• No results found

Competition Between Imported Tilapia and US Catfish in the US Market

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Competition Between Imported Tilapia and US Catfish in the US Market"

Copied!
16
0
0

Loading.... (view fulltext now)

Full text

(1)

199

Competition Between Imported Tilapia

and US Catfish in the US Market

ANA NORMAN-LÓPEZ

CSIRO Marine and Atmospheric Research

FRANK ASCHE

University of Stavanger

Abstract This paper investigates the competition between domestic catfish fil-lets and imported tilapia filfil-lets in the US market. The market segmentation between fresh and frozen fillets of both species is also considered. The substitut-ability between catfish and tilapia is of interest because market reports have recently suggested that the rapid increase in tilapia imports in the last few years is the result of tilapia taking market share from domestically produced catfish. The competition between fresh and frozen fillets of catfish and tilapia imports in the same market is examined using market integration and demand analysis. The results indicate that imports of fresh and frozen tilapia fillets lie in different market segments, while fresh and frozen catfish fillets compete in the same mar-ket. Furthermore, fresh and frozen fillets of catfish and tilapia imports do not compete in the same market.

Key words Catfish, demand analysis, market integration, tilapia.

JEL Classification Codes C22, Q11, Q17, Q22.

Introduction

Farmed tilapia is currently the third most imported seafood product in the United States of America (USA) after shrimp and Atlantic salmon. Imports have increased from virtually nothing in the early 1990s to 134,869 tonnes in 2005 (NMFS 2006). This growth has been particularly strong in the last four years, when imports have more than doubled. This is mainly due to the increased imports of frozen fillets, the volume of which has risen almost sevenfold from 7,372 tonnes in 2001 to 55,615 tonnes in 2005 (NMFS 2006). The recent increase in tilapia imports suggests that consumers may be substituting at least some of their consumption of other products for tilapia.

Industry commentators have suggested that tilapia is competing with domesti-cally produced catfish in the US market (Harvey 2002; Josupeit 2005). The main reason is that the increase in tilapia imports has coincided with a reduction in the

imports of basa (catfish) from Vietnam during the last few years.1 However, not all

Ana Norman-López is a researcher at CSIRO Marine and Atmospheric Research, 233 Middle Street, Cleve-land 4163, Australia, email: [email protected]. Frank Asche is a professor in the Department of Indus-trial Economics at University of Stavanger, N-4036 Stavanger, Norway, email: [email protected]

Comments from Trond Bjørndal and James P. Innes, as well as funding from the Worldfish Centre and the Norwegian Research Council are gratefully acknowledged. Most of this work was undertaken when Ana Norman-López was with CEMARE, University of Portsmouth.

1 In November 2001, the US senate passed a law prohibiting basa (also known as tra) to be labelled as

(2)

tilapia product forms may be taking market share from domestic catfish. Of the three products imported (fresh and frozen fillets and whole, frozen fish), only the imports of fresh fillets have continued to increase in quantity while maintaining a fairly constant price. Frozen fillets have also experienced a sharp increase in imports, but for this product form prices have declined substantially. Imports of whole, frozen tilapia have remained stable while prices have dropped. The different trends depicted by these three tilapia products suggest they may lie in different market segments.

Tilapia products may also be segmented in the US market because they are im-ported from different countries with varying production technologies, qualities, and transportation costs. In particular, the fresh fillets are mainly shipped from Latin America, while the frozen products are primarily imported from South-East Asia. Freshness and purchase price have been identified by Halbrendt et al. (1995) as the most important attributes determining retailer preferences for tilapia, as well as that of catfish, salmon, and trout. Therefore, differences in the price and quality between producers may affect consumer preferences for the different tilapia products. Conse-quently, it is possible that tilapia has created new market segments, as well as winning market share from a variety of whitefish products, including catfish. Muir and Young (1999) argue that high-quality tilapia may be competing with high-valued species, including snapper and grouper in the US market, while Anderson (2006) suggests that tilapia can be a substitute for flatfish, snapper, and other whitefish.

The purpose of this paper is to investigate the possible competition between fil-lets of imported tilapia and filfil-lets of domestically produced catfish in the US market, as well as competition between the different tilapia product forms. If there is competition, then the extent of the substitutability between these products will be investigated. Whole frozen tilapia is not considered because imports of this product form have remained relatively stable during recent years, while fresh and frozen ti-lapia fillets have accounted for most of the import growth. Moreover, in the USA catfish is primarily marketed as fresh and frozen fillets.

The results will be of interest to exporters of tilapia into the USA and the US seafood industry in general, as the substitutability between these products may offer some insights into the future development of tilapia in the US whitefish market. The implications of strong competition between imported tilapia and domestic catfish could result in actions being taken by the catfish industry in an effort to reduce tila-pia import demand. The catfish industry could target marketing campaigns against tilapia imports. Furthermore, tilapia imports could face higher import tariffs if the domestic catfish industry successfully files an anti-dumping complaint against tila-pia exporters. This has been the experience of Vietnamese basa exporters. Conversely, if there is no competition between these species, then the question re-mains open as to what seafood product(s) tilapia is taking market share from. In addition, actions targeting tilapia would then not benefit US catfish producers.

In the analysis, we use monthly data for the period from January 1997 to Febru-ary 2006. Two main approaches are employed. First, we study the relationship between the prices of fresh and frozen fillets of imported tilapia and US catfish fil-lets. Second, we estimate demand equations for the imports of fresh and frozen tilapia fillets to the US and the wholesale demand for fresh and frozen fillets of do-mestic catfish. During the last decade, testing for market integration has become a common approach for investigating the long-run relationship between products. Nevertheless, demand analysis provides more information on the interactions

be-tween products than tests for market integration.2 Testing for market integration has

2 See Asche, Salvanes, and Steen (1997) and Asche, Bjørndal, and Gordon (2007) for discussions of the

(3)

the advantage that it is less data intensive. This is an issue in this analysis as the data set is relatively short (110 observations) and cannot be extended backwards be-cause of the limited imports of tilapia fillets before 1997. While one would definitely prefer a longer dataset, the results obtained in the demand analysis and market integration tests are complementary.

The paper is organized as follows: In the following section, we discuss the de-mand for tilapia in the US market and investigate the patterns of quantities and prices of imported tilapia fillets and sales of domestic catfish fillets in the US mar-ket. The data used are also presented along with an analysis of their time series properties before we describe the methodology used in the study. This is followed by the presentation of our empirical results before some concluding remarks are made in the final section.

Markets for Tilapia and Catfish in the USA

Catfish and tilapia are popular farmed fish species in the US market, ranking

respec-tively as the fifth and sixth most consumed seafood species in 2005.3 Catfish has

traditionally been a popular product in the USA and is supplied almost entirely by domestic producers. Tilapia, on the other hand, is primarily imported and only en-tered the top 10 most consumed species in 2001, following a strong increase in imports.

Demand for tilapia was originally limited to people of African and Asian origin living in the USA. However, the recent growth in demand implies that this may no longer be the case. Tilapia meets the typical requirements of fish preferred in the US market: its meat is white and can be easily filleted; it is odourless, with a mild flavour; and it is very versatile for cooking (Vannuccini 2001). As a result, tilapia is no longer only supplied to retailers catering to the Asian and African population, as well as restaurants of these ethnic origins, but is also widely available to the general US public in fish markets and supermarkets (Burger et al. 2004).

Tilapia is sold live, fresh, and frozen and in different product forms (whole, gut-ted, gutted and scaled, and fillets). The limited US production is mainly marketed live, as US producers have a geographical advantage over non-domestic producers. Each of the three main product forms imported comes from a wide range of coun-tries. However, the majority of imports are supplied by a small number of councoun-tries. The main exporters of fresh tilapia fillets to the USA are South and Central Ameri-can countries. As shown in the 2005 National Marine Fisheries Service (NMFS) statistics, 92.0% of fresh tilapia fillet imports were from Ecuador, Honduras, and Costa Rica. On the other hand, the main exporters of frozen fillets and whole frozen

tilapia to the USA were South-East Asian countries.4 In 2005, 96.4% of US frozen

tilapia fillet imports were from China, Indonesia and Taiwan.5 For whole, frozen

ti-lapia in 2005, 97.5% of imports were from China and Taiwan.6

3 In 2005, the per capita consumption of catfish was 0.47 kg and that of tilapia was 0.39kg (NFI 2007). 4 Other exporters of fresh tilapia fillets to the USA (in order of market share) were Brazil, El Salvador,

Colombia, Panama, Nicaragua, Jamaica, Peru, Chile, Indonesia, the United Kingdom, and Mexico (NMFS).

5 Other exporters of frozen tilapia fillets to the USA (in order of market share) were Thailand, Vietnam,

Ecuador, Panama, Costa Rica, Hong Kong, Chile, South Korea, Ghana, Nicaragua, Bangladesh, Brazil, and Malaysia (NMFS 2006).

6 Other exporters of whole, frozen tilapia to the USA (in order of market share) were Vietnam, Panama,

Indonesia, Thailand, Ecuador, Hong Kong, Philippines, India, Malaysia, Canada, Costa Rica, Brazil, Ja-pan, and South Korea (NMFS 2006).

(4)

The per capita consumption of catfish in the USA has increased from 0.19 kg in 1985 to 0.47 kg in 2005 (NFI 2007). This is partly due to the introduction of a wide variety of products to satisfy the rapid changes in consumption patterns and con-sumer desire for new food products (Silva and Dean 2001). Another reason is the intensive marketing efforts by the US catfish industry. In particular, The Catfish In-stitute (TCI) has been identified as “the promotional arm of the domestic catfish industry” (Quagrainie 2006). TCI’s marketing campaign is funded by feed mills

within the states producing catfish (Hanson 2001).The funding has increased from

$2 million in 1986 to $3.6 million in 2002. This advertisement was mostly generic, and it was identified to have a positive effect on consumption by several studies (Kinnucan and Venkateswaran 1990; Zidack, Kinnucan, and Hatch 1992; and Kinnucan and Miao 1999). Moreover, individual companies have funded their own marketing campaigns in addition to the generic marketing effort. However, a lack of published literature on the advertising campaigns of individual private companies makes it difficult to account for their impact on catfish consumption.

Unlike tilapia, there is a large literature investigating the market for catfish in the USA. Marketing studies have found catfish consumption to be uneven among different geographical regions, ethnic groups, and educational and income levels (Drammeh et al. 2002; Engle 1998; Kinnucan, Nelson, and Hiariey 1993). Neverthe-less, the introduction of new product forms and marketing practices might affect these consumption patterns over time. For example, early studies indicated a nega-tive relationship between income and catfish consumption (Hu 1985) due to the negative perception that consumers had of catfish (Kinnucan et al. 1988). However, the catfish industry managed to overcome this image problem, resulting in a positive income elasticity of demand (Kinnucan and Miao 1999; Kouka 1995; Zidack, Kinnucan, and Hatch 1992).

Furthermore, price and consumer perceptions regarding nutrition, freshness, safety, appearance, etc.; also affect catfish consumption (Drammeh et al. 2002; Engle 1998; Halbrendt et al. 1995; Kinnucan, Nelson, and Hiariey 1993). In particu-lar, the 2000–01 US survey on farm-raised catfish indicated that consumers rank price as the main factor affecting their consumption of catfish (House et al. 2003).

In figure 1, the rapid increase in tilapia imports since 1997 is compared with the volume of domestically raised catfish sold by processors. Processed US catfish in-cludes the entire range of product forms, although overall sales are mainly driven by changes in the sale of fresh and frozen catfish fillets (Harvey 2001). As shown in figure 1, tilapia imports have increased from a monthly quantity of 1,866 tonnes in January 1997 to 10,390 tonnes in February 2006. During the same period, sales of processed US catfish increased at a much lower rate.

Figure 2 shows the imports of fresh and frozen tilapia fillets and sales of fresh and frozen fillets of domestically processed catfish in tonnes from January 1997 to February 2006. As shown, the sales of fresh and frozen fillets of domestic catfish increased from 1,645 tonnes and 3,738 tonnes in January 1997 to 2,317 tonnes and 5,179 tonnes in February 2006, respectively. This represents almost a doubling of sales over the period considered. However, sales growth for domestic catfish fillets is substantially lower than for tilapia fillets. Imports of fresh and frozen tilapia fil-lets experienced a significant increase throughout the sample period, with the growth of frozen fillets being particularly strong. For instance, fresh fillets of im-ported tilapia increased from 203 tonnes in January 1997 to 1,894 tonnes in February 2006. Over the same period, frozen fillets of tilapia imports increased from 117 tonnes to 4,432 tonnes.

Figure 3 presents the nominal wholesale processor prices of fresh and frozen fil-lets of domestic catfish and the nominal import prices of fresh and frozen tilapia

(5)

Figure 1. Total Sales (tonnes) of Processed US Catfish and Tilapia Imports,

January 1997–February 2006

Sources: USDA (2006) and NMFS (2006).

Figure 2. Total Sales (tonnes) of Fresh and Frozen US Catfish Fillets and Fresh

and Frozen Tilapia Fillets Imports, January 1997–February 2006

(6)

fillets.7 The figures are in $/kg and cover the period from January 1997 to February

2006. In general, the wholesale prices of fresh and frozen domestic catfish fillets follow a similar pattern, increasing from $6.06/kg and $5.80/kg in January 1997 to $6.39/kg and $6.31/kg by June 2000, respectively. After this date, the wholesale prices of fresh and frozen fillets of domestic catfish dropped until early 2003, reach-ing a minimum value of $5.36/kg in March 2003 for fresh fillets and $5.20/kg in December 2002 for frozen fillets. Several factors may have contributed to this de-cline, including increasing imports of basa frozen fillets until the end of the 2001 and the increasing sales of domestic catfish fillets. Since 2003, the wholesale pro-cessor prices of fresh and frozen domestic catfish fillets increased to $6.33/kg and $5.93/kg, respectively, in February 2006.

Figure 3 also shows the import prices of fresh and frozen tilapia fillets. Fresh tilapia fillet prices fluctuate slightly over time but generally follow a declining trend until May 1999, when they reached their lowest value at $4.16/kg. Since that point, import prices have increased along with quantities, indicating an increase in market size. Catfish is a possible substitute, as the prices of fresh tilapia fillets and fresh and frozen catfish fillets have been similar since the end of the year 2000.

The import prices of frozen tilapia fillets show a declining trend from January 1997 to February 2006 as well as a fall in price fluctuation (figure 3). This may be related to the strong increase in imports of this product. For frozen tilapia fillets, the

re-Figure 3. Monthly Wholesale Prices ($/kg) of Fresh and Frozen US Catfish Fillets

and Import Prices of Fresh and Frozen Tilapia Fillets, January 1997–February 2006

Sources: USDA (2006) and NMFS (2006).

(7)

lationship between prices and quantities suggests that a reduction in price is the result of a movement down the demand schedule (figure 2). This indicates that frozen tilapia fillets may compete in a different market from fresh tilapia and catfish fillets.

The data used in the econometric analysis are the monthly import quantities and

prices of fresh and frozen tilapia fillets in the USA.8 The data were obtained from

the foreign trade information provided by NMFS. The monthly volume sold and wholesale processor prices of fresh and frozen domestic catfish fillets were obtained from the catfish processing reports of the USDA’s National Agriculture Statistics Service (USDA 2006). Monthly income is derived from the seasonally unadjusted indices of aggregate weekly payrolls. This variable, together with the historical con-sumer price index for all urban concon-sumers (from 1913 to the present), is from the Bureau of Labor Statistics of the US Department of Labor.

Our original intention was to consider the entire NMFS data set on tilapia fillet imports available at the time of analysis (July 1992 – February 2006). However, un-til the late 1990s, un-tilapia fillet imports were sun-till very small, resulting in strong

fluctuations in monthly import prices.9 Consequently, we restricted the data set to

begin in January 1997 when prices were observed to be more stable.

To study the time-series properties of the data, we tested for unit roots using the

commonly applied Augmented Dickey–Fuller (ADF) test.10 If a data series contains

a unit root (I(1)), it is non-stationary, and unless it combines with another non-sta-tionary series to form a stanon-sta-tionary cointegration relationship, regressions involving this variable will falsely identify the presence of a significant economic relationship. A requirement of the ADF test is that the adequate lag length is set in order to achieve white noise in the error term. We have done this by using the Schwarz infor-mation criteria and autocorrelation tests (LM). ADF tests for each series were performed in levels and first differences with a constant and trend. The null hypoth-esis in the ADF test is that each series is non-stationary (I(1)). Table 1 presents the ADF tests on nominal and real prices, quantities, and real income. The values in brackets represent the chosen number of lags for each ADF test. All data series were found to be non-stationary in levels but stationary in first differences.

Methodology

In this section, we discuss the market integration analysis using non-stationary prices. We then describe the demand model specification.

Testing for Market Integration

Stigler (1969) defined a market as, “the area within which the price of a commodity tends to uniformity, allowance being made for transportation costs.” Other defini-tions of a market apply this concept not to a geographical space but to product space, so quality differences will take the place of transportation costs (Stigler and Sherwin 1985). Following these definitions, prices may deviate from each other in the short run, but in the long run, arbitrage and substitutability will ensure that prices form an equilibrium relationship. Therefore, products will be in the same market when prices hold an equilibrium relationship (that is, they are cointegrated).

8 Prices obtained from import values.

9 The fluctuation is particularly strong for import prices of frozen tilapia fillets. 10 All unit root tests were performed with the econometric software package EViews 5.0.

(8)

A variety of seafood studies have examined the market relationship between differ-ent goods by analysing their prices with tests for cointegration.11

There are two approaches to test for cointegration: the Engle and Granger test (1987) and the Johansen test (Johansen 1988). We use the Johansen test in the mar-ket integration analysis as it allows hypothesis testing (such as the ‘law of one price’).

In our study, we test for market integration between two price series at a time. The Johansen test is based on a vector autoregressive (VAR) system. To start, we set

a vector zt containing two (N) of the price series we are investigating. Then, we

model zt as an unrestricted VAR model with k lags containing these variables in lev-els, where, zt is (n × 1) and each of the Πi is an (n × n) matrix of parameters. The

system is in reduced form with each variable in zt regressed on only lagged values of

both itself and all other variables in the system. In order to use the Johansen test, the VAR representation needs to be turned into a vector error correction model (VECM) of the following form:

Δzt = Γ Δ1 z( – )t 1 + … + Γ Δk–1 z( –t k+1) + Πz( – )t k + μt, (1)

where Γi = –(I – Π1 – … – Πi), (i = 1, …, k–1), and Π = –(I – Π1 – … – Πk). The

Johansen test centres on an examination of the Π matrix. Π is the long-run “level solution” to equation (1), because in equilibrium all the first differences of the price se-ries (Δzt–i) will be zero, and setting the error terms, ut, to their expected value of zero

will leave Πzt–k = 0. Furthermore, Π = αβ′, where α represents the speed of adjustment,

Table 1

Unit Root Tests (Augmented Dickey–Fuller) of Logged Nominal Fillet Prices, Real Prices, Quantities, and Real Income, Jan. 1997–Feb. 2006 (n = 110)

Levels First Differences

Variable Constant Trend Constant Trend

Tilapia, fresh fillets, nominal prices –1.599 (1) –2.770 (1) –11.627* (0) –11.568* (0)

Tilapia, frozen fillets, nominal prices –1.905 (2) –3.278 (3) –13.232* (1) –13.148* (1)

Catfish, fresh fillets, nominal prices –1.591 (0) –1.423 (0) –12.544* (0) –12.574* (0)

Catfish, frozen fillets, nominal prices –1.988 (1) –1.835 (1) –6.018* (0) –6.031* (0)

Tilapia, fresh fillets, real prices –2.429 (1) –2.833 (1) –11.742* (0) –11.683* (0)

Tilapia, frozen fillets, real prices –0.920 (2) –3.101 (3) –13.405* (1) –13.318* (1)

Catfish, fresh fillets, real prices –0.852 (1) –1.844 (0) –12.875* (0) –12.831* (0)

Catfish, frozen fillets, real prices –0.958 (1) –1.804 (1) –6.755* (0) –6.722* (0)

Tilapia, fresh fillets, quantity –1.167 (1) –2.734 (1) –15.512* (0) –7.425* (10)

Tilapia, frozen fillets, quantity –0.372 (2) –3.376 (2) –10.636* (1) –10.592* (1)

Catfish, fresh fillets, quantity –2.099 (12) –0.478 (12) –3.470**(11) –4.249* (11)

Catfish, frozen fillets, quantity –2.593 (4) –3.208 (4) –4.100* (11) –4.191* (11)

Real income –0.223 (12) –3.430 (2) –12.144* (0) –12.306* (0)

The values in parentheses indicate the number of lags. Prices are in $/kg, quantities are in kg and real income in $.

* indicates significance at the 1% level; **indicates significance at the 5% level.

11 Applications to seafood data include Gordon and Hannesson (1996); Jaffry et al. (2000); Asche,

(9)

while β is a matrix of long-run coefficients. Both α and β are (N × r) matrices. There are two asymptotically equivalent tests for cointegration in the Johansen framework: the likelihood ratio test and the trace test. The test for cointegration be-tween the zs is calculated by looking at the rank of the Π matrix via its Eigen values. The rank of Π, r, determines how many linear combinations of zt are stationary. If r = N, the variables in levels are stationary. If r = 0, none of the linear combinations is stationary (Π = 0). When 0 < r < N, there exist r linear stationary combinations of zt, or r cointegration vectors. In this instance, we need to determine how many r ≤ (n– 1) cointegration vectors exist in β. If the series are cointegrated, we further investigate whether the two price series are imperfect substitutes or whether they are perfect substitutes (LOP), so their relative price is constant. We test for the LOP by imposing the restriction β′ = (1, –1)′.

Demand Analysis

Demand analysis is the most common approach used to estimate demand character-istics, including the degree of substitution. This includes the potential substitution between imports of tilapia fillets and domestic catfish fillets. Consumer theory indi-cates that the quantity demanded of any product is a function of its own-price, the prices of substitutes, and income. Demand analysis also allows us to derive cross-price elasticities empirically; these indicate the extent to which commodities compete in the same market. Demand models are generally estimated using tradi-tional econometric tools, such as ordinary least squares (OLS). However, there is a problem when the data are non-stationary and there is no long-run relationship be-tween the variables, as this will lead to spurious regressions. On the other hand, if cointegration exists between the series, OLS will achieve a consistent estimate of the long-run, steady-state relationship between the variables in the model, and all dynamics and endogeneity issues can be ignored asymptotically.

We estimate four double-log, static demand models for the import of fresh and frozen tilapia fillets and sales of fresh and frozen domestic catfish fillets. In these models, fresh tilapia fillets are assumed to compete with fresh catfish fillets in the same market and vice versa. Frozen tilapia fillets compete with frozen catfish fillets in the same manner. The specification of each model is as follows:

lnqit = αi + λln pit + ωlnpjt + elnXt + εt, (2)

where qit is the quantity consumed of good i, αi is a constant, pit is the real price of

good i, pjt is the real price of good j, and Xt is the consumer’s real income, all at time

t. λ represents the own-price elasticity, ω represents the cross-price elasticity, e

rep-resents the expenditure elasticity, and εt is the error term. We also assume that there

are deterministic trends and seasonal variation in demand. This is captured by intro-ducing trend and dummy variables in the demand equations as appropriate.

To determine whether the static models consistently estimate the long-run rela-tionship between the variables, we investigate the time-series properties of the error terms, εt. If the series in each regression are cointegrated, εt will be stationary (I(0)),

otherwise non-stationary (I(1)). When testing the residuals from the demand equa-tions for stationarity, we use the critical values from MacKinnon (1991).

(10)

Empirical Analysis

Market Integration

To determine whether fresh and frozen fillets of imported tilapia and domestic cat-fish are competing within the same market, we perform bivariate Johansen cointegration tests (Johansen 1988) between the four price series of interest (table 2).12 All of the pairwise tests, with the exception of the test for fresh and frozen

cat-fish fillets, fail to reject the null hypothesis of no cointegration vector with rank = 0 at the 5% level. The test for fresh and frozen catfish fillets rejects the null hypoth-esis of cointegration vector with rank = 0 at the 5% level. However, the hypothhypoth-esis that there are two cointegrating vectors is rejected.

Hence, the main results from the market integration tests are as follows. First, the US wholesale processor prices of fresh and frozen catfish fillets form a long-run relationship during the period under consideration. Thus, fresh and frozen fillets of domestic catfish compete within the same market. Second, the import prices of fresh and frozen tilapia fillets do not form a long-run relationship. This result comes as no surprise because frozen fillets are mainly supplied by South-East Asian countries, while fresh fillets are mainly imported from South and Central American producers. Third, domestic catfish fillets and imported tilapia fillets are not within the same market. Hence, imported tilapia fillets cannot be taking market share from domestic catfish fillets, as they do not lie in the same market. That is, catfish and tilapia are regarded as unrelated products.

Given that the prices for fresh and frozen catfish fillets were found to be related, we have also tested whether the LOP holds in this relationship. As shown in the last column of table 2, the LOP was rejected for this relationship, with a test statistic of 10.967. Hence, we conclude that the market for catfish fillets is not fully integrated.

Demand Analysis

Tables 3 and 4 present the parameter estimates and summary statistics for the de-mand equations. The long-run own-price, cross-price, and income elasticities estimated from the demand models are reported in the first panel of each table. The second panels in tables 3 and 4 indicate the significance of the constant and joint significance of the seasonal dummies specified in every model. In all equations, the seasonal dummies are significant, indicating seasonal variation in demand. A trend has also been included in the demand model for frozen tilapia fillets, and the results indicate it is significant in this model. As our data series are non-stationary in levels (table 1), we confirm that the data series in each of the demand equations form a long-run relationship. This is done by testing whether the series are cointegrated through the first step of the Engle–Granger test. The results from these tests are re-ported in the last row of tables 3 and 4. The results indicate that the data series in all demand equations appear to be cointegrated. Furthermore, the four equations have

high R2 values; this also supports the hypothesis of cointegration in all equations.

Reset tests also suggest no misspecification in any of the models. However, the test for error autocorrelation for lags 1 to 12 is rejected for fresh fillets of imported

tila-12 The Johansen cointegration framework was performed with the econometric software package EViews

5.0. The software allows the cointegration tests to be made using five different trend assumptions. We chose to have no intercept or trend in the cointegration test or VAR model following the Schwarz and Akaike information criteria.

(11)

Table 3

Long-Run Parameter Estimates (Elasticities), Jan. 1997–Feb. 2006 (n = 110) Equation

Fresh Tilapia Frozen Tilapia

Variable Coefficient Standard Error Coefficient Standard Error

Tilapia, fresh price –0.711* 0.249

Tilapia, frozen price – – –0.689** 0.296

Catfish, fresh price –0.237 0.506 – –

Catfish, frozen price – – 0.072 1.024

Income 0.157 0.691 0.564 2.052 Constant 15.068 [0.000]* 1.360 [0.246] Trend – 14.663 [0.000]* Seasonals 46.610 [0.000]* 4.075 [0.000]* R2 0.986 0.966 RESET Test 0.0123 [0.912] 2.784 [0.099]

Error autocorrelation 1–12 lags

F-Test 2.440 [0.009]* 1.072 [0.394]

Cointegration Testa –10.567* –8.330*

* indicates significance at the 1% level; **indicates significance at the 5% level.

a Critical values for the cointegration tests are –3.8199 at the 5% level and –4.4273 at the 1% level

(MacKinnon 1991).

Table 2

Bivariate Johansen Tests for Cointegration, Jan. 1997–Feb. 2006 (n = 110) Law of

Null Hypothesesa One Price

Rank (ρ) = 0 Rank (ρ) ≤ 1

Nominal Prices Maxb Tracec Maxb Tracec

Tilapia (fresh)/Tilapia (frozen) 5.040 5.099 0.059 0.059 –

Tilapia (fresh)/Catfish (fresh) 3.580 3.602 0.023 0.023 –

Tilapia (fresh)/Catfish (frozen) 6.173 6.184 0.011 0.011 –

Tilapia (frozen)/Catfish (fresh) 3.410 3.734 0.325 0.325 –

Tilapia (frozen)/Catfish (frozen) 3.233 3.318 0.085 0.085 –

Catfish (fresh)/Catfish (frozen) 12.442** 12.467** 0.024 0.024 10.967*

Results from Schwarz and Akaike Information Criteria.

a The null hypothesis is that the number of cointegrating vectors is equal to ρ. b Maximum eigenvalue test.

c Trace test.

(12)

pia and domestic catfish at the 1% level. This is not, however, a serious problem be-cause ordinary inference theory does not apply with nonstationary data (Engle and

Granger 1987).13

The own-price elasticities of fresh and frozen tilapia fillets (table 3) and frozen fillets of domestic catfish (table 4) are –0.711, –0.689, and –0.773, respectively. These values indicate inelastic demand for these products, although they are close to unit elasticity. The own-price elasticity of demand for fresh fillets of domestic cat-fish (table 4) is –1.029; this indicates unit elastic demand for this product. The results for catfish fillets are consistent with previous findings that provide an own-price elasticity between –0.706 (Kinnucan and Miao 1999) and –1.17 (Kouka 1995).

The income elasticities of demand for fresh and frozen imported tilapia fillets and frozen domestic catfish fillets are 0.157, 0.564, and 0.540, respectively (tables 3 and 4). These positive, yet inelastic, income values indicate that consumers regard these products as normal goods. On the other hand, the income elasticity of fresh domestic catfish fillets is positive and highly elastic (2.015). This indicates that con-sumers regard fresh domestic catfish fillets as a luxury good. The variation in income elasticities between fresh and frozen domestic catfish fillets is of no great surprise, as previous studies have reported income elasticities ranging between 0.378 (Zidack, Kinnucan, and Hatch 1992) and 2.226 (Kouka 1995). The coeffi-cients of the cross-price elasticities of demand in the four models (tables 3 and 4) are close to zero and insignificant (again, if ordinary inference theory applies), and

Table 4

Long-Run Parameter Estimates (Elasticities), Jan. 1997–Feb. 2006 (n = 110) Equation

Fresh Catfish Frozen Catfish

Variable Coefficient Standard Error Coefficient Standard Error

Catfish, fresh price –1.029* 0.137

Catfish, frozen price – – –0.773* 0.083

Tilapia, fresh price –0.005 0.101 – –

Tilapia, frozen price – – 0.089 0.047

Income 2.015* 0.421 0.540** 0.258 Constant 21.304 [0.000]* 155.438 [0.000]* Trend – – Seasonals 26.593 [0.000]* 18.411 [0.000]* R2 0.870 0.791 RESET Test 0.044 [0.835] 0.001 [0.979]

Error autocorrelation 1–12 lags

F-Test 3.130 [0.001]* 1.073 [0.394]

Cointegration Testa –6.267* –7.881*

* indicates significance at the1% level; **indicates significance at the 5% level.

a Critical values for the cointegration tests are –3.8199 at the 5% level and –4.4273 at the 1% level

(MacKinnon 1991).

13 Note that the conclusions do not change if heteroskedastic and autocorrelation (HAC) consistent

(13)

two of the relationships actually suggest complementarities. These findings imply that the demand for fresh and frozen imported tilapia is independent of the demand for fresh and frozen domestic catfish. This corroborates the findings from the market integration analysis. Hence, the demand analysis provides essentially the same re-sults as the market integration analysis with respect to the competition between tilapia and catfish—they are not substitutes in consumption.

Concluding Remarks

The purpose of this article is to investigate whether imports of fresh and frozen fil-lets of tilapia and fresh and frozen filfil-lets of domestic catfish compete in the same market. Industry commentators have suggested this is a possibility following the surge in tilapia imports over the last few years (Harvey 2004; Josupeit 2005). Our results are of interest, as they provide some insights into the future development of tilapia in the US market.

The rapid increase in imports certainly suggests that tilapia may be taking mar-ket share from other seafood products. If tilapia win marmar-ket share from catfish, then the US catfish industry may experience negative pressure on prices, as this market is already considered to be saturated (O’Dierno, White, and Garfield 2003). This situa-tion could cause the US catfish industry to target tilapia in a similar manner as it did with imports of Vietnamese basa. In 2000–2001, the US catfish industry favoured a ‘brand’ campaign over a generic campaign (Kinnucan et al. 2003). This new cam-paign emphasized that domestically raised catfish were of US origin and of a higher quality than the imported Vietnamese basa (catfish) frozen fillets. The change of fo-cus occurred following growing imports of Vietnamese basa through the year 2000 and the belief that this was leading to a decline in the prices of domestic catfish. Furthermore, the US Department of Commerce ruled to raise tariffs for this product in January 2003. This ruling followed from an anti-dumping complaint by the Cat-fish Farmers Association that led to Vietnamese exporters being found guilty of dumping frozen fillets of basa in the US market and consequently forcing the prices of domestically produced catfish down (Harvey 2004).

Our results indicate that fresh and frozen catfish fillets are within the same mar-ket; as such, there is a single market for catfish in the USA. Hence, a potential competing product will influence demand for both product forms of catfish. The re-sults also indicate that the markets for fresh and frozen tilapia fillets are separate. Hence, at most one of the tilapia product forms can compete in the catfish market. However, when tested, the results indicate that none of the tilapia product forms compete with catfish.

These results have important implications for the future development of tilapia in the USA. While the declining price of frozen tilapia fillets suggests a movement along the demand schedule, the stable price of fresh tilapia fillets suggests that this product form is winning market share from an established market, although not the market for catfish. Finally, since tilapia does not compete with catfish, targeting marketing campaigns or filing anti-dumping suits against tilapia would not benefit US catfish producers.

Our results with respect to the lack of competition between tilapia and catfish may be regarded as surprising given the opinion of several industry commentators. For instance, Harvey (2002) and Josupeit (2005) suggested tilapia has increased its market share by filling the gap left as a result of declining Vietnamese basa imports. However, the small decline in the volume of Vietnamese basa imports relative to the

(14)

large increase in tilapia imports supports our conclusion that there must be other factors influencing the increase in tilapia imports.14

Another explanation for the increase in market share of tilapia is the decline in wild fishery landings. In particular, Muir and Young (1999) and Anderson (2006) have suggested wild flatfish, snapper, and grouper are other seafood products that tilapia may be competing with. Determining whether or not this is the case will be an important topic for future research. Alternatively, it is also possible the demand growth for tilapia is similar to that observed by Asche, Bjørndal, and Young (2001) with salmon. Their findings indicated that while salmon was winning market share from a large number of other food products, it was taking so little from each indi-vidual market that it was difficult to measure the impact.

References

Anderson, J.L. 2006. The Seafood Industry: 2020. International Boston Seafood

Show. Boston, MA. March 12–14. http://seafoodreport.com/uploaded_docs/

Boston_2006_JLA.pdf

Asche, F., T. Bjørndal, and D. V. Gordon. 2007. Studies in the Demand Structure for Fish and Seafood Products. Handbook of Operations Research in Natural Re-sources, A. Weintraub, C. Romero, T. Bjørndal and R. Epstein, eds., pp. 295–314. Amsterdam: Kluwer.

Asche, F., T. Bjørndal, and J.A. Young. 2001. Market Interactions for Aquaculture Products. Aquaculture Economics and Management 5:303–18.

Asche, F., D.V. Gordon, and R. Hannesson. 2004. Tests for Market Integration and the Law of One Price: The Market for Whitefish in France. Marine Resource

Economics 19:195–210.

Asche, F., K.G. Salvanes, and F. Steen. 1997. Market Delineation and Demand Structure. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 79:139–50.

Burger, J., A. Stern, C. Dixon, C. Jeitner, S. Shukla, S. Burke, and M. Gochfeld. 2004. Fish Availability in Supermarket and Fish Markets in New Jersey. Science

of the Total Environment 333:89–97.

Drammeh, L., L. House, S. Sureshwaran, and H. Selassie. 2002. Analysis of Factors

Influencing the Frequency of Catfish Consumption in the United States.

Se-lected Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Agricultural Economics Association, Long Beach, CA, July 28–31.

Engle, C.R. 1998. Analysis of Regional and National Markets for Aquacultural Food

Products in the Southern Region. SRAC Final Report No. 601.

Engle, R.F., and C.W.J. Granger. 1987. Co-integration and Error Correction: Repre-sentation, Estimation and Testing. Econometrica 55:251–76.

Gordon, D.V., and R. Hannesson. 1996. On Prices of Fresh and Frozen Cod. Marine

Resource Economics 11:223–38.

Halbrendt, C., Q. Wang, C. Fraiz, and L. O’Dierno. 1995. Marketing Problems and Opportunities in Mid-Atlantic Seafood Retailing. American Journal of

Agricul-tural Economics 77(December):1313–18.

Hanson, T. 2001. Marketing Strategies of The Catfish Institute, 1985-2001. Research Report, Department of Agricultural Economics, Mississippi State University, Mississippi State, MS.

14 Following import data from the NMFS, total Vietnamese basa imports declined from 7,765 tonnes in

2001 to 1,929 tonnes in 2003. After 2003, total Vietnamese basa imports increased to 8,623 tonnes in 2005. On the other hand, total tilapia imports have increased year on year from 56,337 tonnes in 2001, to 90,246 tonnes in 2003, to 134,869 tonnes in 2005 (NMFS 2006).

(15)

Harvey, D.J. 2001. Aquaculture Outlook: Imports Provide Competition for Domestic

Production. October 10, 2001, LPD-AQS-14. Retrieved August 26, 2006, from

US Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service website: www.ers.usda.gov

_ . 2002. Aquaculture Outlook: In 2002, Aquaculture Volumes Higher, but Prices

Depressed. October 10, 2002, LPD-AQS-16. Retrieved August 26, 2006, from

US Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service website: www.ers.usda.gov

_ . 2004. Aquaculture Outlook: Seafood Falling as Portion of Overall Livestock

Consumption. October 8, 2004, LPD-AQS-20. Retrieved August 26, 2006, from

US Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service website: www.ers.usda.gov

House, L., T. Hanson, S. Sureshwaran, and H. Selassie. 2003. Opinions of U.S.

Con-sumers About Farm-Raised Catfish: Results of a 2000–2001 Survey. Bulletin

1134. July 2003. Experiment Station. Mississippi Agricultural & Forestry Ex-periment Station.

Hu, T. 1985. Analysis of Seafood Consumption in the US.: 1970, 1978, 1981. Insti-tute for Policy Research and Evaluation, Pennsylvania State University.

Jaffry, S.A., S. Pascoe, G. Taylor, and U. Zabala. 2000. Price Interactions Between Salmon and Wild Caught Species on the Spanish Market. Aquaculture

Econom-ics and Management 4:157–67.

Johansen, S. 1988. Statistical Analysis of Cointegration Vectors. Journal of

Eco-nomic Dynamics and Control 12:231–54.

Josupeit, H. 2005. Tilapia Market Report—Tilapia Imports Soar in the US Market. April. Globefish, FAO. www.globefish.org

Kinnucan, H.W., F. Asche, Ø. Myrland, and C.A. Roheim. 2003. Advances in Eco-nomics of Marketing and Implications for Aquaculture Development.

Aquaculture Economics and Management 7(1/2):35–53.

Kinnucan, H.W., and Y. Miao. 1999. Media-specific Returns to Generic Advertising: The Case of Catfish. Agribusiness 15(1):81–99.

Kinnucan, H.W., R.G. Nelson, and J. Hiariey. 1993. U.S. Preferences for Fish and Seafood: An Evoked Set Analysis. Marine Resource Economics 8:273–91. Kinnucan, H.W., S. Sindelar, D. Wineholt, and U. Hatch. 1988. Processor Demand

and Price-mark-up Functions for Catfish: A Disaggregated Analysis with Impli-cations to the Off-flavor Problem. Southern Journal of Agricultural Economics 20:81–92.

Kinnucan, H.W., and M. Venkateswaran. 1990. Effects of Generic Advertising on Perceptions and Behaviour: The Case of Catfish. Southern Journal of

Agricul-tural Economics 22:137–51.

Kouka, P.-J. 1995. An Empirical Model of Pricing in the Catfish Industry. Marine

Resource Economics 10:161–69.

MacKinnon, J.G. 1991. Critical Values for Co-Integration Tests. Long-Run

Eco-nomic Relationships, R.F. Engle and C.W.J. Granger, eds., pp. 267–76. Oxford:

Oxford University Press.

Muir, J.F., and J.A. Young. 1999. Strategic Issues in New Species Development for Aquaculture. Elsevier Biofutures Series. XXXIII International Symposium on

New Species for Mediterranean Aquaculture 85–96. Amsterdam: Elsevier.

National Fisheries Institute (NFI). 2007. US Consumption of Seafood. Information from National Fisheries Institute website: www.aboutseafood.com/media/ top_10.cfm

National Marine Fisheries Service (NMFS). 2006. Fisheries Statistics Division, For-eign Trade Information from National Marine Fisheries Service website: www.st.nmfs.noaa.gov/st1/trade/build_a_database/TradeSelectIndex.html

(16)

Nielsen, M. 2005. Price Formation and Market Integration on the European First-hand Market for Whitefish. Marine Resource Economics 20:185–202.

Nielsen, M., J. Setälä, J. Laitinen, K. Saarni, J. Virtanen and A. Honkanen. 2007. Market Integration for Farmed Trout in Germany. Marine Resource

Econom-ics 22(2):195-213.

O’Dierno, L., D.S. White, and S. Garfield. 2003. Aquaculture Marketing Analysis

and Opportunities in the Northeast Region. Northeast Regional Aquaculture

Center (NRAC) Publication No. 03-003.

Quagrainie, K.K. 2006. Analysis of U.S. Catfish Fillet Market Share Using a Flex-ible Logistic Model. Marine Resource Economics 21:33–45.

Silva, J.L., and S. Dean. 2001. Processed Catfish: Product Forms, Packaging, Yields

and Product Mix. Southern Regional Aquaculture Center (SRAC) Fact Sheet

No. 184.

Stigler, G.J. 1969. The Theory of Price. London: Macmillan.

Stigler, G.J., and R.A. Sherwin. 1985. The Extent of a Market. Journal of Law and

Economics 28:555–85.

U.S. Department of Agriculture (USDA). 2006. Catfish Processing Reports. Infor-mation from USDA’s National Agricultural Statistics Service website: http:// usda.mannlib.cornell.edu/MannUsda/viewDocumentInfo.do?documentID=1015 Vannuccini, S. 2001. Global Markets for Tilapia. INFOFISH International 6:16–20. Zidack, W., H.W. Kinnucan, and U. Hatch. 1992. Wholesale- and Farm-level

Im-pacts of Generic Advertising: The Case of Catfish. Applied Economics 24:959–68.

References

Related documents

controls, pointing to de ficits in the regulation of negative emotions. Pa- tients with lower control of disgust feelings displayed worse function- ing in everyday life, had

This article is available at DigitalCommons@ILR: https://digitalcommons.ilr.cornell.edu/articles/1305.. Union Attitudes Toward Management Cooperation Lee Dyer Cornell University

of the Los Angeles Municipal Code, and after compliance with the Order, a subsequent Order to Comply is issued for violation of the same provisions occuring within one year of

If the parent is not signed, or the zone has other reasons to provide its DNSKEY RR as a trust anchor, then a secure channel needs to be used to publish the keys, and keep

The objectives of present study were to establish egg Se toxicity thresholds for mortality and deformities in early life stages of zebrafish after exposure to excess SeMet via in ovo

Tilapia: Commercially important tilapia, Different culture systems, Means of intensifying tilapia culture, polyculture of tilapia, Water quality management in tilapia

  Effectively identifying requirements   Creating realistic project schedule   Forming the relevant team... Example: SharePoint

The coefficient for the variance of adjusted spread across all the regression models and estimation techniques is statistically significant the 1% level and