote renewable energy technology totalled $14.7 billion in 2010,

growing significantly from its level of $5.1 billion 2007. In comparison, federal spending to promote wind power totalled$4.98 billion in 2010 and$476 million in 2007 (U.S. Energy Information Adiminstration (EIA) 2011).

(2)

in the form of rebates and tax credits and exemptions are being offered. In the case of

residential applications, these financial incentives have lowered the cost of installing a solar

photovoltaic (PV) system by as much as 50%. Given the large amount of current and

projected government expenditures that go to solar incentive programs, it is important to

determine what types of incentives are effective, and to what extent they influence growth

in solar PV capacity.

Despite the fact that incentives for solar PV have become widespread, there are few

em-pirical studies that examine the effectiveness of specific policies used to incentivize residential

solar PV adoption. To date, there is no empirical investigation of the impact of solar PV

incentives that parses the effects of different state policies. This paper fills this gap in the

literature.

We use county level data spanning eight years (2005-2012) to examine the impact of state

policy incentives for residential PV while controlling for demographics, solar resources, and

environmental preferences using panel data estimation methods. Newly installed residential

solar PV capacity in kilowatts (kW) is the dependent variable of interest.

This paper improves upon the existing literature examining determinants of solar

adop-tion in a number of ways. First, individual representaadop-tion of policies enables us to investigate

the effectiveness of different policy options. Existing studies that examine the drivers of

res-idential solar energy adoption (solar hot water or PV) either lump policy incentives in one

variable (Kwan 2012) or do not consider them (Zahran et al. 2008). Others focus on the

role of peer effects in the diffusion of solar PV technology (Bollinger and Gillingham 2012;

Noll, Dawes, and Rai 2014). Second, we use panel data to examine the impact of specific

incentives on adoption. Previous studies (Kwan 2012; Zahran et al. 2008) rely on cross

sec-tion data which, while informative, does not exploit variasec-tion over time. Third, we address

a number of estimations issues. We use a Tobit model to account for the non-linear

rela-tionship between our dependent variable and explanatory variables due to the large share of

(3)

specification to address potential endogeneity in policy variables.

Our empirical results show that policy incentives are effective at increasing solar PV

capacity at the county level. Sales tax exemptions, rebate availability and loan financing

programs are significantly related to increases in PV capacity. Solar renewable energy credit

prices, which represent stringency of solar-specific mandates are also found to significantly

in-crease residential solar PV capacity. In contrast, we find that Renewable Portfolio Standards,

a technology-blind mandate does not impact PV capacity growth. These results suggest that

policy incentives play a significant role in increasing the demand for solar energy. In

par-ticular, solar-specific policies and policies that are geared toward reducing upfront cost to

consumers are most effective. Results also indicate that Democratic party affiliation as well

as demand for hybrid vehicles are positively related to solar PV adoption, suggesting the

importance of environmental preferences in residential solar PV adoption decisions.

The paper proceeds as follows: section 1 gives a brief background of solar policy incentives

at the state level. Sections 2 presents our analytical framework and section 3 discusses the

empirical model. Section 4 presents data sources. Section 5 discusses our empirical findings

and section 6 concludes.

1

Background

Over the last several years, solar PV technology has enjoyed a steep upward trend in

adop-tion across the United States (U.S.). Total operating solar PV capacity reached 8.3 GW by

the end of 2013. In 2012 the U.S. was fourth in the world PV market for total peak power

capacity behind Germany, Italy and China (Barbose, Darghouth, and Wiser 2012). Net

electricity generation from solar power sources has grown exponentially; between 2009 and

2013 annual net generation increased by roughly 5000% (U.S. Energy Information

Adimin-stration (EIA) 2014). New solar capacity additions in 2013 totalled 4,751 MW, a 41%

(4)

second-largest source of new energy generating capacity behind natural gas (U.S. Energy

Information Adiminstration (EIA) 2014).

Residential solar PV systems represents an important market segment. In 2013, 792 MW

of new capacity was added, representing 17% of solar capacity additions that year. Forecasts

of solar PV capacity additions in 2014 project growth to be most rapid in the residential

segment (GTM Research and Solar Energy Industries Association 2014).

Concurrently, solar power industry revenues, employment, and wages have increased

steadily since 2007, with a strong upward trend projected to continue uninterrupted through

2018 (Smith 2013). However, while the U.S. solar power industry has enjoyed substantial

growth in recent years, the share of solar generated electricity is small when compared with

other energy sources. Electricity generated from solar energy accounted for only 0.2% of

total electricity generated in the U.S. in 2013 (U.S. Energy Information Adiminstration

(EIA) 2014).

1.1

State policy incentives

State governments have implemented a range of policy initiatives aimed at increasing the

share of solar PV-generated electricity in the U.S. energy mix. In 2011 alone, legislatures

in ten states enacted various innovative financial incentives directed at increasing in-state

residential PV capacity (DSIRE 2013). Renewable portfolio standards have received the

most attention in case studies and empirical analyses. Renewable portfolio standards (RPS)

are regulations which mandate that a specific share of a state’s electricity sales must be

generated from renewable energy sources. Carley (2009) and Yin and Powers (2010) show

empirically that RPS implementation is associated with positive growth of in-state RE

gen-eration. Findings by Maguire (2011) and Adelaja et al. (2010) provide evidence that RPS

positively influence wind energy adoption. However, Carley (2009) points out that RPS

generally fail at achieving their stated goal of increasing the share of renewable energy

(5)

policies thus far, Wiser, Barbose, and Holt (2011) emphasize the need to include

technology-specific standards into RPS designs to promote diversity in renewable energy markets. The

authors cite evidence that RPS alone promote only a limited number of least-cost renewable

technologies. While solar PV technology is a promising source of renewable energy, the

cur-rently high cost of solar panels does not make it competitive with wind energy, hydropower

or geothermal. One strategy has been to amend existing RPS mandates to include a

“carve-out” for solar energy generation. Of the 29 states plus the District of Columbia with active

RPS policies, 16 states and the District of Columbia have included a solar carve-out. New

Jersey currently has the most aggressive support for solar energy with a carve-out of 4.1%

of electricity sales by 2028.

Generally a solar carve-out goes hand in hand with a solar renewable energy credit

(SREC) market. An SREC market provides a financial production incentive to solar-enabled

households. SRECs are solar energy production credits awarded per kilowatt hour (kWh)

to owners of grid-connected solar PV systems. Aggregation firms sell bundles of SRECs to

utilities in the state’s renewable energy credit market. Utilities are obligated to meet solar

energy sales requirements either by installing their own solar power facilities, buying SRECs

in the open market, or paying year-end alternative compliance payments. The average SREC

price per year is used to measure the effects of a state’s solar carve-out

Additional state incentives come in the form of tax policies, cash rebates, and solar

consumer support laws. Tax incentives are designed to reduce the high up-front costs of

installing a solar PV system. Tax credits and exemptions from personal, property, and sales

taxes aim to reduce the tax liability of adopters. Many states use a combination of tax-based

incentive mechanisms. Roughly twenty states offer sales tax exemptions for the cost of solar

equipment, thirty states offer property tax exemptions for the added value to homes with

solar PV systems, and twenty states and the District of Columbia provide income tax credits.

Rebate programs provide direct cash subsidies towards the up-front costs of installing

(6)

are more politically charged than other incentives as they require appropriation of state

funds. Sixteen states and the District of Columbia currently have active rebate programs.

In Massachusetts, the Commonwealth Solar Rebate II program is allotted$4 million per year since 2003, funded by a$0.0005 per kWh surcharge on electricity bills in the state. In addition to direct financial incentives, states also provide legislative support which can protect solar

PV consumers. Solar rights policies are state laws which prohibit local governments from

enacting regulations or ordinances restricting a home owner’s ability to install a solar energy

system.

Table 1.1 gives an overview of when key policies were enacted in the states included in this

study. Success with promoting residential solar PV adoption varies significantly across state

lines. As of December 2012, New Jersey had a total of 955.7 megawatts (MW) of installed

solar PV capacity, whereas New Hampshire ended the year with just 5.4 MW (NREL 2013).

After controlling for population size this is roughly a 20-fold discrepancy in solar technology

adoption.

It is unclear whether adoption trends are a manifestation of availability of solar resources

(i.e., sunshine) , individual home-owner characteristics such as income and pro-environmental

preferences, or genuine responses to state incentive policies. In a county-level study of solar

hot water system adoption using cross section data, Zahran et al. (2008) find that age

and county participation in the International Council for Local Environmental Initiatives

(ICLEI) are significant across model specifications. Policy incentives are not considered

in the analysis. Kwan (2012) examines solar PV adoption at the zip-code level using cross

section data. He finds that policy incentives have an impact on solar PV adoption. However,

Kwan (2012) uses a single aggregate incentives index to represent financial incentives, while

mandates, solar consumer rights and loan financing programs are not considered. He also

identifies solar insolation and demographic characteristics such as college graduation rates,

age, and income as strong predictors of solar PV adoption.

(7)

Table 1: State solar PV incentives Year Policy State 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 Solar carve-out CT DE • • • • • • MA • • • MD • • • • • • ME NH • • • NJ • • • • • • • • NY† ◦ ◦ ◦ ◦ ◦ ◦ ◦ ◦ PA • • • • • • • RI VT WV

Sales tax exemption

CT • • • • • • DE MA • • • • • • • • MD • • • • • ME NH NJ • • • • • • • • NY • • • • • • • • PA RI • • • • • • • • VT • • • • • • • • WV Rebate CT • DE • • • • • • • • MA • • • • • MD • • • • • • • • ME • • • • • • • NH • • • NJ NY • • • PA • • • • RI VT • • • • • • • • WV

This table only indicates existence of a policy. Levels of each policy vary by state and time.

(8)

research questions which have yet to be comprehensively addressed. This paper seeks to

answer whether policy incentives are effective at promoting adoption, which incentives are

most effective, and what are the prevailing characteristics of homeowners who are likely to

invest in a solar PV system.

2

Analytical Model

The empirical model is guided by an analytical model of a household’s decision to install a

PV system. Assume that the household seeks to minimize the lifetime cost of a fixed level

of electricity consumption by choosing the optimal time to invest in an energy saving device

such as a solar PV system. The household solves the following optimization problem 2:

min T T Z 0 PtEe−rtdt+ ∞ Z T (1−φ)PtEe−rtdt+ (1−π)ITe−rT (1)

where PtE is the price of electricity, φ is the proportion of electricity consumption

gen-erated from solar PV, r is the discount rate, IT is the cost of the solar PV system at the

time of installation, and π is the amount of subsidies received as a proportion of IT. The

first term in (1) is the cost of electricity prior to installation of the solar PV system. The

second term is the cost of electricity when the solar PV is in place, and the third term is the

installation cost net of subsidies.

Taking the derivative of (1) with respect to T, we obtain the condition for the household

to invest in a PV system at time T:

φPE T

r ≥(1−π)IT (2)

Equation (2) shows that a household will invest in a PV system if the discounted present

value of benefits from solar PV is greater than the net investment cost at the time of

(9)

stallation. Based on equation (2) we can identify the variables that affect the household’s

decision to install solar PV when economic factors are considered. We expect that factors

that increase discounted benefits relative to net investment cost will increase the likelihood

of adoption by a household at time T.

The higher the price of electricity the greater the likelihood that a household will choose

to invest at a given timeT. A lower discount rate (r) also encourages investment. Hausman

(1979) suggests that there is an inverse relationship between discount rates and income.

Thus, we include median home value and income as explanatory variables in our regression.

The expectation is that the higher a household’s income and home value, the greater the

likelihood of adoption.

The share of electricity generated from solar PV (and thus the cost savings attributed

to solar PV) is determined in large part by the amount of solar resources available to the

household. Thus, we include data on solar insolation. Households with greater access to solar

resources will expect greater energy bill savings, reduced payback periods on the investment,

and potentially greater returns from production-based policy incentives. We expect that

greater solar insolation would lead to greater likelihood of adoption. The lower the net

cost of installing solar PV the greater the likelihood of adoption. The installation cost data

available through the NREL OpenPV database points to limited variation in installation

costs for an average sized residential system (NREL 2013). Residential installation costs are

assumed to be constant among counties. A linear time trend variable is included in order

to capture changes to federal policies as well as falling prices of solar panels over time. The

net cost to the household also depends on the amount of financial assistance obtained from

solar incentive programs. We include data on different financial incentives that lower the net

cost of PV installation. We also include variables to represent support policies such as loan

programs.

Equation (2) helps identify financial factors that are likely to affect adoption. However,

(10)

environmen-tal externalities, contribute to the public good, gain prestige, and “feel good” about oneself

could also motivate solar PV adoption (Andreoni 1990; Sidiras and Koukios 2004; Sexton

and Sexton 2014). We use the share of hybrid-electric vehicles in new vehicle registrations

per county, percentage of households that purchase organic food, as well as the percentage of

Democratric Party votes to represent households’ pro-environmental preferences that cause

them to make green investments due to non-financial considerations. Studies have also

iden-tified peer effects and familiarity with technology as factors that influence adoption of solar

PV (Bollinger and Gillingham 2012; Noll, Dawes, and Rai 2014). As more solar panels are

installed in a neighborhood, social interactions and solar panel visibility on rooftops may

cause a reduction in perceived uncertainty about solar technology. We use a one year lag

of the number of solar installations to capture the impacts of peer effects and familiarity

with PV technology. Other studies also find that age, urbanization, and educational

at-tainment can be important factors in determining solar adoption (Kwan 2012; Zahran et al.

2008; Lutzenhiser 1993; Labay and Kinnear 1981). It is possible that these variables affect

purchasing power, discounting preferences, or environmental awareness. We include median

county age and the share of residents with a bachelors degree or higher. As a measure of

ur-banization and as control variables for available rooftop space, we include population density

and housing density for each county.

3

Empirical model and choice of estimation method

The main empirical goal of this paper is to model the drivers of solar PV capacity growth at

the county level. The analytical model shows the variables that affect a household’s decision

to adopt solar PV. We expect that the same variables (averaged at the county level) will

also determine the amount of PV capacity at the county level. Based on the analytical

model, counties receiving larger financial incentives that lower the cost of PV installation

(11)

prices, greater solar insolation and number of existing PV systems installed, and higher

proportion of residents that have higher incomes, are better educated and that have

pro-environmental preferences will have greater PV capacity.

Equation 3 is the hypothesized linear model of county solar PV capacity additions.

Yit=α+Xitβ+Pitζ+Gitκ+Iiγ+it (3)

where the dependent variable, Yit, is residential PV capacity additions in county i, in year t,

and it is the error vector. Average installed solar kW capacity across all counties and time

periods, holding all explanatory variables constant at zero, is captured by the intercept α.

Vectors Pit and Git include policy and non-policy variables that vary over time. Vector Ii

includes explanatory variables which do not vary over time: average annual solar insolation

and the percentage of votes for the democratic candidate in the 2008 presidential election.

Explanatory variables can be categorized into three groups: demographics and geographic

controls; state policies; and indicators of pro-environmental preferences. A specification

including only demographics and geographic controls as regressors is analogous to previous

studies of solar technology adoption (Zahran et al. 2008), in which the financial effects of

state policies are not considered. The independent variables included in this specification are:

average annual solar radiation (insolation), yearly average electricity price; the percentage of

homeowners with a bachelor degree or higher; median home value; median age; the number of

owner-occupied homes; population density; lagged number of solar installations; and a time

trend. A state policy specification builds on the previous model by including the following

incentive variables: SREC prices; sales tax exemption; the number of years an RPS has been

in effect; plus four binary variables indicating the availability of: a personal tax credit; cash

rebates; solar rights regulations; and loan programs. The final specification includes two

indicators of pro-environmental preferences: the proportion of hybrid vehicles out of total

auto sales, and the proportion of democratic party voters. 3

(12)

3.1

Tobit estimator

In the solar technology adoption context, a potential problem with estimating the linear

model in Equation (3) is the high number of counties with no solar installations for a given

year. Thirty seven percent (37%) of the county-year observations in the data have zero solar

capacity additions, and 17% of counties have no solar installations throughout the study

period. This implies that 37% of linear combinations of explanatory variables included in

the model are associated with a zero value in the dependent variable. An empirical difficulty

arises because a least squares model will falsely impose a linear association to this data,

i.e., combinations of the right hand side variables can result in negative predictions of solar

adoption. Thus, parameter estimates obtained from a linear estimator are likely to be biased

and inconsistent.

We apply a maximum-likelihood Tobit estimator to account for a non-linearity due to the

high proportion of corner solutions in the data. The Tobit model is typically referred to as a

censored regression model. However, Wooldridge (2010) makes a clear distinction between a

censored regression and a corner solution application of the Tobit estimator. It important to

make this distinction for the purposes of this paper. In a censored regression context there

are observations in the sample which are artificially censored at some arbitrary point. This

is distinct from a corner solution context because the dependent variable is fully observed.

Zero solar PV capacity addition in a county simply reflects that no new residential solar PV

systems were installed in the given year. Household solar PV capacity additions are strictly

positive with a probability mass point at zero. When individual household decisions are

aggregated to the county level the lower limit remains at zero.

3.1.1 Unobserved county heterogeneity as a random effect

A random-effects error component is added to the standard Tobit estimator in order to

incorporate unobserved heterogeneity by county. The error term is re-written as an aggregate

(13)

error,

µit=νi+it (4)

whereνi is the random parameter which represents unobserved county-specific effects, under

assumptions: νi|Xit ∼ N(0, σ2ν), it|Xit ∼ N(0, σ2). A formal test for random effects is

performed using the Breusch-Pagan (BP) Lagrange Multiplier test. The null hypothesis

of no random effect is rejected. However, the RE Tobit estimator relies on the restrictive

assumption that the error term is strictly exogenous, i.e., cov(νi, Xit) = cov(νi, Xi,t−1) =

0. Violation of this assumption casts doubt on the RE Tobit results. A Hausman test

between a linear fixed-effects and random-effects model shows that the above assumption

is violated. Despite this limitation, the results from an RE Tobit estimator are useful for

making comparisons across different estimators.

3.1.2 Instrumental variable method

A potential source of endogeneity is the SREC incentive. SRECs provide a financial incentive

to drive household demand for PV systems. Meanwhile, each newly installed PV array

generates solar energy, which increases the supply of SRECs and puts downward pressure on

SREC prices. This source of endogeneity can cause the parameter estimates of SREC price

effects as well as the other included explanatory variables to be biased. An instrumental

variable (IV) Tobit estimator is applied in an attempt to mitigate the endogeneity bias.

Three instruments are used for SREC prices: the solar alternative compliance payment

(SACP), a one-period lag of SREC prices, and a binary variable indicating the presence of

a solar carve-out. A Smith-Blundell test of exogeneity confirms that the right hand side

(14)

4

Data

A panel of 300 counties over 8 years (2005 to 2012) was constructed from several data

sources. This section outlines the various data sources. The final dataset consists of 2014

observations.

4.1

Solar Adoption

Data on residential solar PV installations were obtained from the National Renewable Energy

Lab (NREL) Open PV Project. The Open PV Project is a public database which provides

location and capacity rating information for all solar PV projects in the United States. We

obtain data from 2005-2012 for the following states: ME, NH, VT, MA, NY, RI, CT, NJ,

PA, DE, MD, WV, and the District of Columbia. Following Barbose, Darghouth, and Wiser

(2012) and Kwan (2012), we use an upper limit of 10 kW capacity to denote residential PV

systems. Geographic Information System (GIS) software was used to spacially reference and

aggregate individual residential PV systems to the county level. County boundary shapefiles

were obtained from the U.S. Census Bereau Tiger/Line shapefile database. Figure 1 provides

(15)

Figure 1: Total residential PV capacity (kW), year-end 2012 (1024.30,11122.36] (248.98,1024.30] (113.13,248.98] (27.45,113.13] (0,27.452] [0,0]

4.2

Electricity price and solar resource

Yearly state average electricity prices were obtained from the U.S. Energy Information

Ad-ministration. Residential electricity prices are averaged yearly for the total electric industry

by state, measured in cents per kilowatt hour (¢/kWh). Electricity prices are not indexed or adjusted for inflation.

The average annual solar resource was calculated using data developed by the State

University of New York/Albany satellite radiation model. Solar resource, i.e., insolation is

measured in kilowatt-hours per square meter per day (kWh/m2/day). Ten-kilometer grid

cells of annual average daily total solar resource were spatially referenced and aggregated to

(16)

4.3

State incentives for solar PV

State policy incentive variables were constructed using the Database of State Incentives for

Renewables and Efficiency (DSIRE 2013). State sales taxes are used to capture heterogeneity

of sales tax incentive policies. A homeowner receiving a sales tax exemption in a state with

a high sales tax effectively receives a larger incentive than an identical homeowner in a

neighboring state with a lower sales tax. Personal tax credit and property tax exemptions

are included as binary variables, which take on a value of one if the county is located in

a state with these incentives. Rebate and loan program availability are also measured as

binary variables. Following Menz and Vachon (2006), we also include an RPS trend variable

to capture the number of years a state RPS has been in effect.

4.3.1 SREC prices

Solar renewable energy credit market prices were obtained from www.SRECtrade.com. One

SREC is equivalent to one megawatt hour (MWh) of electricity generation. The market price

of SRECs is averaged for each year in the study period. All counties within the same state

are subject to the state market price of SRECs. There are some SREC markets which can

overlap state lines. For example, the Pennsylvania SREC market accepts energy generated

by systems located in Ohio. Solar alternative compliance payment (SACP) in dollar amount

is used as an instrument for SREC prices. The SACP is a per kWh fine levied on utilities

for shortfalls in meeting RPS solar carve-out requirements. Unlike SREC prices which are

determined in the market, the SACP is set by legislature years in advance.

4.4

Indicators of pro-environmental preferences

Three variables are used to capture preferences for positive environmental action. The

percentage of county residents who buy organic food was obtained from Geographic Research

Inc. (2011). Presidential election results from 2008, obtained from National Atlas of the

(17)

county in the 2008 presidential election. Yearly hybrid vehicle registrations for personal

transportation by county were obtained from the automotive consulting firm R. L. Polk.

4.5

Demographics and geographic characteristics

County-level, yearly data from 2005-2012 for median age, median household income, median

home value, number of owner-occupied housing units and total population were obtained

from American Factfinder, a web service of the U.S. Census Bureau’s American Community

Survey.

Table 2 presents summary statistics. Column 1 is the variable name with units. Home

density, population density and median home values are used in natural log form to correct

for highly skewed distributions. Column 2 indicates the level of variation for each variable,

where “C” is for county, “S” is for state, and “Y” is for year.

5

Results and Discussion

This section presents marginal effects obtained from the empirical methods discussed above.

Table 3 compares three specifications of residential PV demand. The displayed coefficients

are average marginal effects on the uncensored dependent variable obtained from the Tobit

estimator.

Each subsequent specification represents an improvement to the model fit. Both the

log-likelihood and pseudo-R2 increase from model (1) to model (3). Likelihood ratio tests are

performed to formally confirm that each subsequent specification represents a statistically

significant increase in explanatory power.

The addition of state policy effects and environmental preferences reveals significant

cor-rections of omitted variable bias. Omitted variable bias arises when a significant explanatory

variable is omitted from the specification. Corrections of omitted variable bias are evident

(18)

Com-Table 2: Summary statistics

Varies by Mean Std. Dev. Min. Max. Dependent variable

PV capacity additions C, Y 105.891 357.184 0 7467.045

Independent variables

Solar resource (kWh/m2/day) C 4.491 0.199 4.085 5.007

ln(Owner-occupied homes) C, Y 10.381 1.147 7.34 12.908

ln(Population density) C, Y 5.43 1.571 1.035 11.18

ln(Median home value) C, Y 12.033 0.591 10.325 13.816

Electricity price (¢/kWh) S, Y 13.9 3.315 6.21 20.33

Bachelor degree or higher (%) C, Y 29.769 12.542 3.925 83.252

Median Age C, Y 40.203 3.08 27.3 51

SREC Price ($) S, Y 72.397 154.789 0 664.5

Sales tax exemption (%) S, Y 3.641 3.75 0 8.48

RPS trend S, Y 4.872 3.546 0 15

Rebate (d) S, Y 0.457 0.498 0 1

Income tax credit (d) S, Y 0.349 0.477 0 1

Loan program (d) S, Y 0.182 0.386 0 1

Solar rights (d) S, Y 0.196 0.397 0 1

Hybrid vehicle sales (%) C, Y 1.932 1.071 0 10.986

Democrats (%) C 51.679 11.92 23.64 92.5

Instruments

SACP S, Y 176.47 246.75 0 711

Carve-out (d) S, Y .368 .482 0 1

(d) for discrete change of dummy variable from 0 to 1

†Natural log transformed values

*Population density calculated by Total populationLand area , with county land area measured in square miles (mi2).

(19)

Table 3: Three specifications of residential PV demand

(1) (2) (3)

∆(System count)t−1 0.0118∗∗∗ 0.00873∗∗∗ 0.00858∗∗∗

(4.77) (3.60) (3.71) Solar resource (kWh/m2/day) 1.243+ 2.146∗∗∗ 1.872∗∗

(1.87) (3.32) (2.94) ln(Owner-occupied homes) 0.760∗∗∗ 0.905∗∗∗ 1.020∗∗∗

(3.66) (4.26) (4.66) ln(Population density) -0.428∗∗ -0.601∗∗∗ -0.678∗∗∗

(-2.84) (-4.77) (-4.89) ln(Median home value) 1.460∗∗∗ 0.931∗∗ 1.113∗∗∗

(4.34) (2.93) (3.52) Electricity price (¢/kWh) 0.431∗∗∗ 0.246∗∗∗ 0.182∗∗∗

(14.99) (5.03) (3.42) Bachelor degree or higher (%) 0.00785 0.0221+ -0.00379

(0.56) (1.88) (-0.27) Median Age -0.110∗∗∗ -0.0894∗∗ -0.0750∗∗ (-3.35) (-2.90) (-2.56) Time trend 0.359∗∗∗ 0.208∗∗∗ 0.195∗∗∗ (10.11) (3.59) (3.45) SREC Price ($) 0.00105∗∗ 0.00104∗∗ (2.38) (2.46) Sales tax exemption (%) 0.342∗∗∗ 0.374∗∗∗

(7.01) (7.21)

RPS trend -0.0566 -0.0510

(-1.49) (-1.32)

Rebate (d) 1.224∗∗∗ 1.111∗∗∗

(7.38) (6.54)

Income tax credit (d) -0.516+ -0.432+

(-1.92) (-1.65)

Loan program (d) 1.539∗∗∗ 1.782∗∗∗

(5.54) (6.51)

Solar rights (d) 0.262 0.129

(1.34) (0.68)

Hybrid vehicle sales (%) 0.276∗∗

(2.96) Democrats (%) 0.0179∗∗ (2.16) Pseudo-R2 0.201 0.250 0.254 Log-likelihood -3404.1 -3195.2 -3178.1 t statistics in parentheses + p <0.1,∗∗ p <0.05,∗∗∗ p <0.001

(20)

pared to (1), the effect of lagged system count decreases in (2) and (3), although it remains

significant. The effect of solar resources (insolation) nearly doubles in magnitude and gains

statistical significance when policy variables and pro-environmental preference variables are

introduced in models (2) and (3). The remainder of this paper will focus on results based

on the full specification in model (3).

5.1

Comparing results across estimators

This section compares results across four estimators: a pooled Tobit, a random-effects (RE)

Tobit, an instrumental variable (IV) Tobit, and a pooled ordinary least squares (OLS)

esti-mator. As discussed above, results obtained from the random effects (RE) Tobit estimator

as well as the OLS approach are problematic because of restrictive assumptions about the

error term and non-linearity of PV demand, respectively. Nevertheless, the results from both

estimators are displayed for comparison.

The estimates displayed in Table 4 are marginal effects under the Tobit estimators and

linear β coefficients under the OLS estimator.

Several explanatory variables are robust to model specification. Lagged system count

is significant under all but the RE Tobit estimator. This result points to the existence of

a “snowball effect” in residential solar technology adoption. It can be inferred that social

interactions and solar panel visibility on neighbors’ rooftops may lead to a reduction in

perceived uncertainty about solar technology.

The number of owner-occupied households in a county has a positive effect and is robust

at the 1% significance level. This is primarily a control variable which is used to make

comparisons across counties of different sizes. It’s significance speaks to the importance of

controlling for available roof space. The time trend is also positive and robust to specification.

Time effects are assumed to capture changes to federal policies and to solar panel installation

costs over time. Costs vary over time due to falling solar panel prices as well as decreasing

(21)

Table 4: Comparing results across estimators

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Tobit RE Tobit IV Tobit OLS ∆(System count)t−1 0.00858∗∗∗ 0.00222 0.00935∗∗∗ 0.0120∗∗∗

(3.71) (1.09) (3.87) (4.56) Solar resource (kWh/m2/day) 1.872∗∗ 1.306+ 1.840∗∗ 1.275∗∗

(2.94) (1.67) (2.82) (2.65) ln(Owner-occupied homes) 1.020∗∗∗ 1.196∗∗∗ 0.976∗∗∗ 0.839∗∗∗

(4.66) (5.16) (4.49) (4.90) ln(Population density) -0.678∗∗∗ -0.819∗∗∗ -0.659∗∗∗ -0.465∗∗∗

(-4.89) (-5.08) (-4.75) (-4.21) ln(Median home value) 1.113∗∗∗ 1.832∗∗∗ 1.124∗∗∗ 0.672∗∗ (3.52) (5.65) (3.50) (2.74) Electricity price (¢/kWh) 0.182∗∗∗ 0.0930+ 0.211∗∗∗ 0.0549 (3.42) (1.92) (3.68) (1.34) Bachelor degree or higher (%) -0.00379 0.000601 -0.00492 0.000368

(-0.27) (0.04) (-0.35) (0.03) Median Age -0.0750∗∗ -0.0588∗∗ -0.0737∗∗ -0.0454+

(-2.56) (-2.22) (-2.44) (-1.81)

Time trend 0.195∗∗∗ 0.332∗∗∗ 0.167∗∗ 0.226∗∗∗

(3.45) (6.26) (2.85) (5.65) Hybrid vehicle sales (%) 0.276∗∗ 0.0965 0.290∗∗ 0.211∗∗

(2.96) (1.05) (2.98) (2.75) Democrats (%) 0.0179∗∗ 0.0356∗∗ 0.0181∗∗ 0.0109 (2.16) (3.00) (2.08) (1.62) SREC Price ($) 0.00104∗∗ 0.000383 0.00154∗∗ 0.00197∗∗∗

(2.46) (0.90) (2.05) (4.97) Sales tax exemption (%) 0.374∗∗∗ 0.323∗∗∗ 0.360∗∗∗ 0.344∗∗∗

(7.21) (6.29) (6.67) (7.76)

RPS trend -0.0510 -0.0627 -0.0490 -0.0364

(-1.32) (-1.37) (-1.24) (-1.17) Rebate (d) 1.111∗∗∗ 0.890∗∗∗ 1.180∗∗∗ 0.692∗∗∗

(6.54) (5.83) (6.57) (5.18) Income tax credit (d) -0.432+ 0.185 -0.480+ -0.605∗∗

(-1.65) (0.64) (-1.69) (-2.31) Loan program (d) 1.782∗∗∗ 1.994∗∗∗ 1.630∗∗∗ 0.771∗∗∗ (6.51) (6.83) (4.68) (3.53) Solar rights (d) 0.129 -0.568∗∗∗ 0.0708 0.134 (0.68) (-3.63) (0.36) (0.78) Constant -37.14∗∗∗ -46.55∗∗∗ -36.10∗∗∗ -20.74∗∗∗ (-6.41) (-9.29) (-6.14) (-5.01) Observations 2014 2014 1911 2014 t statistics in parentheses + p <0.1,∗∗ p <0.05,∗∗∗ p <0.001

(22)

a solar PV system, including the cost of mounting equipment, interconnection and labor.

As the industry develops, experience and competition among installers drives BOS costs

downward. Consumers’ growing familiarity with the technology, through word-of-mouth

and solar energy marketing, may also be driving the positive time effect.

The negative parameter estimate for population density, robust across specifications at

the 1% significance level, suggests an inverse relationship between urbanization and

resi-dential solar PV adoption. This result is not consistent with Zahran et al. (2008), where

empirical evidence pointed to a positive relationship between urbanization and solar hot

wa-ter adoption. However, the urbanization measure used by Zahran et al. (2008) is a dummy

variable for Census-designated urban areas which may include sub-urban environments with

relatively low population density when compared with metropolitan city areas.

Of the variables measuring differences in demographics, median home value and median

age are fairly robust across specifications. The strong positive result for median home values

speaks to the importance of income status as predictor of residential PV demand. Higher

income homeowners have more disposable income to invest in a solar PV system. Estimated

effects of educational attainment, on the other hand, are weak and sensitive to model

specifi-cation. Median age has a negative effect which is significant at 5% and 10% levels under the

Tobit and linear OLS estimators, respectively. The negative effect is somewhat unexpected;

it is possible that younger homeowners are more willing to invest in solar PV because they

expect to stay in their homes for many years and are thus able to reap long-term benefits

from their solar PV system.

The state policy variables are very strong predictors of residential solar PV adoption.

Parameter estimates for sales tax exemptions, rebates, and loan programs are robust across

estimators at the 1% significance level. SREC prices are significant at least at the 5% level

under all but the RE Tobit. Each of these state incentives impacts the financial decision of

residential PV adoption because they each decrease the cost of installing a solar PV system.

(23)

markets decrease the amount of time it takes for the PV investment to pay for itself.

Unexpectedly, the income tax credit effect is negative and significant at 10% under all

but the RE Tobit estimator. There are two possible reasons why income tax credits fail

to boost residential PV demand. Firstly, the income tax credit incentive may be too small

to significantly impact the adoption decision. This is because the state income tax credit

amount is calculated based the net expenditure of an installation. The net expenditure is

defined as the expense less the 30% federal tax credit and any other state financial incentives.

Secondly, the income tax credit does not reduce the out-of-pocket expense of a residential

installation because homeowners must wait to claim the credit during tax season. The lack

of an immediate price reduction may be rendering the income tax credit incentive ineffective.

The RPS trend effect is consistently not significant across estimators. This suggests

that a technology-blind RPS alone, holding all else constant, does not provide a significant

incentive to residential PV adoption. This is consistent with Wiser, Barbose, and Holt

(2011)’s concerns that without a solar-specific mandate, RPS programs only favor a limited

number of least-cost technologies. To our knowledge, this is the first empirical evidence of

the failure of a technology-neutral RPS to promote diversity in renewable technology.

Demand for hybrid vehicles and political party affiliation are found to be significantly

related to residential solar PV demand. Voting rates for the democratic party are

signifi-cant at 5% across specifications. This is strong evidence of a relationship between political

party affiliation and pro-environmental preferences, and suggests that Democratic-leaning

constituencies, holding all else constant, are more likely to invest in solar PV technology.

The estimated effect of hybrid vehicles sales is positive and significant at 5% under all but

the RE Tobit estimator. This is further empirical evidence of findings by Dastrup et al.

(2012) which point to a positive relationship between these two “green status” consumer

(24)

5.2

Marginal effects

Marginal effects are evaluated based on results obtained from the instrumental variable (IV)

Tobit estimator. The IV Tobit is the preferred model because it simultaneously deals with

two empirical issues: 1) the non-linearity of residential PV demand; and 2) the endogeneity

of SREC prices. The linear maximum-likelihood parameter estimates, ˆβ, are also displayed

for comparison.

The following tables are divided into three groups of variables: demographics and

geog-raphy; state incentive policies; and pro-environmental preference indicators. In Table 5 the

marginal effects are evaluated at the sample means of each independent variable. Coefficient

estimates are interpreted as proportional changes to residential PV capacity, given a one

unit change in the independent variable. For variables in natural log form the coefficients

are elasticities.

The largest change in PV capacity comes about from a one-unit change in solar resource.

An additional kilowatt-hour per meter squared per day is expected to increase residential PV

capacity by 141%. This helps to explain the wide discrepancy in adoption between states

like California and New Jersey. Both states have aggressive incentives, but average solar

resources in California exceed sunshine in New Jersey by 2-3 kWh across the state. Solar

resource also has the largest per-unit effect (20.5%) on the probability of positive adoption.

The time trend indicates that with each year, holding all else constant at zero, residential

PV capacity is expected to grow by roughly 13%. This effect is driven by falling solar panel

prices and competition among a growing number of installation firms. One-cent increases

in electricity prices have a 16% impact on PV capacity. An additional system installed in

the previous year is expected to increase capacity by about 7/10 %. A county with ten new

systems installed in the current year could expect new capacity to increase by 7% the next

year, holding all else constant.

Residential PV demand is fairly inelastic to differences in the number of owner-occupied

(25)

Table 5: Marginal effects at means: demographics and geography

Unit change At (1) (2) (3) (4)

in Mean βˆ ∂E[Y]/∂X ∂E[Y|Y >0]/∂X ∂P(Y >0)/∂X

∆(System count)t−1 13.276 0.0107∗∗∗ 0.00935∗∗∗ 0.00718∗∗∗ 0.00104∗∗∗

(3.81) (3.87) (3.91) (3.45)

Solar resource (kWh/m2/day) 4.495 2.109∗∗ 1.840∗∗ 1.415∗∗ 0.205∗∗

(2.83) (2.82) (2.81) (2.83)

Electricity price (¢/kWh) 13.985 0.242∗∗∗ 0.211∗∗∗ 0.162∗∗∗ 0.0235∗∗∗

(3.65) (3.68) (3.70) (3.42)

Bachelor degree or higher (%) 30.194 -0.00563 -0.00492 -0.00378 -0.000548

(-0.35) (-0.35) (-0.35) (-0.35)

Median Age 40.177 -0.0845∗∗ -0.0737∗∗ -0.0567∗∗ -0.00821∗∗

(-2.43) (-2.44) (-2.46) (-2.31)

Time trend 5.045 0.191∗∗ 0.167∗∗ 0.128∗∗ 0.0185∗∗

(2.87) (2.85) (2.82) (2.95)

Percent change in Elasticities

ln(Owner-occupied homes) 10.435 1.119∗∗∗ 0.976∗∗∗ 0.751∗∗∗ 0.109∗∗∗

(4.55) (4.49) (4.43) (4.62)

ln(Population density) 5.495 -0.756∗∗∗ -0.659∗∗∗ -0.507∗∗∗ -0.0734∗∗∗

(-4.80) (-4.75) (-4.70) (-4.75)

ln(Median home value) 12.053 1.287∗∗∗ 1.124∗∗∗ 0.864∗∗∗ 0.125∗∗∗

(3.55) (3.50) (3.46) (3.65)

t statistics in parentheses

(26)

Table 6: Marginal effects: environmental preferences

Unit change At (1) (2) (3) (4)

in Mean βˆ ∂E[Y]/∂X ∂E[Y|Y >0]/∂X ∂P(Y >0)/∂X

Hybrid vehicle sales (%) 1.943 0.332∗∗ 0.290∗∗ 0.223∗∗ 0.0323∗∗

(2.98) (2.98) (2.98) (2.92)

Democrats (%) 51.917 0.0207∗∗ 0.0181∗∗ 0.0139∗∗ 0.00201∗∗

(2.09) (2.08) (2.08) (2.09)

t statistics in parentheses

+ p <0.1,∗∗ p <0.05,∗∗∗ p <0.001

number of owner-occupied homes is expected to increase residential capacity by about one

percent. PV demand is more inelastic when it comes to population density. A one percent

increase in the population density is expected to decrease capacity by .65%, while a one

percent increase the county median home value is expected to increase capacity by 1.12%.

Next, table 6 presents the marginal effects of pro-environmental preference indicators.

The marginal effects are again evaluated at the sample means.

Hybrid vehicles sales are found to be positively related with residential PV adoption. An

increase from 2% to 3% of hybrid vehicle sales is associated with a roughly 30% increase in

residential capacity. Political party affiliation has a statistically significant effect, but small

in magnitude. If voting rates for the democratic party increase from 52% to 53%, residential

capacity is expected to increase by about 2%.

5.3

Policy impacts

Table 7 presents the per-unit change effects of SREC prices and sales tax exemptions. Sample

means were not used as evaluation points because the averages are skewed due to an absence

of these incentives from several states. Wherever the incentive is not available these variables

take on a value of zero, causing sample means to be far from representative of real world

values. Instead, the effects are evaluated at three representative points of each variable.

SREC prices are evaluated at the mean of observed positive values ($280), and one standard deviations away in each direction ($95, $465). Sales tax exemptions are evaluated at 6% and

(27)

Table 7: Marginal effects: SREC prices and sales taxes Unit change (1) (2) (3) (4) in βˆ ∂E[Y]/∂X ∂E[Y|Y >0]/∂X ∂P(Y >0)/∂X SREC Price ($) at$95 .00176∗∗ 0.00130∗∗ 0.00115∗∗ 0.000125∗∗ (2.04) (2.03) (2.03) (2.01) at$280 .00176∗∗ 0.00134∗∗ 0.00120+ 0.000119∗∗ (2.04) (1.97) (1.96) (2.13) at$465 .00176∗∗ 0.00138+ 0.00124+ 0.000112∗∗ (2.04) (1.92) (1.90) (2.26)

Sales tax exemption (%)

at 6% 0.412∗∗∗ 0.347∗∗∗ 0.304∗∗∗ 0.0292∗∗∗ (6.81) (5.98) (5.98) (7.57) at 8% 0.412∗∗∗ 0.368∗∗∗ 0.330∗∗∗ 0.0228∗∗∗ (6.81) (5.83) (5.69) (13.35) t statistics in parentheses + p <0.1,∗∗ p <0.05,∗∗∗ p <0.001

8%, which are the sales tax rates in Vermont and New York, respectively.

The SREC price effect is significant, although the coefficient is not large. The small effect

may be due to the significant variability in SREC prices since the opening of SREC markets.

A one hundred dollar increase from $95 is estimated to give a 13% boost to residential PV adoption. Negative shifts in SREC markets can likewise negatively impact demand.

These results support anecdotal evidence from Pennsylvania that plummeting SREC prices

slackened demand for new PV installations. Large drop-offs in the SREC incentive may

cause homeowners to question the reliability of these markets for providing a production

incentive throughout the lifespan of the PV system. Future solar carve-out policies may

need to consider price support mechanisms to avoid price shocks and mitigate uncertainty

about SREC markets. Where a sales tax exemption is available, an increase in the sales tax

rate from 6% to 7% is expected to increase residential PV adoption by roughly 35%. States

with higher sales taxes will see somewhat greater gains to adoption as a result of the sales

tax exemption policy.

Next, table 8 presents the marginal effects due to the availability of policies represented

(28)

Table 8: Marginal effects: dummy policy variables

Discrete change (1) (2) (3) (4)

from 0 to 1 βˆ ∂E[Y]/∂X ∂E[Y|Y >0]/∂X ∂P(Y >0)/∂X Rebate (d) 1.351∗∗∗ 0.997∗∗∗ 0.873∗∗∗ 0.108∗∗∗

(6.37) (6.51) (6.58) (5.85)

Income tax credit (d) -0.555+ -0.401+ -0.357+ -0.0387+

(-1.68) (-1.70) (-1.69) (-1.70) Loan program (d) 1.785∗∗∗ 1.369∗∗∗ 1.228∗∗∗ 0.125∗∗∗ (4.77) (4.69) (4.61) (4.95) Solar rights (d) 0.0809 0.0595 0.0527 0.00572 (0.36) (0.36) (0.36) (0.36) t statistics in parentheses + p <0.1,∗∗ p <0.05,∗∗∗ p <0.001

in residential PV capacity due to a discrete change from zero (no policy) to one (policy exists).

Loan programs have the largest impact on residential PV capacity. Availability of a

low-interest solar loan is expected to increase capacity by 137%, holding all else constant.

Rebates also have a strong positive effect, with availability of a rebate expected to increase

capacity by roughly 100%. Income tax credit has an unexpected sign (for reasons discussed

above) and is weakly significant. Solar rights regulations are found to have no significant

effect on residential PV demand.

6

Conclusion

This paper examines the effect of state policy incentives on residential solar PV capacity

growth. It is possible that solar adoption is mainly being driven by pro- environmental

preferences and altruism. In this case, solar policies are inefficient because adopters would

have installed solar PV absent policy incentives. Previous literature has not explored state

policy effects on growth of residential PV capacity, while controlling for demographic and

geographic characteristics, and pro-environmental preferences.

Our empirical results show that policy incentives are significant drivers of solar PV

ca-pacity growth. Solar-specific policies such as the rebate, loan program, sales tax exemption,

(29)

not significant. This result suggests that for PV capacity to grow, policies directly targeted

at solar are needed. Our findings also suggest that policies that reduce the up-front cost

of solar PV installation have the most impact. Of solar-specific policies, the coefficient of

loan program availability has the greatest magnitude, suggesting that credit constraint is a

deterrent to adoption and the availability of financing is just as important as (if not more

so than) direct financial incentives.

Similar to previous studies, we find evidence that demographic characteristics such as

lower median age and income are correlated with PV adoption. The lagged number of solar

installations is also significant suggesting that familiarity with solar PV technology and

in-fluence of adopters within one’s network positively inin-fluence solar PV adoption. In addition,

pro-environmental preferences as indicated by political party affiliation and ownership of

hybrid vehicles are positively related to growth in PV capacity.

We also find evidence that non-policy variables that affect the financial viability of a

solar PV system such as solar insolation and electricity prices are significant, underscoring

the importance of financial considerations in a household’s adoption decision.

The focus of this paper is measuring the impact of solar incentive policies. These policies

are certain to have welfare consequences. While we do not consider the efficiency of solar

PV policies, the magnitude of policy impacts estimated in this study could be used as an

(30)

References

Adelaja, A., Y.G. Hailu, C.H. McKeown, and A.T. Tekle. 2010. “Effects of Renewable Energy

Policies on Wind Industry Development in the US.”

Andreoni, J. 1990. “Impure altruism and donations to public goods: a theory of warm-glow

giving.”The Economic Journal, pp. 464–477.

Barbose, G., N. Darghouth, and R. Wiser. 2012. “Tracking the Sun V An Historical

Sum-mary of the Installed Price of Photovoltaics in the United States from 1998 to 2011.”

Environmental Energy Technologies Division, Lawrence Berkeley National Laboratory.

Bollinger, B., and K. Gillingham. 2012. “Peer effects in the diffusion of solar photovoltaic

panels.”Marketing Science 31:900–912.

Carley, S. 2009. “State renewable energy electricity policies: An empirical evaluation of

effectiveness.”Energy Policy 37:3071–3081.

Dastrup, S.R., J. Graff Zivin, D.L. Costa, and M.E. Kahn. 2012. “Understanding the Solar

Home price premium: Electricity generation and Green social status.”European Economic

Review 56:961–973.

DSIRE. 2013. “Database of State Incentives for Renewables and Efficiency.” available at

www.dsireusa.org.

Geographic Research Inc. 2011. “SimmonsLOCAL Consumer Survey Data.” Retrieved from

SimplyMap databasewww.simplymap.com.

GTM Research and Solar Energy Industries Association. 2014. “US Solar

Mar-ket Insight (TM): 2013 Year in Review (Executive Summary).” Retrieved from

http://www.seia.org/research-resources/solar-market-insight-report-2013-year-review.

Hausman, J.A. 1979. “Individual Discount Rates and the Purchase and Utilization of

(31)

Kwan, C.L. 2012. “Influence of local environmental, social, economic and political variables

on the spatial distribution of residential solar PV arrays across the United States.”Energy

Policy 47:332–344.

Labay, D.G., and T.C. Kinnear. 1981. “Exploring the consumer decision process in the

adoption of solar energy systems.” Journal of Consumer Research, pp. 271–278.

Lopez, A., B. Roberts, D. Heimiller, N. Blair, and G. Porro. 2012. “US Renewable Energy

Technical Potentials: A GIS-Based Analysis.”Contract 303:275–3000.

Lutzenhiser, L. 1993. “Social and behavioral aspects of energy use.”Annual Review of Energy

and the Environment 18:247–289.

Maguire, K. 2011. “What’s Powering Wind? The Role of Prices and Policies in Determining

the Amount of Wind Energy Development in the United States (1994-2008).” In 2011

Annual Meeting, July 24-26, 2011, Pittsburgh, Pennsylvania. Agricultural and Applied

Economics Association, 103599.

Menz, F.C., and S. Vachon. 2006. “The effectiveness of different policy regimes for promoting

wind power: Experiences from the states.” Energy Policy 34:1786–1796.

National Atlas of the United States. 2009. “2008 Presidential General Election, County

Results.” available at www.nationatlas.gov.

Noll, D., C. Dawes, and V. Rai. 2014. “Solar Community Organizations and active peer

effects in the adoption of residential PV.” Energy Policy 67:330–343.

NREL. 2013. “National Renewable Energy Laboratory.” available at openpv.nrel.gov.

Sexton, S.E., and A.L. Sexton. 2014. “Conspicuous conservation: The Prius halo and

will-ingness to pay for environmental bona fides.” Journal of Environmental Economics and

(32)

Sidiras, D.K., and E.G. Koukios. 2004. “Solar systems diffusion in local markets.” Energy

Policy 32:2007–2018.

Smith, D. 2013. “IBISWorld Industry Report 22111e Solar Power in the US.”

U.S. Energy Information Adiminstration (EIA). 2011. “Direct Federal Financial

Interven-tions and Subsidies in Energy in Fiscal Year 2010.”

—. 2014. “Electric Power Monthly with Data for January 2014.” avaliable at www.eia.gov.

Wiser, R., G. Barbose, and E. Holt. 2011. “Supporting solar power in renewables portfolio

standards: Experience from the United States.” Energy Policy 39:3894–3905.

Wooldridge, J.M. 2010. Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data.

Yin, H., and N. Powers. 2010. “Do state renewable portfolio standards promote in-state

renewable generation.” Energy Policy 38:1140–1149.

Zahran, S., S.D. Brody, A. Vedlitz, M.G. Lacy, and C.L. Schelly. 2008. “Greening local

energy: explaining the geographic distribution of household solar energy use in the United

References

Related documents

This work will primarily draw on existing literature and analysis of several far-right political movements around the world to attempt to characterize the LDP as fitting into

The two chapters of my thesis are guided by the questions ‘why have women rappers been left out of the gangsta rap canon?’ and the ‘what changes about our understanding of

The concept of domination in fuzzy graphs was first introduced by A Somasundaram and S Somasundaram [8]. S.Revathy and C.V.R Harinarayanan[4] developed the concept Connected

Figure 2.23 (a) Charge/discharge profiles of cells assembled with HM LNMO cathode or control LNMO one, (b) charge/discharge capacities per cathode area (mAh

Most of these records represent extensions of the nort­ hern borders of the known areas of distribution of the different species along the coast from the province

Clothing dramatically altered the size and depth of the expanding cavity, as well as increased lateral pressures, resulting in more severe fractures with greater bullet distances

Where Standard List equipment has previously been supplied to a client and needs to be replaced (like for like) the ACC Case Owner can submit an ACC96 equipment request for

7DHC: 7-dihydrocholesterol; BSA: Bovine serum albumin; CDU: Collagen digestion units; -CoA: Acetyl- Coenzyme A; ENS: Enteric nervous system; ER: Endoplasmic reticulum; FBS: Fetal