• No results found

The Design of a Best Execution Market

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "The Design of a Best Execution Market"

Copied!
18
0
0

Loading.... (view fulltext now)

Full text

(1)

The Design of a Best Execution Market

Miroslav Budimir (mailto:miroslav@budimir.de),

Carsten Holtmann (mailto:carsten.holtmann@iw.uni-karlsruhe.de),

Dirk Neumann (mailto:dirk.neumann@iw.uni-karlsruhe.de),

Chair for Information Management and Systems Universität Karlsruhe (TH) Englerstrasse 14 76 131 Karlsruhe Germany Phone +49 (0) 721 608 8375 Fax +49 (0) 721 608 8399 http:// www.iw.uni-karlsruhe.de

(2)

Abstract

The notion of best execution on securities markets is manifold. Best execution has different meanings to different market participants. Therefore, it is difficult to find a unique market structure that meets the requirements of all the participants.

Traditional market structures are either static or flexible, meaning that an individual market participant does not have any choice concerning the concrete market structure's characteristics for his transaction, like e. g. the price discovery mechanism, trading frequency or the market transparency.

Focusing on customer orientation, we propose a new type of market structure: the dynamic market model, where participants individually choose the characteristics of the market structure for each transaction they perform. Furthermore, this paper offers an approach to design dynamic market models from scratch. W e briefly sketch the necessary steps towards a dynamic market model.

Finally, we present AMTRAS; the prototype of an electronic trading system that was conceived and implemented following the aforementioned approach. AMTRAS is a bond trading system based on software-agent technology and designed for the needs of institutional investors. It implements a dynamic market model, a sophisticated product- and partner matching scheme as well as an innovative price discovery approach.

(3)

The Design of a Best Execution Market

1

The term best execution is used by the New York Stock Exchange (NYSE) since the 1970ies (Levitt 1999). Most scientists in the field of finance do agree that the notion of best execution does not attribute to one single factor, but its common use is in many cases inconsistent and it often refers to ”best price” only.

In our opinion best execution depends on a wide variety of elements and has to be analyzed from two different perspectives:

i. The investor’s perspective:

Each investor (each group of investors with homogeneous demands, respectively) has her own understanding of best execution depending on a huge number of possible demand or execution factors like speed, price, market impact etc. The relevance of each single element’s contribution to the goal of best execution is contingent upon the individual demands of the investor regarding the product to be traded.

ii. The market’s design perspective:

Even though the discussion of best execution often aims at the question of broker’s responsibility to ensure execution quality for their clients (see Levitt 1999), we follow Macey and O’Hara taking a closer look upon the question of market design: ”best execution must be considered within the context of market structure” (Macey and O’Hara 1997, p. 220). Instead of defining best execution as a question of order routing, we consider it to be a question of customer orientation in market design. As ”each trading structure provides a different vector of execution attributes and services a different clientele” (Macey and O’Hara 1997, p. 220) designing one market structure that allows best execution for a number of investors remains a question of high complexity and unseldom huge compromises.

This article deals with these circumstances and introduces the idea of dynamic market models as a concept to more customer orientation in the design of markets.

The paper is organized as follows. First, we will illustrate demand characteristics respectively execution factors

of different investor groups and the resulting complexity implied in the design of markets. Then, the notion of

1

We would like to thank the editor, Frank Lierman, and the participants of the 23rd SUERF Colloquium for helpful comments.

(4)

static and flexible market models will be introduced, followed by the idea of dynamic market structures – the possibility to individually configure the structural features of a market. This market model is then illustrated by a research prototype that was implemented as a proof of concept in section two. The last section will outline some conclusive remarks and address future research.

1. The Design of Best Execution Markets

1.1. Best Execution: Different Things to Different People

Most scientists and practitioners in the field of finance agree that the notion of best execution does not attribute to one single factor, like the execution price. Instead, it seems more likely that best execution depends on a wide variety of elements. Although the literature does not provide an encyclopedic list of factors, a few articles are helpful to identify the most important ones. From Wagner and Edwards (1993), Macey and O’Hara (1997, p. 189), the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC 1977) and NYSE’s Market Structure Report (NYSE 2000, p. 14) follows that the main determinants are trading costs (market impact, transaction costs, etc.), the trading mechanism, access to different markets, trading strategy, market transparency, opportunity for price improvement and speed of execution.

Though it is nearly impossible to list all the relevant best execution factors, the ones stated above may limit the amount of all possible factors to what we consider as very important ones. Howe ver, these papers do not identify the relevance of each factor concerning a specific investor group: Institutional investors have different needs than individual investors. Traders have different requirements than securities dealers. But even within these groups there are heterogeneous requirements, e. g. depending on a specific situation: An institutional trader prefers a low transparency setting when trading a block, while the same trader prefers a high quote transparency when trading a liquidity-motivated small order.

These considerations show that best execution is an indistinct matter: Each clientele has different requirements towards best execution factors. Furthermore, these requirements differ also regarding products traded, e.g. the needs of an investor trading blue chip stocks will probably not be the same when the same investor trades illiquid bonds. Some conceivable market participants and some execution factors are depicted in figure 1.

(5)

Best Execution Factors fast execution low commissions market impact trading strategies market information speed of inf. dissemination anonymity

individual identity disclosure access to different markets innovative market design convenient trading certainty of order execution indicative offers technical improvements

speculators arbitrageurs conservative medium-risk high-risk average star traders

short term traders long term traders pension funds mutual funds insurances liquidity traders / CMS friendly hostile conventional online

bank’s own account trading funds firms m&a fiscal agents funds investors individual investors pure dealers broker-dealers

factor of major relevance

factor of medium relevance

insignificant factor

institutional investors retail investors dealers

Market Participants

Figure 1: The Matrix of Best Execution

Moreover, these reflections point out the ambiguities in the meaning of economic best execution. Yet, we elaborate on the possibility to allow each investor to configure the market according to what she assumes to be best execution. As we demonstrate, this goal hinges upon the underlying market model. In this chapter we therefore pick-up the issue of market models. In particular, we propose a specific type of market model which we consider promising to approach our goal of best execution. In order to implement this in practice, we suggest a procedure that is generally apt to stress customer orientation throughout the process of market design.

1.2. Traditional Market Models

In literature the notion of a market model – often dubbed as market structure – has been controversially discussed for a long time. The German Stock exchange, for instance, defines the market model as ”the mechanism of matching orders to trades in the exchange trading system” (Deutsche Börse 2000, p. 7). This

(6)

narrow definition, however, refers only to securities that are traded on stock exchanges and comprises neither the off-market securities trading nor commodity trading as a whole.

A more comprehensive approach tends to the structural features of markets such as price discovery, trading frequency etc. (see Gomber 2000, pp. 10-11). Each of the features can have several characteristics.

The market maker principle employed by the Nasdaq until 1997 is an example for one possible characteristic of the feature ”price discovery”, whereas most of the Electronic Communication Networks (ECN), e. g. Island, rely on continuous auctions (Island 2000). Accordingly, the configuration of the structural features of the market determines the concrete market model. However, these characteristics are not necessarily fixed over time. Recall that trading on the NYSE actually involves two different trading mechanisms: A call auction is used to open trading, whereas a continuous auction is applied until the end of the trading day (O’Hara 1995, p. 10, 179). On the other hand there are cases where these characteristics are not subject to change. This case, for instance, applied at the Nasdaq before the Order handling rules (OHR) were introduced. Until then, only the market maker principle was employed: dealers offered their quotes, traders hit them (see Huang and Stoll 1996, p. 318).2 From this examples it becomes obvious that not only the combination of the characteristics but also an additional determinant – the degree of the characteristic’s variability – is crucial for the market model. Following this insight, market models can be distinguished into three categories, being

• static,

• flexible and

• dynamic market models.

A static market model denotes the case where exogenous factors (i. e. factors independent from the market occurrences) determine the structural features’ characteristics (see Budimir and Gomber 1999, p. 255). An example will be helpful for comprehension: The feature ”price discovery” at the aforementioned ECN Island has only one characterization, that being a continuous double auction. The trading rules – i. e. to implement just one price discovery mechanism – are set independent from the events taking place on the market.

2

In 1997, the Nasdaq implemented a hybrid market by adopting new OHR. The limit order display rule requires a market maker to publicly display a trader’s order if it is inside the spread. These orders can be executed without the interposition of a market maker.

(7)

Beside this trivial case the classification of market models that facilitate a change of the characteristics is more sophisticated. The NYSE provides a vivid example of a static market model. The exogenous factor trading time determines the trading mechanism: At the beginning of the trading day there is a call auction. After that, trading takes place using a continuous auction.

A flexible market model denotes the case where endogenous factors – i. e. factors that are the result of special market events – determine the characteristics of the market structure (see Budimir and Gomber 1999, p. 256). The circuit breaker of the Xetra system appears to be an appropriate example. It occurs whenever the next execution price lies outside a specified price range. As a consequence, continuous trading is instantaneously interrupted and a call auction is initiated (Deutsche Börse 2000).

However, both static and flexible market models cannot meet the heterogeneous requirements of all the different market participants. Applied to the case of securities markets, the ability to fulfil investor’s needs is crucial for the success of both stock exchanges and ECNs, respectively. Yet, stock exchanges have traditionally adopted either flexible or static market models that are incapable of meeting all the investors demands. Their services usually comprise transactions designed for the ”medium investor”. The lack of flexibility is a major reason why a variety of ECNs have emerged which seek to offer specific transaction services for special niches. This shortcoming of traditional market models leads us to the third category, namely to dynamic market models.

1.3. Dynamic Market Models as a Solution

A dynamic market model denotes the case where market participants themselves choose market structure’s characteristics for each transaction. This concept aims to provide the market participants with a toolbox that enables them to select the most proper trading vehicle according to their individual preferences (see Gomber 2000, p. 99). Schwartz uses a resembling metaphor: ”As with any shopping mall, the trader (customer), when entering the market, would select the specific modality (store) that best suits his or her needs, given the size of the order, the trading characteristics of the stock, and that customer’s desire to trade quickly or willingness to be patient” (Schwartz 1998, p. 149). The multiple-platform market structure proposed by the NYSE (2000) exemplifies the concept of dynamic market models:

(8)

The NYSE introduced two innovative trading systems within it’s Network NYSETM initiative:3 Institutional XPressTM for block trading and NYSE Direct+TM for retail orders. By providing a multiple-platform market structure the investor may choose between two price discovery mechanisms. She can either select a floor based agency auction or an automatic execution through an electronic trading system. The floor based agency auction of the NYSE traditionally embodies a high concentration of liquidity due to the large number of market participants. The investors on the NYSE floor are represented by the so-called crowd, i. e. brokers that come to the post to seek an execution. The competition among the crowd leads to an adequate price discovery. On the other hand, an automatic execution especially takes the demand for execution speed into account. Both trading mechanisms and market structures are left to fair competition but within the bounds of a single marketplace (NYSE 2000, p. 11). The dynamic market model approach, however, is even more far-reaching, since it permits a tailor-made compilation of all features.

Overall, dynamic market models appear to be superior to traditional market models since they allow investors to choose the most benefiting trading vehicle according to their preferences. The choice of the structural features, however, implies that the trading system has to verify the mutual interoperability of the chosen market models before two corresponding orders can match.4 The trade may take place only if their structural features coincide. This market model clearly divides the market into several market segments. Each of the market segments is distinguished by a different degree of market transparency, price discovery etc. One might discern that this configuration will reduce the liquidity of the entire market: If, at one hand, we have a buyer who prefers a continuous double auction as price discovery mechanism for his order and, at the other hand, there is a seller who prefers a call auction, there will be no matching at all – even if all the other order parameters match.5 This argument can be softened regarding the desire for alternative market models that finally led to the evolvement of

3

The NYSE has recognized that the technical development requires amendments concerning their market structure in order to provide their customers best execution in NYSE-listed stocks. The committee of public directors of the NYSE motivates the deployment of technological advances and regulatory changes as long as they serve the best execution principle (NYSE 2000, p. 14). At first, the inquiry of the market structure leads among others to recommend the implementation of a multiple-platform market structure.

4

Therefore new matching protocols or algorithms have to be implemented besides the trivial case of single-item (i. e. price) matching. Successive or parallel multi-attribute matching routines might be conceivable (for more information to the topic of electronic negotiations refer to http://enegotiations.wu-wien.ac.at/).

5

There are other structural features’ characteristics that are not that essential, e. g. anonymity. If one player reveals his identity to the market while his trading partner does not, the order can still be executed.

(9)

ECNs. Hence, the provision of a dynamic market model does not additionally fragment the market. It rather concentrates distinct transaction orders in one marketplace (see Gomber 2000, p. 159).

NYSE’s push forward suggesting a multiple -platform market model clearly breaks with the tradition of static and flexible market models. Due to the dynamic market model’s immanent advantages, the NYSE approach is considered promising. Hitherto lack of transaction data empirical evidence is not yet given.

A market that embodies a dynamic market model, however, still cannot provide the full range of best execution demanded by the full range of investors. Nonetheless, such a market is in the position to meet the diverse demands of a predetermined investor group and can be gradually enriched: The implementation of a dynamic market model from scratch is rather difficult. Different market segments require the provision of different structural features. The selection of the predetermined investor group thus has an impact on the adequate market model. To simplify the design process, we suggest to comply with the following procedure (see figure 2).

product selection investor identification demand evaluation (execution factors) market model design (structural features) implementation & experimental tests

Figure 2: The Market Design Process

As a first step, the product selection divides the total market into market segments and thereby reduces complexity. While the demands of all investors are multifaceted, partly even inconsistent with each other, the demands of investors pertaining to the same market segment may have at least quasi-homogeneous demands. Secondly, the various market participants have to be identified. In the third step, surveys performed on the identified investor groups yield the demands with respect to best execution. In this context the influence of customs and practices on the demand must be recognized. At this point, a “matrix of best execution” – as depicted in figure 1 – can be a helpful tool to depict each investor group’s preferences regarding each relevant factor. Figure 1 provides an arbitrary example, introducing three preference levels. Empirical data may assist to set up the matrix. In step 4, the conceptual market design (see Neumann 2001) and it’s IT (information technology) implementation is performed. Basically each of the structural attributes, mainly the price discovery mechanisms, have to be attuned to the demands in order to achieve a high level of customer orientation. Finally,

(10)

the evaluation (step 5) of the system may ideally be conducted by a multi-tier testing procedure: Tier 1 regards functionality (debugging), tier 2 encompasses experimental tests in order to ensure the desired market performance without detrimental effects on the market outcome. Finally, tier 3 regards the post-introduction phase. In this phase, actual market participants (traders) are involved in order to check how the system meets their requirements. Effective ways to determine the degree of requirement satisfaction are questionnaires and expert interviews.

In each of the phases it is allowed to step back to prior ones, to reconfigure or enhance the model.

The stated arguments presented in this chapter gave rise to the implementation of a trading system which we introduce in the following chapter. Moreover, we briefly sketch the design process exemplifying the suggested procedure.

2. AMTRAS: The Case of a Dynamic Market Model

The prototype AMTRAS6 (Agent Mediated Trading System) was developed as an Internet trading system for institutional bond trading (see Weinhardt and Gomber 1999). The trading system utilizes the innovative technology of software agents and thus differs substantially from conventional trading systems.7 It’s main purpose was the proof of concept for dynamic market models. We focus on the German institutional bond market because the trading process on this market is overall inefficient: About 90% of bond trades are conducted over-the-counter, by bilateral negotiations via phone or a broker’s intermediation. Neither exchanges nor electronic bond trading systems are utilized by market participants because the existing market structures do not account for their heterogeneous needs. Market data supports this observation: Only 10% of the trades are conducted via exchanges, the portion traded on electronic systems is even smaller (see Weinhardt and Gomber 1999). Evidently, this phenomenon reveals weaknesses of electronic trading systems adopting traditional market models. An attempt to establish a successful bond trading system must particularly fulfil the needs of the most

6

The project was a joint venture of the Chair for Information Systems at the faculty of Economics, Giessen University, in association with the Deutsche Börse, Compaq and the software company living systems,

Donaueschingen (Germany). 7

Software agents are ”computational systems that inhabit some complex dynamic environment, sense and act autonomously in this environment, and by doing so realize a set of goals or tasks for which they are designed” (Maes 1994).

(11)

important investor group, namely institutional investors who prevail bond trading (step 2 from the market design process described in section 1.3).

A survey was performed on German institutional investors in order to extract their requirements for this specific market (step 3). According to the survey, best execution comprises the following sections:

The involvement of a broker always bears the risk of information leakage: The broker can take advantage of his information and run in front of his customer’s order, avoiding it’s price impact. Thus, the avoidance of front-running is a requirement institutional investors impose on the trading process. From this, a similar requirement results: the preference of institutional investors to remain anonymous in the trading process. Especially when large volumes are traded, a trader wants to avoid the resulting price impact. This can be achieved by reducing pre-trade market transparency. Ideally for a block trader, the order is being executed on a market with no quote transparency. Also, if the information about a block trader’s identity is being disseminated, this might hazard the broker’s reputation – a major asset in the investment business.

Liquidity clearly remains the central aspect of markets. However, liquidity is rather the result of a market’s ability to satisfy the needs of the investors. The design of the market model can at most indirectly influence liquidity. Only if all the needs of the investors are met, order flow can be accrued by adding additional liquidity to the market.

The next requirement follows from the assumption that securities of one issuer are – more or less – substitutes. For instance, an investor might prefer a long position of a German Jumbo-Pfandbrief with a maturity of ten years and/or a nominal interest rate of 5%. However, if this security cannot be found, the trader might be satisfied with ”near” values (“fuzzy search”), e. g. a maturity of eleven years and/or 4,75%. In order to address this requirement, the trading system needs a sophisticated product matching scheme – ideally one that differs from and enhances the existing ”ISIN”-matching schemes.

Due to lack of regulation, one pitfall of OTC markets is the contingency risk: If one of the partners does not fulfil his obligations, the counterparty might suffer substantial losses. In order to address this risk, participants on the OTC markets prefer to transact only with partners they know well. Traditional trading systems trying to intrude the bond market did not succeed to overcome this difficulty: Most of these systems failed to implement a suitable counterparty search mechanism.

The demand for immediacy of a transaction is controversial. This controversy stems from the trade-off between immediacy and transaction costs. For example a temporal consolidation (e. g. intraday auction) collects orders

(12)

over a specific time span raising the liquidity of the auction. This positive impact on the (implicit) transaction costs is accrued on the expense of immediacy.

The results of the survey yield – beside homogeneous requirements for the dedicated investor group – also heterogeneous requirements among them. This obviously requires the application of alternative trading vehicles. Within the fourth step, the system is designed conceptually and implemented by means of IT.

In order to meet these, heterogeneous requirements, AMTRAS introduces the notion of dynamic market models by utilizing innovative software agent technology. The possibility to chose the most appropriate market mechanism individually and for each transaction separately enables investors to find best execution within the framework of one marketplace. The trader can individually configure the characteristics price discovery and

degree of order obligation. Also, the search for a suitable product and a counterparty offers a maximum of flexibility. All these features explicitly consider investors’ contradictory requirements. The selection of the desired market model hence grants the flexibility which is comparable with the flexibility in the existing off-exchange markets (see Gomber 2000, p. 158).

The electronic trading process implemented in AMTRAS differs substantially from the conventional (electronic) trading process. It is represented by a multidimensional, multi-staged negotiation protocol and sequentially pursues three distinct stages. All stages together determine the terms of the transaction (see figure 3).

(13)

Figure 3: The Dynamic Market Model of AMTRAS

The trader initiates the trading process by specifying and submitting his order. In AMTRAS, an order is represented by a software agent. The agent, who acts on the trader’s behalf, is equipped with a trading strategy and sent to the trading platform. It interacts with other agents, each of belonging to a distinct trader. The agents interact and ”live” on the trading platform(s) – i. e. one or more servers, to whom all trader-clients are connected. Following a successful product- and counterparty search the agents perform a price discovery process. After a successful match, both (or more) agents return to their traders and inform them about the terms of trade.

Next, the AMTRAS trading process is described in more detail. At stage 1, the product matching is performed. In this phase, the requirement towards a flexible product search is implemented. During the order specification, a trader has the possibility to specify either a concrete ISIN or the type of security traded. In the case of a fuzzy product specification, the trader may additionally specify exact values or a range of both nominal interest rate and maturity.

On success (i. e. when one agent “finds” an agent that represents a matching product) the agent triggers the second stage: the counterparty search. This stage accounts for the aforementioned contingency – or counterparty

Specification of the parameters by traders

Search process

partner matching (stage 1) product matching (stage 2)

notification of potential partners bargaining over security and price via telephone

Pricing Process (stage 3)

simple search “search and chat”

electronically supported interactive chat computerized bargaining feedback: price and volume stylized Vickrey auction auction enhanced bi- or multilateral negotiation negotiation graphical representation of trading strategies

(14)

– risk that particularly aggravates off-exchange trades. In AMTRAS a trader can specify individual search clusters: From a population he draws a subset of institutions/traders that he exclusively wants to transact with. A trader’s agent will only find agents belonging to that cluster – others will explicitly be ruled out. By doing so the counterparty risk is not completely eliminated but to a certain extent alleviated (see Edwards, 1995). At this stage, two explanations must be made: First, the search cluster can be altered for each transaction and by each trader individually. Second, the sequence of step one and two is not crucial; the same result would have been accomplished if the system first identified the relevant partners, in order to perform a product search in stage two.

After successful product and counterparty search, the agent faces one (or more) matching partners. At stage 3, price discovery is performed. AMTRAS supports four distinct mechanisms. These are

i. Search with conventional price discovery. After a successful product- and partner matching, the agents return to their traders presenting them a list of one (or more) potential trading partner(s) and corresponding products. Now, further negotiations can be performed the traditional way via phone.

ii. “Search-and-Chat” price discovery. Instead of a simple search, further negotiations can be performed as a bi- or multilateral bargaining process, that being an electronically supported interactive negotiation between trading partners. In AMTRAS, there is a possibility to ”Search and Chat” via an integrated chat system, that routes offers to the corresponding partner and disp lays them on the trader’s screen.

iii. AMTRAS auction. This is a modification of the auction described by Vickrey (1961). This auction is tailor-made for the needs of institutional bond traders. It is optimized for block trading, because it enables the trader to execute his order in a low-transparency environment, while it offers the opportunity to collect many retail orders on the opposite side with a simultaneous price improvement.

iv. AMTRAS negotiation. This is an enhanced negotiation facility that offers bi- and multilateral graphical supported negotiations. It offers traders the possibility to pre-specify their trading strategy. This strategy is employed autonomously by the agent without the need for trader’s intervention. Nevertheless, an intervention is still possible at any point of the negotiation, which makes the process completely interactive. By the employment of competitive bidding on both sides, a high level of price quality can be assured.

As we previously stated, the needs of the traders may be heterogeneous. The dynamic market model provides various price mechanisms being apt to guarantee best execution individually.

(15)

The depicted multidimensional negotiation is realized by the use of software agents. Software agents adopt the preferences and strategies of their human counterparts and pursue them on behalf of the trader in an appropriate manner. This feature eliminates the risk of front-running because the software agent’s goals should always be in accordance with the principal’s. Moreover, the interposition of agents conforms with the demand for anonymity (see Weinhardt, Gomber and Holtmann 2000, p. 830).

Since it is impossible to recognize all the effects the new trading system might have to the market – for instance the possibility to hit stale quotes with the SOES introduction at the Nasdaq –, it is advisable to use the techniques of experimental economics to perform laboratory tests before its final release. The major challenge within this step is to find an appropriate experimental design, one that depicts the real-world as good as possible within the realms of the experimental environment. The findings of the experimental tests can be used to improve the system as well as to supply new insights to the other steps in the market design process.

3. Conclusion

In this article we present an approach to more customer orientation in (financial) market design. We introduce the matrix of best execution illustrating the complexity when heterogeneous demands are given.

The idea of dynamic market models is introduced giving the opportunity to combine heterogeneous structural features into one market structure allowing an individual compilation of factors by each investor. Dynamic market models thereby increase customer orientation and the possibility to achieve best execution transactions by providing a toolbox to the investors. We suggest a five step approach in creating customer oriented markets. Therefore, the application of the design process on the German bond trading market (AMTRAS) is used to point out our before mentioned statements using innovative price discovery mechanisms, i. e. the possibility of bi- and multilateral negotiations that could be delegated to software agents.

Current and future research targets the following aspects:

i. We are currently designing and performing experimental tests with the AMTRAS system (phase 5) to ensure customer satisfaction and to enhance system’s capabilities.

ii. Additionally, we are transferring our existing approach to different problems in this context. Taking the growing relevance of private investors into account (see Weinhardt, Gomber and Holtmann 2000, p. 826 and Holtmann et al. 2001), we do focus on stock market design, filling the structural features with innovative solutions (see also Budimir and Holtmann 2001).

(16)

iii. As we do not consider the aforementioned aspects regarding the design of best execution markets to be valid for financial markets exclusively, we are currently moving ahead on the product dimension in our best execution matrix and are transferring our approaches towards energy (see Strecker and Weinhardt 2000) and other kinds of commodity markets.

As in current B2B (Business-to-Business) or B2C (Business-to-Customer) markets respectively exchanges, market structures are static and the price discovery is reduced to quite simple protocols – namely auctions (see e. g. Ströbel 1999), we do think that our concepts have to be transferred to other than financial markets as well.

The transfer of financial markets’ approaches – targeting price discovery as well as ma rket microstructure theory as whole – towards the trading of commodities of all kinds is promising to overcome current limitations and to attain time -to-market and quality advantages for innovative players in designing tomorrows markets. Actually players are recognizing the lack of existing markets as they state:

”Hybrid models allow existing participants to connect and interact in even more ways, providing the flexibility that real worlds markets demand and spawning more transactions within the marketplace. Because each mechanism attacks a different business inefficiency, the market that provides the full range of trading mechanisms will most optimally serve its buying and selling communities, as well as create complementary revenue streams for itself.”

(see IDAPTA 2000)

A lot of effort has to be made to transfer existing concepts and approaches to build financial as well as generic markets following the best execution idea.

References

Budimir, Miroslav and Peter Gomber (1999). "Dynamische Marktmodelle im elektronischen Wertpapierhandel." Wirtschaftsinformatik 41 (3), pp. 218-225.

Budimir, Miroslav and Carsten Holtmann (2001). “The Design of innovative Securities Markets: The Case of Asymmetric Information.” In: Buhl, Hans-Ulrich et al. (eds.): “E-Finance: Innovative Problemlösungen für Informationssysteme in der Finanzwirtschaft“, Berlin et al.: Springer, pp. 175-196.

Deutsche Börse (2000). "Market Model Stock Trading Release 4.0". On-line at http://www.xetra.de.

Edwards, Franklin R. (1995). "Off-Exchange Derivatives Markets and Financial Fragility". Journal of Financial Services Research 9 (3/4), pp. 259-290.

(17)

Holtmann, Carsten, Christoph Lattemann, Stefan Strecker and Christof Weinhardt (2001). “Transforming Financial Markets to Retail Investors: A Comparison of the U.S. and the German On-line Brokerage Market.” In: Proceedings of the 34th Hawaii Conference on System Sciences (HICSS 2001), IEEE Computer Society. Huang, Roger D. and Hans R Stoll (1996). "Dealer versus Auction Markets: A Paired Comparison of Execution Costs on NASDAQ and the NYSE". Journal of Financial Economics 41 (3), pp. 313-357.

IDAPTA (2000). “eMarkets to Face Market-Driven Challenges.” On-line at http://www.idapta.com/insight/whitepapers/.

Island (2000). "How Island Works." On-line at http://www.island.com/about/howitworks.htm.

Levitt, Arthur (1999). “Best Execution: Promise of Integrity, Guardian of Competition.” Remarks by SEC Chairman Arthur Levitt at the Securities Industry Association, Boca Raton, Florida, November 4, 1999. On-line at http:www.sec.gov/news/speeches/spch315.htm.

Macey, Jonathan R. and Maureen O’Hara (1997). "The Law and Economics of Best Execution." Journal of Financial Intermediation 6 (3), pp. 188-223.

Maes, Pati (1994). "Modeling Adaptive Autonomous Agents", Artificial Life Journal 1 (1&2), pp. 135-162. Neumann, Dirk (2001). Design Aspects of Electronic Negotiations. Working Paper. Chair for Information Management and Systems, Universität Karlsruhe (TH), Germany. December.

NYSE (2000): Market Structure Report of the New York Stock Exchange Special Committee on Market Structure, Governance and Ownership. New York.

O’Hara, Maureen (1995). Market Microstructure Theory. Blackwell Publishers, Malden, MA (USA) and Oxford (UK).

Schwartz, Robert A. (1998). "Technology’s Impact on the Equity Markets." In: Chris F. Kemerer (ed.): Information Technology and Industrial Competitiveness: How Information Technology Shapes Competition. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers, pp. 137-152.

SEC (1977). Securities and Exchange Commission's Second Report on Bank Securities Activities, at 97-98, n. 233 as reprinted in H. R. Rep. No. 145, 95 Cong., 1st Sess. 233 (Comm. Print 1977).

Strecker, Stefan and Christof Weinhardt (2000). “Electronic OTC Trading in the German Wholesale Electricity Market.” In: Proceedings of the First International Conference on Electronic Commerce and Web Technologies (EC-Web 2000). Heidelberg et. al.: Springer, pp. 280-290.

Ströbel, Michael (1999). ”Effects of electronic Markets on Negotiation Processes – Evaluating Protocol Suitability”, Research Report (#93237), IBM Research, Zurich, Switzerland.

Vickrey, William (1961). “Counterspeculation, Auctions, and Competitive Sealed Tender.“ Journal of Finance 16 (1), pp. 8-37.

Wagner, Wayne H. and Mark Edwards (1993). "Best Execution." Financial Analysts Journal 49 (january – february), pp. 65-71.

(18)

Weinhardt, Christof and Peter Gomber (1999). "Agent-Mediated Off-Exchange Trading.” In: Proceedings of the 32nd Ha waii Conference on System Sciences (HICSS 1999). IEEE Computer Society.

Weinhardt, Christof, Peter Gomber and Carsten Holtmann (2000). "Online-Brokerage: Transforming Markets from Professional to Retail Trading." In: Hansen, Hans Robert et al. (eds.): Proceedings of the 8th European Conference on Information Systems (ECIS), vol. 2. Vienna: University of Economics and Business Administration, Department of Management Information Systems, pp. 826-832.

Figure

Figure 1: The Matrix of Best Execution
Figure 2: The Market Design Process
Figure 3: The Dynamic Market Model of AMTRAS

References

Related documents

In this study we investigated effects of three restoration treatments—roller chopping, prescribed burning, and a combination of the two—applied in either summer or winter, on

Therefore, there are certain codes of behaviour and, more deeply, the desired emotions (like empathy) connected to identity and attachment, that play a role in sustaining the

The Center for Higher Education Policy Analysis (CHEPA) in the Rossier School of Education, at the University of Southern California directed a 3-year research initiative, Financial

This paper focuses on the specific problems in the labour and social security legislation as it relates to crowdworkers, analysing their place in labour markets,

Each of the resulting systems was then evaluated on the same test data and the WER improvement (positive or negative) was added to contribution score of every sentence included

The continuous time series data consisting of the demon- strator base body and joint angles was used to incrementally learn the motion primitives and the higher order model, using

14 Register Online: www.pecs.com | 888-732-7462 (Mon-Fri, 9am-5pm Eastern Time) Pyramid Package A: PECS Level 1 Training: Basic and Teaching Critical Communication Skills

Mar-Ortiz, Julio; González-Velarde, José Luis; Adenso-Díaz, Belarmino Reverse Logistics Models and Algorithms: Optimizing WEEE Recovery Systems Computación y Sistemas,