LandUsePolicy42(2015)381–391
ContentslistsavailableatScienceDirect
Land
Use
Policy
jou rn al h om ep a g e :w w w . e l s e v i e r . c o m / l o c a t e / l a n d u s e p o l
Bus
stop,
property
price
and
land
value
tax:
A
multilevel
hedonic
analysis
with
quantile
calibration
Yiming
Wang
a,∗,
Dimitris
Potoglou
b,c,
Scott
Orford
b,
Yi
Gong
daTheBartlettSchoolofConstructionandProjectManagement,TheBartlettFacultyofBuiltEnvironment,UniversityCollegeLondon,LondonWC1E7HB,UK bSchoolofPlanningandGeography,CardiffUniversity,KingEdwardVIIAvenue,CardiffCF103WA,UK
cRANDEurope,WestbrookCentre,MiltonRoad,CambridgeCB41YG,UK
dSustainablePlacesResearchInstitute,CardiffUniversity,33ParkPlace,CardiffCF103BA,UK
a
r
t
i
c
l
e
i
n
f
o
Articlehistory:Received20October2013
Receivedinrevisedform30May2014
Accepted26July2014
Keywords:
Landvaluetax Transportinfrastructure Busstop
Propertyprice
a
b
s
t
r
a
c
t
Basedonamultilevelandquantilehedonicanalysisregardingthelocalpublicbussystemandtheprices ofresidentialpropertiesinCardiff,Wales,wefindstrongevidencetosupporttworesearchhypotheses: (a)thenumberofbusstopswithinwalkingdistance(300–1500m)toapropertyispositivelyassociated withtheproperty’sobservedsaleprice,and(b)propertiesofhighermarketprices,comparedwiththeir cheapercounterparts,tendtobenefitmorefromspatialproximitytothebusstoplocations.Giventhese statisticalfindings,wearguethat,landvaluetax(LVT),albeitaclassicpoliticalideadatingbacktotheearly 20thcentury,doeshavecontemporaryrelevanceand,withmoderngeographicinformationtechnologies, canberigorouslyanalysedandempiricallyjustifiedwithaviewtoactualimplementation.LevyingLVT willnotonlygenerateadditionalfiscalrevenuestohelpfinancethedevelopmentandmaintenanceof localpublicinfrastructures,butwillalsoensureamorejustdistributionoftheeconomicwelfareyielded bypublicinvestment.
©2014TheAuthors.PublishedbyElsevierLtd.ThisisanopenaccessarticleundertheCCBYlicense (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/3.0/).
Introduction
Inrecentyears,theUnitedKingdom(UK)haswitnessedarevival ofpublicinterestsinlandvaluetax(LVT).1 Theoriginalideaof
LVTdatesbacktoGeorge(1879),anAmericanpoliticaleconomist, who,partlyinspiredbySmith(1863),positsthatthevalueofland, ultimately,comesfromtheadjacentinfrastructuresandamenities investedbythewholecommunity.Incrementsinlandvaluedue topublicinvestment,thus,oughttobere-capturedthroughLVT. TheearliestpoliticalattemptstolegislateLVTtookplaceinthelate EdwardianBritain(Short,1997,Chapter2).LVTwasofficially pro-posedinthe1909financebill(alsoknownas“People’sBudget”), whenDavidLloydGeorgeservedasChancelloroftheExchequer asamember ofthegoverningLiberalparty.However,thethen Conservatives-dominatedHouseofLords,thoughpassingthe gen-eralbudgetin1910,managedtovetotheLVTproposal.Asimilar storyhappenedlaterwiththe1931FinanceAct,whichcontained
∗Correspondingauthor.+4402076791890.
E-mailaddress:[email protected](Y.Wang).
1FortheexamplesofLabour’sLandValueCampaign(http://www.labourland.
org/)andtheLiberalDemocraticParty’sActionforLandTaxationandEconomic
Reform(http://libdemsalter.org.uk/).
aLVTinitiativepassedbytherulingLabourpartybutwasrejected againbytheTorygovernmentin1934(Wenzer,2000).Oneofthe latesteffortstoseeklegislationofLVTwasin2012byCarolynLucas, aGreenpartymemberoftheUKparliament(TheUKParliament,
2012).
AlthoughLVTwasneverimplementedinBritain,itstracescan beobservedinmanyotherplacesaroundtheworld,suchasinthe citiesofPittsburghandHarrisburgintheAmericanStateof Penn-sylvaniaandanumber ofcountriessuchasAustralia, Denmark, Estonia,Russia,andNewZealand(Andelson,2000;Bourassa,1990;
Dye and England, 2010; Wyatt, 1994). While the actual policy
practice varies among these international cases, LVT has been increasingly justified as a way to financethe construction and maintenanceofpublictransportinfrastructures.Thebasicrationale remainsquitethesameasperGeorgeoriginal(1879),thatpublicly investedtransportnetworkcanpromotethevaluesofnearby pri-vatelyownedlandplots,giventheirimprovedaccessibility.From apoliticaleconomyperspective,thispartofaddedlandvalue,if substantiated,becomesakindofpositiveexternalitieswhichcan beoffsetorcapturedthroughLVT.Otherwise,generaltaxpayers (whogenerategovernmentrevenues)areessentiallysubsidising landownerswho“quietly”extractthevalues ofpublictransport infrastructures.Makingthis free-rideproblemevenmore press-ingistheundersupplyandunderfundingofpublictransportinthe
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.landusepol.2014.07.017
present-dayUK,whichhasresultedinaseriesofsocialexclusion issues,facedtypicallybythelowerincomepopulationwhohave difficultiesaffordingprivatetransport(Lucas,2006).
In this paper,we explore theviabilityof levyingland value taxtofinancethemaintenanceanddevelopmentoflocalpublic transportinfrastructureswithinacontemporaryUKcontext.Our empiricalstudyfocusesonthepublicbussystemownedbyCardiff citycouncilinsouthWales,whichsawa
£
0.6millionfundingcut inthefinancialyearof2012,leadingtoasecondincreaseinbus faressinceOctober2011(WalesOnline,2012).Employinga con-ventionalordinaryleastsquare(OLS)hedonicregressionapproach, wefirstlyexaminetherelationsbetweenthesalepricesofcirca 10,000residentialpropertiesacross12electoralwardsincentral Cardiff from2000to 2009(see Fig.2), and thenumber of bus stopswithintheradiiof300m,400m,500m,750m,1000mand 1500mofeachproperty,basedonthe2007NationalPublic Trans-portAccessNodes(NaPTAN)dataset(DepartmentforTransport, 2007).WethenfurtherrefinetheOLSresults,respectively,withina multilevelmodelling(JonesandBullen,1994)andquantile regres-sionframework(Koenker,2005).Ourmultilevelanalysissuggests theOLSestimatestobeunbiasedwithrespecttotheinfluenceof busstoplocationsontheimplicitlandvaluesofnearbyproperties. Likewise,ourquantilebivariateposthoctestsconfirmthe over-allrobustnessoftheOLSoutcomes.Apolicyimplicationofthese statisticalfindingsistoexerciseatwo-tierprogressivelocalland valuetaxationschemeinhelpingCardiffcouncilfinancethelocal bussystem.Our estimation, basedonthe numberof bus stops withina 1500mradiusofeveryindividualpropertyincludedin oursampledata,suggeststhat,forapropertypricedbelowcirca£
195,000,everyadditionalbusstopcontributestoacirca0.11% marginalincreaseinpropertypricethroughlandvaluebetterment. Thecorrespondingfigureis0.22%forapropertyinthesecondtier withamarketpriceabove£
195,000.Theremainderofthispaperisorganisedasfollows.Thenext section“Landvaluetax:fromEdwardiantocontemporaryBritain” reviewstheliteratureonlandvaluetaxandtherelatedplanning practices,mainlywithinaUKcontext.Thisisfollowedbythedesign ofthisresearchin“Researchdesign”section,whichstudiesthecase ofCardiffBus,byfollowinganOLSandmultilevelhedonic regres-sionapproachsupplementedbyaquantilecalibration.Thedataand modelresultsarereportedinsections“ThecaseofCardiffbus”and “Modelresults”,respectively,beforethestudy’spolicyimplications arediscussedin“Policyimplications”section.Theconclusionsare summarisedin“Conclusionandfutureresearch”section,alongside thedirectionsoffutureresearch.
Landvaluetax:fromEdwardiantocontemporaryBritain
TheEdwardians
Thelatestglobaleconomicrecessionhasforcedmanycountries tocutpublicspending.ThisisparticularlythecaseintheUK,with thecoalitiongovernmentaimingtoreducepublicexpenditureby asmuchas
£
6.2 billionbetween2010and 2011(HerMajesty’s Treasury,2010).Sincebudgetarystringencycontinuedinto2012 and2013,publicfinancehasbecomeatopchallengeconfronting theWestminsterparliament,whichisseekingnewsourcesoftax income,forexample,byproposingafurtherriseinvalue-added consumptiontax(VAT)from20%to25%(TheTelegraph,2012).Acenturyago,theEdwardianpoliticiansweresimilarlyfaced withapublicfinancechallengetofundtheemergingwelfarestate programmes,includinganembryonicpensionscheme(Hattersley, 2004).DavidLloydGeorge,duringhisChancellorshipofthe Exche-quer as a member of thegoverning Liberal party, proposedto tax on tobaccos, luxurious goods, and most important of all,
land,inthe1909financebill.Thesetaxationmeasureswerenot
only intended to balance the government budget, but also to
tackle widespread political and economic inequalities faced by theBritish society. Given its populist flavour, the 1909budget wasoftencalledPeople’sBudget(Short,1997).However,thethen Conservatives-dominatedHouseofLords,thoughreluctantly pass-ingmanyinitiativesincludedinPeople’sBudgetoneyearlaterin 1910,managedtovetothelandvaluetax(LVT)proposal.
TheoriginalideaofLVTactuallycamefromtheothersideofthe Atlantic.George(1879),anAmericanpoliticaleconomistbornin Philadelphia,Pennsylvania,oncewrote:
“Thetaxuponlandvaluesis,therefore,themostjustandequal ofalltaxes.Itfallsonlyuponthosewhoreceivefromsocietya peculiarandvaluablebenefit,andupontheminproportionto thebenefittheyreceive.Itisthetakingbythecommunity,for theuseofthecommunity,ofthatvaluewhichisthecreationof thecommunity.”(George,1879,Chapter33)
George’scentraltenetisthatthevalueofland,ultimately,comes fromtheadjacentinfrastructuresandamenitiesinvestedbythe localcommunity.Incrementsinlandvalueduetopublic invest-mentthereforeoughttobere-capturedthroughLVT.Thisargument resonateswiththegroundrenttheoriesbySmith(1863),Ricardo
(1891),andevenMarx(1867).Thetaxonlandvaluecanalsobe
consideredakindofPigovian(1920)tax,ifoneseestheaddedland valueaccruingfromthepositiveexternalitiesyieldedby commu-nityinvestment(Petrella,1988).
TheContemporaries
ThePigovianaspectofLVTisperhapsbestfeaturedinits
con-temporarypractice, asLVT has beenmore and more exercised
as a way to support the financing of public transport infras-tructures (Ryan, 1999; Rybeck, 2004;Smith and Gihring,2006;
Al-Mosaindetal.,1993;BollingerandIhlanfeldt,1997;Bowesand
Ihlanfeldt,2001;Debrezionetal.,2007,2011;HessandAlmeida,
2007).Underpinningthispolicypracticeisatheoretical conjec-ture that publicly invested transport facilities adds significant values to the nearbyprivately owned land plots by improving theirspatialaccessibilitiestothetransportnetwork.Thiskindof public-investment-triggeredprivatelandvaluebettermentisa typ-icalinstanceofpositiveexternalitiesthatcouldbeoffsetthrough propergovernmentintervention(Pigou,1920).
Nonetheless, land value taxation remains unimplemented
withintheUK,eventhoughsomecloselyassociatedfiscal interven-tionsdoexistintheBritishtownplanningpractice.Forexample, section(106)ofthe1990TownandCountryPlanningActallows local planning authorities to charge developers, on a case-by-case basis and often by negotiation, a so-called section (106) paymenttocompensate for thepotentialnegative externalities (e.g.,congestionand crowdedness)of newdevelopmentonthe local community (The UK Parliament, 1990). Later, the Barker
ReviewofLandUsePlanning (2006)waslargelycritical of
sec-tion (106) for its vagueness in concept and inconsistencies in practice.ThecommunityInfrastructurelevy(CIL)wasintroduced inthe2008PlanningActtopartiallyreplacesection(106)(TheUK
Parliament,2008).
Likelandvaluetax,section(106)andCILarebothpublic finan-cialmeasuresintendedforexternalities,hencePigovianbynature. However,LVTdiffersfromsection(106)andCILinbeinga bet-termenttax,whichtriestocapturethepositiveexternalitiesof communityinvestmentinlocalpublicinfrastructures(Leeetal., 2013). By comparison, the two types of planning charges are employedtocompensateforthepotentialnegativeexternalities ofnewpropertydevelopmentswithrespecttothelocalhousing andinfrastructurecapacities.Theyarethusessentiallythesame
Y.Wangetal./LandUsePolicy42(2015)381–391 383 thingaswhatiscalled“impactfee”intheUS(see,e.g.,Ihlanfeldt
andShaughnessy,2004).
GiventhesubtleandyetimportantdifferencebetweenLVTand planningcharges,itperhapsmakesmoresensetolookatLVTin ref-erencetotheexistingUKtaxationsystem.2Forexample,Maxwell
andVigor(2005)suggestsubstitutingLVTforcounciltaxandthe
stampduty. Theyargue that LVT is a levyonland, while both thestampdutyandcounciltaxareestimatedbypropertyvalue andareapropertytax.Taxingonpropertyinsteadoflandvalue involvesdisincentivesforhomeownerstomaintainandimprove theirhousingconditions–themoretheyinvestinmaintenanceand renovation,themorepropertytaxliable.Thisperspectiveresonates closelywithBourassa’s(1990,1992)earlierempiricalstudiesabout asimilartopicwithintheUScontext,whichidentifiedasignificant incentiveeffectofLVTvis-à-vispropertytaxation.
Researchdesign
Researchquestion
Levyingland-valuetaxinvolvesbothsubstantialpoliticalaswell astechnicalcomplexitiesandconstitutesaradicalreformtothe existingUKpublicfinanceregime.Ourresearchfocusesmoreonthe empiricalandtechnicalaspectsoftheissue,aimingtoexplorethe waystoassesslocalpublicinfrastructures’potentialcontribution totheadjacentlandvalues andtoaddresstheaccordingpolicy implications.
While theword “infrastructure”connotesa variety of facili-ties(usuallyofphysicalpresence),thispaperconcentratesonthe relationshipbetweenlandvaluesandpublictransport infrastruc-tureintheUK.Thisisbecauseofthegeneralconsensusnowadays regardingtheubiquitousandintimateinteractionsbetween trans-portandlanduseactivities(GeursandvanWee,2004).Another reason is that landvalue taxation, in recent decades,hasbeen increasinglyrationalisedasavaluecapturemechanismtofinance thedevelopmentand maintenance ofpublictransport facilities. Last,giventhecurrenteconomicclimate,publictransport infras-tructuresintheUKaretypicallyshortoffundingandthusinneed ofstrengthenedfiscalsupport(Lucas,2006).
Ourspecificresearchquestioncentresonhowtoassessthe spa-tialrelationshipsbetweenthelocalpublictransportinfrastructures and thelandvalues ofnearbyresidential properties.A concep-tual issue is that housing sub-markets are a salient feature of theBritishlocalrealestate sector(Orford,2000).A correspond-ingmethodologicalframeworkneedstobeinplacetocapturethe latentheterogeneitieswithregardtothecharacteristicsof differ-entneighbourhoodenvironments,divergentpropertypricelevels, andthevaryingrelationsbetweentheirimplicitlandvaluesand thenearnesstopublictransportlocations.
Ahedonicapproach
Given our research question, we employ a hedonic regres-sionapproachasthebasicmodellingmethodinthisstudy.While
Rosen’s(1974) seminal theoreticalpaper recommended a
two-stageregressionprocedure,forthispolicy-orientedpaper,weadopt areduced-formversionoftheRosenoriginaland,asshowninEq.
(1),assumea linearsemi-logfunctionforminthefirststageof hedonicregression,whichallowsustosimplifythesecondstageby directlyvaluingthebusstoplocationsbasedonthecorresponding
2Actually,landvaluetax(LVT)isalsooftencalledsingletax,becauseaccording
toHenryGeorge,thecollectionofLVTshouldreplaceanyothertaxationschemes,
suchasthoseonincomesandconsumptions.
coefficientestimates (see a similarapplication,for example,by
Heikkilaetal.(1989),p.223):
log(p)=F(H,Y,W,L,ε) (1)
wherepdenotestheproperty’ssaleprice,ofwhichthenaturallog isafunctionofH,Y,WandL,plusanerrorterm,ε.Hstandsfora setofhedoniccontrolvariables,eachofwhichcorrespondstoan attributeoftheobservedproperty,intermsofwhetheritisfreehold (r),newlybuilt(n),detached(d),semi-detached(s),orterraced(t), floorarea(f),andhowfarthepropertyislocatedfromthecentral businessdistrict(z).HmaybespecifiedasEq.(2):
H={r,n,d,s,t,f,z} (2)
Yrepresentsanothersetofdummy-codedvariablescapturing theyearinwhichanobservedsaletransactiontookplace.Thisis intendedtoadjustfortemporaleffects,suchasshortterm property-priceinflationinthelocalmarket,withXdenotingthetotalnumber ofyearsunderobservation.Ifthefirstyearisnotedasyear0,we haveEq.(3):
Y={Yu|u=0,1,2,...,X−1} (3) Wconsistsofaseriesofdummy-codedvariables,each indicat-ingalocaljurisdictionwithinwhichapropertyislocated.These variables captureaveragelocal environmentaleffects related to educationalandrecreationalamenitiesaswellastheoverall rep-utationofthearea.AssumingatotalofMjurisdictionswithinthe studyarea,oneofwhichisdenotedasareferencejurisdiction,W0,
wemaydefineWasfollows:
W={Wv|
v
=0,1,2,...,M−1} (4) ItshouldbenotedthatthemodelspecificationasperEqs.(4)and (5)maybeconsideredfollowinga‘discrete-spaceexpansion’pro-cess(JonesandBullen,1994,p.254),wherebytheconstanttermof
aregressionequationisexpandedintothe(X−1)+(M−1)dummy variables.
L={ı} (5)
LinEq.(5)representsasetoftargetvariables,whichrelatedirectly tothe locationof land beneath a property. Thesevariables are supposedtomeasurespatialaccessibilityandproximityto pub-lictransportinfrastructure.WeassumeinthispaperthatLconsists ofonlyoneelementı.ıinEq.(5)measurestheaggregatenumber ofpublictransportnodes(e.g.,trainstations,busstops,airport ter-minals)withinabufferorcatchmentareaofanobservedproperty location.3
Finally,acoupleofstandardeconometricassumptionsare asso-ciatedwiththeerrorterm,ε.First,weassumeindependenceor zeroautocorrelationintheobservedvaluesofε.Nevertheless,data collectedintherealworldarelikelytosufferfromspatialaswell astemporalautocorrelation,dependingonhowthecollectionis conducted.Second,weassumeasingleconstantvarianceinthe errortermornon-heteroskedasticity.However,thisassumptionis alsosubjecttoposthoctest,giventhathousingsub-marketsarean inherentfeatureoftheUKlocalrealestateindustryandtherefore thepossibilityofspatialheterogeneityinimplicitpricesbetween sub-markets.
3Itneedstobeacknowledgedthatrecentyearshaveseensomehighly
sophis-ticatedaccessibilitymeasures(e.g.,Ferrarietal.,2012).Whiletheseinnovative measuresarenotthecentraltopicofthispaper,theycanbeveryusefulforfuture research.
Multi-levelmodelling
Multilevelmodellingmaybeseenasageneralisedversionof lin-earregression(Duncanetal.,1998).Amultilevelmodellinganalysis combinesbothindividualandcontextualparameters,suchasthe geographicaljurisdiction(e.g.,electoralwards)inwhichaproperty islocatedandtheyearswhenapropertyistransacted.Multilevel modelsareintendedtoassessthecorrelationbetween observa-tionswithinthesame level ofanalysis and attempttocapture thesevariationsbyallowingtheregressionintercepttovaryacross, forexample,thejurisdictionsandtheyearsofsale.Thisapproach isknownasa“randomintercept”multi-levelmodellingmethod
(JonesandBullen,1994).
ˇ0,v,u=ˇ0+ v+˚v,u (6)
ˇ0inEq.(6)istheaverageinterceptforalloftheobserved prop-ertiesacrossdifferentjurisdictionsandsoldindifferentyears.v and˚v,uaretwoindependenterrorcomponents:vmeasuresthe extenttowhichtheregressioninterceptforobservationswithin agivenjurisdiction,Wv (
v
=0,1,2,...,M−1),deviatesfromthe overallaveragedconstantterm,ˇ0.Likewise,˚v,u measuresthe differencebetweenˇ0andtheinterceptforobservations,notonly withinWv,butalsosoldinagivenyear,Yu(u=0,1,2,...,X−1).Wedeploythismultilevelspecificationtocapturebothspatial andtemporallandvaluevariations,asperFig.1.InFig.1(a),thedata aregroupedgeographicallyintheupmostlevelbyelectoralward (ourproxyforhousingsub-markets),hopedtoaddresspotential issuesofspatialautocorrelationandheterogeneity.Thedifferent yearsofhousesalesarethendefinedasthesecondlevelofanalysis, inviewofdealingwithpotentialtemporalautocorrelation.Fig.1(b) presentsanalternativepanelstructure,wherewardremainsthe firstlevelofanalysisandeachindividualpropertyisnowsituated atthenextstage.However,theyearofsaleforeverypropertyis furtherdefinedasatertiarylevel.Thisalternativehierarchyis rele-vantwhenadatasetcontainsmanypropertiesthathavebeensold multipletimesduringtheperiodofobservation.
Quantilecalibration
The method of quantile regression is firstly introduced by
KoenkerandBassett(1978).Quantileregressionessentially
esti-matesmultiplequantiles(e.g.10%,50%or75%)inthedependent variable’sconditionaldistribution.Asaresult,theapproachtends togeneratemorerobustcoefficientestimatesandprovidemore comprehensiveinformationaboutthedistributionoftheresponse variablethanconventionalregressiontowardsthemean(Koenker,
2005).
Inthecaseofthispaper,weareconcernedwiththe substan-tialpricedifferentiationfeaturingmanyUKlocalpropertymarkets
(Orford,2000).We hypothesisethat propertiesatthe highend
ofalocalrealestatemarketmayexhibitsystematicallydifferent transport-landrelationsthan thoseat thelowerend. In econo-metricterms,this leadstonon-constantconditionalvariance in log(p)(i.e.,thenaturallogofpropertyprice),henceaviolationof thehomoscedasticityassumption.Toadjustfortheheterogeneous relationsbetweenpropertypriceandthenumberofnearbypublic transportfacilities,weapplyabivariatequantileregressionmethod inourposthocrobustnesstest:
log(p)iq=G(ı,ε) (7)
wherei(i=1,2,...,q)standsfortheithquantileintheconditional distributionoflog(p),ifthedistributionisdividedintoatotalofq equalintervals.
Fordemonstrationpurposes,assumeK(log(p))asthekernel densityfunctionoflog(p).Oneshallseethatthequantileestimation
isdifferentfromtheconventionalmeanestimation.Specially,to estimatethemeanorexpectedvalueoflog(p),wehave
E(log(p))=
log (p)max log(p)minlog(p)×K(log(p))dlog(p) (8)
The quantile estimation is however different by solvingthe belowequationinreferencetolog(p)iq:
log (p)iq log(p)minK(log(p))d log(p)= i
q (9)
A quantile coefficient, given a linear function form, can be workedoutthrough linearprogramming(KoenkerandHallock, 2001).Acquiring alargenumber of quantilecoefficients in this wayenablesustoconductbootstrappingre-samplingandgenerate anasymptotickerneldensitydistributionsuchasK(log(p)), allow-inganassessmentoftheasymptoticstandarderrorandconfidence intervalforeveryquantilecoefficient(MachadoandMata,2005).
ThecaseofCardiffbus
Thelocalbackground
TheWelshCapitalcityofCardiffisourstudysite,becausethecity exemplifiesanarrayofUK-wideissueswithregardtothefinancing oflocalpublictransport.PublicservicesintheUKhaveexperienced widespreadfundingcutsandausteritymeasuressince2008.Local publictransportisoneoftheseverelyaffectedsectors.Forexample, inCardiff,thelocalcouncil-ownedCardiffbussystemwitnesseda
£
0.6millionfundingcutbytheWelshGovernmentin2012,leading toasecondincreaseinbusfaresinceOctober2011(WalesOnline,2012).
Aselsewhere,lackoffundingforpublictransportimplicatesa numberofpotentialissuesinCardiff.Inflatedbusfare,for exam-ple,islikelytodiscourageenvironment-friendlytravelbehaviour andpushpeoplebackintotheircars(NewmanandKenworthy, 1999).Internationalexperiencealsoshowsthatrestrictedpublic transporttendstomakecommutingcostparticularlyunaffordable forthelowerincomepopulation, exacerbatingthe“spatial
mis-match” betweenwhere theylive andwhere theycanfind jobs
(Kain,1992).Business opportunitiescanalsobeaffectedifthey
becomelessaccessibleduetoashrinkingsupplyofpublic trans-port facilities. Allof theseissues, among many others, alert us tothechallengeoffinancingpublictransportinadireeconomic climate.
Levyinglandvaluecapturepropertytaxappearstobea prom-isingsolution.InthecaseofCardiffBus,asinglefareof
£
1.70only accountsforthevalueofbusservicetoapassenger,whileaproperty ownerwholivesadjacenttotheCardiffbusnetworkdoesnot nec-essarilypaythebusfareinsofarasnotusingtheservice.However,fromaGeorge(1879)perspective,theCardiff Busnetworkmay
havepromotedtheaccessibilityofitsnearbyrealestateproperties, hencecontributingtoanappreciationofeachproperty’svalueby ameasurablepercentage.Ifthisresearchhypothesiscanbe sub-stantiatedand evidenced,a landvaluecapturetaxation scheme becomesjustifiable.
Thedata
Thedatasetusedinthisstudycontainsobservedpropertyprices andbusstoplocationsmainlywithincentralCardiffbetween2000 and2009(seeFig.2).Ourstudyareacovers12localelectoralwards. TheareacontainstypicalVictorianandEdwardianterracedhouses, flatsinconvertedbuildingsandsuburbanstylesemi-detachedand
Y.Wangetal./LandUsePolicy42(2015)381–391 385
Fig.1.Cross-sectional(a)vsmultilevelpanel;(b)structuresforpropertydataanalysis.
Notes:adaptedfromDuncanetal.(1998).
Table1
Definitionofvariablesanddescriptivestatistics.
Continuousvariables Definition Mean St.dev.
p PropertysalepriceinBritishpoundsterling(£) 143922 87264
log(p) Naturallogarithmofpriceofthepropertywhensold 11.725 0.5
ı300m Numberofbus-stopswithin300metres(m)offtheproperty 7.4 3.7
ı400m Numberofbus-stopswithin400metres(m)offtheproperty 13.3 5.3
ı500m Numberofbus-stopswithin500metres(m)offtheproperty 20.7 7.4
ı750m Numberofbus-stopswithin750metres(m)offtheproperty 45.2 14.8
ı1000m Numberofbus-stopswithin1000metres(m)offtheproperty 77.7 24.4
ı1500m Numberofbus-stopswithin1500metres(m)offtheproperty 167.7 57.5
F Floorareaofapropertyinsquaremetres(m2) 105.2 48.9
Z Distancetothecentralbusinessdistrictinmetres(m) 3225.3 1408.7
Categoricalvariables Definition Proportion
r 1ifpropertyisonfreeholdtenure,0otherwise 89.7%
n 1,ifpropertyisnewlybuiltwhensold,0otherwise 3.8%
Propertytype
Flatasathereferencecategory 4.1%
d 1,ifpropertyisadetachedhouse,0otherwise 12.0%
s 1,ifpropertyisasemi-detachedhouse,0otherwise 25.6%
t 1,ifpropertyisaterracedhouse,0otherwise 58.3%
Year
Y0 1,ifpropertywassoldin2000,0otherwise(referencecategory) 11.2%
Y1 1,ifpropertywassoldin2001,0otherwise 13.4%
Y2 1,ifpropertywassoldin2002,0otherwise 14.5%
Y3 1,ifpropertywassoldin2003,0otherwise 12.6%
Y4 1,ifpropertywassoldin2004,0otherwise 12.3%
Y5 1,ifpropertywassoldin2005,0otherwise 9.6%
Y6 1,ifpropertywassoldin2006,0otherwise 12.9%
Y7 1,ifpropertywassoldin2007,0otherwise 12.4%
Y8 1,ifpropertywassoldin2008,0otherwise 1.1%
Ward
W0 1,ifapropertyislocatedinCyncoed(referencecategory) 11.5%
W1 1,ifpropertyislocatedinAdamsdownorButetown,0otherwise 12.1%
W2 1,ifpropertyislocatedinCathays,0otherwise 2.4%
W3 1,ifpropertyislocatedinHeath,0otherwise 1.6%
W4 1,ifpropertyislocatedinLlanishen,0otherwise 1.3%
W5 1,ifpropertyislocatedinSplottorRumney,0otherwise 23.1%
W6 1,ifpropertyislocatedinPenylan,0otherwise 15.0%
W7 1,ifpropertyislocatedinPentwyn,0otherwise 17.6%
W8 1,ifpropertyislocatedinPlasnewydd,0otherwise 13.9%
Fig.2.PropertiesandbusstopsincentralCardiff.
purpose-buildflats.Over 9700residentialpropertieswithinthe areahavebeensoldatleastoncebetween2000and2009, pro-viding12,887salerecords,accordingtotheLandRegistry.Apart fromthesale records,LandRegistry alsocarries detailed infor-mationregardingtheseproperties,includingtheirdwellingtypes
(detached,semi-detached,terraceorflat),tenures(freeholdand leasehold),andwhethera propertywasa newbuild. Floorarea wascalculated forevery propertyin thesample usinga meth-odologydescribed in Orford (2010). The bus stoplocationsare retrievedfrom the2007NationalPublicTransportAccessNode
Table2
Numberoftimesapropertyissoldwithinthe9-yearperiodofthedata.
Numberoftimesapropertyissoldwithinthe9-yearperiodofobservation
1 2 3 4 5 6 7
Y. Wang et al. / Land Use Policy 42 (2015) 381–391 387 Table3
Resultsofordinaryleastsquares,log(p)asdependentvariable.
Model1 Model2 Model3 Model4 Model5 Model6
Within300m Within400m Within500m Within750m Within1000m Within1500m
ˇ s.e. ˇ s.e. ˇ s.e. ˇ s.e. ˇ s.e. ˇ s.e.
Constant 10.506*** 0.025 10.479*** 0.027 10.438*** 0.028 10.417*** 0.034 10.343*** 0.039 10.269*** 0.048 Freehold(r) 0.120*** 0.009 0.121*** 0.009 0.123*** 0.009 0.126*** 0.009 0.127*** 0.009 0.125*** 0.009 New-built(n) 0.228*** 0.013 0.230*** 0.013 0.232*** 0.013 0.230*** 0.013 0.237*** 0.013 0.217*** 0.013 Detached(d) 0.651*** 0.016 0.654*** 0.016 0.654*** 0.016 0.647*** 0.016 0.644*** 0.016 0.645*** 0.016 Semi-detached(s) 0.468*** 0.014 0.471*** 0.014 0.469*** 0.014 0.465*** 0.014 0.464*** 0.014 0.465*** 0.015 Terraced(t) 0.360*** 0.014 0.361*** 0.014 0.359*** 0.014 0.356*** 0.014 0.354*** 0.014 0.357*** 0.014 Floorarea(f) 0.004*** 0.000 0.004*** 0.000 0.004*** 0.000 0.004*** 0.000 0.004*** 0.000 0.004*** 0.000 DistancetoCBD(z) 0.035*** 0.004 0.038*** 0.004 0.042*** 0.004 0.046*** 0.005 0.055*** 0.005 0.066*** 0.007 Salein2001(Y1) 0.112*** 0.009 0.110*** 0.009 0.111*** 0.009 0.112*** 0.009 0.113*** 0.009 0.110*** 0.009 Salein2002(Y2) 0.301*** 0.009 0.297*** 0.009 0.297*** 0.009 0.297*** 0.009 0.299*** 0.009 0.295*** 0.009 Salein2003(Y3) 0.526*** 0.009 0.522*** 0.009 0.524*** 0.009 0.525*** 0.009 0.522*** 0.009 0.520*** 0.009 Salein2004(Y4) 0.694*** 0.009 0.693*** 0.009 0.693*** 0.009 0.694*** 0.009 0.693*** 0.009 0.691*** 0.009 Salein2005(Y5) 0.781*** 0.010 0.778*** 0.010 0.776*** 0.009 0.778*** 0.009 0.777*** 0.009 0.776*** 0.010 Salein2006(Y6) 0.791*** 0.009 0.789*** 0.009 0.789*** 0.009 0.791*** 0.009 0.791*** 0.009 0.789*** 0.009 Salein2007(Y7) 0.842*** 0.009 0.840*** 0.009 0.840*** 0.009 0.841*** 0.009 0.840*** 0.009 0.839*** 0.009 Salein2008(Y8) 0.858*** 0.023 0.857*** 0.023 0.861*** 0.022 0.860*** 0.022 0.861*** 0.022 0.861*** 0.022 Adamstown(W1) −0.512*** 0.014 −0.508*** 0.014 −0.502*** 0.014 −0.499*** 0.014 −0.488*** 0.014 −0.465*** 0.015 Splott(W2) −0.513*** 0.012 −0.507*** 0.012 −0.493*** 0.012 −0.486*** 0.013 −0.464*** 0.014 −0.430*** 0.017 Cathays(W3) −0.196*** 0.020 −0.194*** 0.020 −0.186*** 0.020 −0.182*** 0.020 −0.164*** 0.020 −0.152*** 0.021 Heath(W4) −0.142*** 0.019 −0.137*** 0.019 −0.139*** 0.019 −0.143*** 0.019 −0.146*** 0.019 −0.144*** 0.019 Llanishen(W5) −0.240*** 0.024 −0.250*** 0.024 −0.257*** 0.024 −0.262*** 0.025 −0.269*** 0.025 −0.276*** 0.025 Penylan(W6) −0.064*** 0.011 −0.064*** 0.011 −0.062*** 0.011 −0.051*** 0.011 −0.039*** 0.011 −0.018 0.013 Pentwyn(W7) −0.648*** 0.010 −0.647*** 0.010 −0.643*** 0.010 −0.644*** 0.010 −0.638*** 0.010 −0.638*** 0.010 Plasnewydd(W8) −0.235*** 0.014 −0.230*** 0.014 −0.225*** 0.014 −0.229*** 0.014 −0.229*** 0.014 −0.218*** 0.014 Pontprennau(W9) −0.500*** 0.020 −0.502*** 0.020 −0.502*** 0.020 −0.506*** 0.020 −0.508*** 0.020 −0.505*** 0.020
Numberofbusstops(ı) 0.003*** 0.001 0.003*** 0.001 0.003*** 0.000 0.001*** 0.000 0.001*** 0.000 0.001*** 0.000
Samplesize 9655 9650 9656 9653 9659 9669 R2 0.850 0.850 0.850 0.851 0.850 0.849 F-test(df) 2176(25) 2179(25) 2185(25) 2195(25) 2186(25) 2167(25) p-Value 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 *p<0.1;**p<0.05. ***p<0.001.
Table4
TestingautocorrelationandhomoscedasticityinOLSresults.
Model1 Model2 Model3 Model4 Model5 Model6
Within300m Within400m Within500m Within750m Within1000m Within1500m Independenceofε Durbin–Watson 1.773 1.777 1.779 1.779 1.779 1.776 p-Value 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 Spatialautocorrelation Moran’sI 0.150 0.150 0.149 0.149 0.150 0.149 Expected −0.0001 −0.0001 −0.0001 −0.0001 −0.0001 −0.0001 Standarddeviation 0.0004 0.0004 −0.0004 0.0004 0.0004 0.0004 p-Value 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000
Homoscedasticity BreuschandPagan(1979)test
2(df) 0.233(1) 0.101(1) 0.533(1) 0.887(1) 1.503(1) 0.612(1)
p-Value 0.6293 0.7512 0.4651 0.3461 0.2202 0.4341
(NaPTAN-v2.2)dataset(Department forTransport,2007).These arealsoshowninFig.2.Thenumberofbusstopswithinspecified radiiofeachproperty(i.e.,300m,400m,500m,750m,1000m,and 1500m)wascalculatedusingArcGIS.Table1presentsasummary ofthevariablesincludedinthesampleofpropertiesinthedataset.
Table2alsoshowsthatthisisbroadlyacross-sectionalratherthan
paneldataset,asmorethan75%ofthepropertieshaveonlybeen soldonceduringthe9-yearperiod.
Modelresults4
OLSresults
Table3presentstheresultsofsixordinaryleastsquare(OLS)
regressions based on the conventional hedonic approach
pre-scribedin“AHedonicApproach”section.Thedependentvariable ineveryregressionisthenaturallogarithmofprice(log(p))andall ofthesixmodelsattempttocapturetheeffectofCardiffBuson landvalueviaı,whichmeasuresthenumberofbusstopswithin differentwalkableradii(i.e.,300m,400m,500m,750m,1000m, and1500m)aroundeachpropertycontainedinthedataset. Fol-lowingBelsleyetal.(1980)avarietyofregressiondiagnostictests wereperformedontheOLSmodelsinordertocheckwhetherany oftheregressionassumptionshadbeenviolated.Theseincluded identifyingoutliersthatmayhaveadisproportionateinfluenceon themodels,andremovingthecorrespondingobservationsif neces-sary;checkingforseriousmulti-collinearityinthemodels;testing thenormalityoftheerrorterm;andcheckingforheteroscedasticity andautocorrelationintheerrorterm.Thelattertestsarediscussed inmoredetailinalatersection.
Model1,forexample,includestheexplanatoryvariablewith regardtothenumberofbusstopswithin300maroundeach prop-erty.Theestimatedparametercorrespondingtothisvariableshows that theeffect of Cardiff Buson property priceor, more accu-rately, onland value as reflected in property price,is positive andstatisticallysignificantatthe1%significancelevel. Inother words,themorebusstopstherearearoundaproperty,thehigher thevalueoflandbeneaththatproperty.Similarfindingsarealso discerniblefromtheotherregressionsestimatingtheeffectof num-berof busstopswithin400m, 500,750m,1000mand 1500m, respectively.
Bybacktransformingthemagnitudeoftheestimated coeffi-cientwithregardtothenumberof busstopswithin300m, we cancalculatethemarginalincreaseinlandvalueasaresultof pla-cingeveryextrabusstoparoundaproperty.Inpercentage, this
4 OLSresultsareestimatedinIBMSPSSStatistics20,whilethemulti-levelanalysis
isconductedwithMLWinv.3.20(Rasbashetal.,2012).Thequantileregressionis
exercisedusinganR/SPSSinterfacebasedontheoriginal“quantreg”Rcodesby
Koenker(2007).
addedlandvalueequalsto(e0.003−1)×100≈0.3%.Examinationof
thecoefficientsofthenumberofbus-stopswithindifferentbuffer zonesaroundpropertyinTable3suggeststhattheeffectofbus stopswithindistanceisrelativelystableandstatistically signifi-cant.Thelandvaluebenefitofeveryadditionalbusstopwithina circularcatchmentarealargerthan500mbyradiusisabout0.1% ofthecorrespondingpropertyprice.Thefigurerisesto0.3%ifthe sizeofcatchmentshrinksto500morlessbyradius.Overall,all modelsshowthattheavailabilityofpublictransportinfrastructure cansignificantlypromotelandvalueand therebyraiseproperty price.
Thecoefficientofz,thedistancetoCardiff’scentralbusiness district(CBD),isalsopositiveandstatisticallysignificant. Accord-ingtosomestudies,thisfindingiscounter-intuitiveandagainst theconventionalwisdomabouturbanspatialstructure.Per clas-sicurbaneconomictheory(e.g.,Anasetal.,1998),propertyprices shoulddeclinealongsideincreaseintheproperties’distancetocity centre.However,previousstudieshavealsoprovidedseveral expla-nationsforthepositiveinfluenceofdistancetoCBDonproperty price.Forexample,theassumptionofa declininglandvalueas distanceincreasesfromCBDisbasedontheadoptionofa mono-centriclocationchoicemodel(DubinandSung,1987),whileCardiff appearstobearatherpolycentriccity.
Floorareaisalsoapositiveandstatisticallysignificantfactorin termsofitsimpactonpropertyprice.Theeffectoffloorspaceis consistentacrossallsixmodelspresentedinTable3.Followinga backtransformationoftheparameterwithrespecttofloorspace, wefindthateveryadditionalsquaremetreinapropertyincreases itsvalueby(e0.004−1)×100≈0.4%.
Wecapturemeanspatialvariationinpropertypricebyusinga seriesofdummy-codedvariablesrepresentingthewardsinwhich eachpropertyislocated.ThewardnamedCyncoedisusedasthe referencecategoryasitistheareawiththehighestaverage prop-ertypriceinthedataset.Allmodelsshowasignificantdifferencein propertypricefromCyncoed,althoughthelastregression(model
6inTable3)indicatesnosignificantdifferenceinpropertyprice
betweenCyncoedandPenylan.
Allothercoefficientshavetheexpectedsignsandagreewith conventionalfindingsinthehedonicliterature(Edmonds,1984). Forexample,apropertyunderafreeholdtenureislikelytoshowa higherpricecomparedwithaleaseholdproperty.Similarly,anewly builtpropertytendstohavemoremarketvaluethananaged prop-erty.Detachedpropertiesexhibitthehighestprices,followedby semi-detachedpropertiesandflats,ofwhichthelatterisdefined asthereferencepropertytypeinthisanalysis.Finally,thedummy variableswithregardtopricedifferencesduetothecalendaryear whenapropertywassoldareallsignificantlydifferentfromzero. Theyearof2000isusedasthereferenceyear,whiletheremaining coefficientsindicateaconstantincreaseinpropertypriceovertime, partlyduetoinflationinpoundsterlingandpartlyduetodynamics inthelocalhousingmarket.
Y.Wangetal./LandUsePolicy42(2015)381–391 389 Multilevelresults
Asmentioned earlier, ordinaryleast square(OLS) regression mayinvolvepotentialissuesrelatedtospatialandtemporal auto-correlations. In terms of spatial autocorrelation, the prices of propertieswithinasamejurisdiction(i.e.,electoralwardsinour data)arelikelytobemoresimilarthanthoseoutside.Intermsof temporalautocorrelation,propertiessoldwithinthesameyearmay showaconvergenceinsalepricevis-à-visthosetransactedwithin adifferentyear.Toaccountforboththegeographicaswellas tem-poralautocorrelations,ourOLSmodelswouldhavetobeexpanded extensivelytoaccommodate(M−1)×(X−1)interactionfactors.In contrast,multilevelmodellinganalysisappearstobeamore effi-cientalternativetoaddresstheissueofautocorrelation(Jonesand
Bullen,1994).
Table4identifiesaproblemofautocorrelationunderlyingall
thesixOLSmodels.TheDurbin–Watsontestsuggestsanoverall significantserialinterdependenceoftheerrorterms(ε)inevery OLSmodel.BecausetheDurbin–Watsonresultismoresensitive totemporalautocorrelation,wefurtherexerciseaMoran’sItest
(Anselin,1988),ofwhichtheestimatesalsoconfirmapresenceof
asignificantalbeitweakspatialautocorrelation(Moran’sI≈0.15). However,theBreuschandPagan(1979)testforthewholemodel suggeststhatheteroscedasticityisnotaproblemintheerrorterms andtheyhaveconstantvariance.Toaddresstheautocorrelation problem,sixmultilevelregressions(models7–12)arefurther con-ducted.Sinceover75%ofthesampledpropertiesaresoldonlyonce between2000and2009,weestimatethemultilevelmodelsin ref-erencetothecross-sectionalhierarchyshowninFig.1(a)instead ofthepanelstructureasperFig.1(b).
Table5illustratestheresultsofourmultilevelmodelling
anal-ysis. Both theward-by-ward (2
ward) and year-to-year variance
(2
year)arestatisticallysignificant,confirmingtheOLSfindingthat
therearegeneralisabledifferencesacrosswardsandyearsinterms ofpropertyprice.Around19%oftheaggregatevarianceinproperty price(2
property)canbeattributedto2ward,comparedwitharound
56%to2
year.Nevertheless,ı,which measurestheimpactofbus
stopsonnearbylandvalue,remainsstableandisthusunbiased. ThisessentiallyconfirmstherobustnessoftheOLSestimates,even infaceoftheidentifiedspatialandtemporalautocorrelations.
Quantileresults
Table6reportstheresultsofourquantilebivariateregressions.
Asnotedabove,weconductthisquantileanalysismainlyasapost hoccalibrationoftheOLSestimates,incaseprice-based hetero-geneitiesleadtoabiasedcoefficientmeasureofı.We thususe log(p)asthedependentvariableand ıastheonlyindependent variabletogaugethenumberofbusstopswithindifferentwalkable distances,from300mto1500m,aroundeveryobservedproperty location.
Generallyspeaking, Table6 indicatesrelativelyweakand/or insignificantassociationsbetweenthenumberofbus stopsand propertypricesatthe10%and20%quantiles,wheretheobserved propertypricesarebelow
£
74,000inthedataset.Incontrast,the strongestandmostsignificantcorrelationscanbefoundfor proper-tiesatthe80%quantile,pricedaround£
195,000.Thoseevenmore expensivepropertiesatthe90%quantile(i.e.,£
250.000),however, seemtobenefitnomorefromthenumberofnearbybusstopsthan thoseatthe80%quantile,eventhoughtheytendtobebetteroff comparedwithallpropertiesbelowthe80%quantile,especially whenweincreasethesearchradiustomorethan750m.WhileconfirmingtheoverallrobustnessofOLSestimateswith regardtothemeanofı,theresultsofourquantileanalysisdo
sug-gestıtobesystematicallyvolatileacrossdifferentpricesegments. Table
5 Results of multi-level modelling, log( p ) as dependent variable. Model 7 Model 8 Model 9 Model 10 Model 11 Model 12 Within 300 m Within 400 m Within 500 m Within 750 m Within 1000 m Within 1500 m ˇ0 s.e. ˇ0 s.e. ˇ0 s.e. ˇ0 s.e. ˇ0 s.e. ˇ0 s.e. Constant 10.735 *** 0.070 10.710 *** 0.071 10.671 *** 0.071 10.660 *** 0.073 10.590 *** 0.075 10.520 *** 0.079 Freehold ( r ) 0.116 *** 0.009 0.117 *** 0.009 0.119 *** 0.009 0.122 *** 0.009 0.123 *** 0.009 0.121 *** 0.009 New-built ( n ) 0.221 *** 0.013 0.223 *** 0.013 0.224 *** 0.013 0.221 *** 0.013 0.226 *** 0.013 0.208 *** 0.013 Detached ( d ) 0.659 *** 0.016 0.662 *** 0.016 0.663 *** 0.016 0.655 *** 0.016 0.653 *** 0.016 0.654 *** 0.016 Semi-detached ( s ) 0.476 *** 0.014 0.480 *** 0.014 0.478 *** 0.014 0.473 *** 0.014 0.472 *** 0.014 0.474 *** 0.014 Terraced ( t ) 0.369 *** 0.014 0.371 *** 0.014 0.370 *** 0.014 0.366 *** 0.014 0.364 *** 0.014 0.367 *** 0.014 Floor area ( f ) 0.004 *** 0.000 0.004 *** 0.000 0.004 *** 0.000 0.004 *** 0.000 0.004 *** 0.000 0.004 *** 0.000 Distance to CBD ( z ) 0.035 *** 0.004 0.038 *** 0.004 0.042 *** 0.004 0.045 *** 0.005 0.054 *** 0.005 0.065 *** 0.007 Number of bus stops ( ı ) 0.003 *** 0.001 0.003 *** 0.001 0.003 *** 0.000 0.001 *** 0.000 0.001 *** 0.000 0.001 *** 0.000 2 ward 0.034 ** 0.020 0.033 ** 0.020 0.033 ** 0.020 0.033 ** 0.020 0.033 ** 0.020 0.033 ** 0.020 2 year 0.099 *** 0.016 0.099 *** 0.016 0.098 *** 0.016 0.099 *** 0.016 0.098 *** 0.016 0.099 *** 0.016 2 property 0.044 *** 0.001 0.044 *** 0.001 0.043 *** 0.001 0.043 *** 0.001 0.044 *** 0.001 0.044 *** 0.001 Contribution of 2 ward to 2 property 0.192 0.188 0.190 0.189 0.189 0.188 Contribution of 2 year to 2 property 0.559 0.563 0.563 0.566 0.560 0.563 Sample size 9655 9650 9656 9653 9659 9669 * p < 0.1. ** p < 0.05. *** p < 0.001.
Table6
Resultsofquantilebivariateregressions,log(p)asdependentvariableandıasindependentvariable.
Quantile ı300m ı400m ı500m ı750m ı1000m ı750m
ˇ s.e. ˇ s.e. ˇ s.e. ˇ s.e. ˇ s.e. ˇ s.e.
10% −0.004 0.003 0.001 0.002 0.007*** 0.002 0.004*** 0.001 0.002*** 0.000 0.001*** 0.000 20% 0.004 0.003 0.003* 0.002 0.005*** 0.001 0.003*** 0.000 0.002*** 0.000 0.001*** 0.000 30% 0.011*** 0.002 0.007*** 0.002 0.007*** 0.001 0.003*** 0.001 0.002*** 0.000 0.001*** 0.000 40% 0.013*** 0.002 0.009*** 0.001 0.009*** 0.001 0.004*** 0.001 0.002*** 0.000 0.001*** 0.000 50% 0.013*** 0.001 0.013*** 0.001 0.009*** 0.001 0.004*** 0.000 0.003*** 0.000 0.001*** 0.000 60% 0.010*** 0.002 0.010*** 0.002 0.009*** 0.001 0.004*** 0.000 0.002*** 0.000 0.001*** 0.000 70% 0.013*** 0.002 0.013*** 0.002 0.008*** 0.001 0.003*** 0.000 0.002*** 0.000 0.001*** 0.000 80% 0.020*** 0.002 0.020*** 0.002 0.010*** 0.001 0.005*** 0.001 0.003*** 0.000 0.002*** 0.000 90% 0.011*** 0.002 0.011*** 0.002 0.008*** 0.001 0.005*** 0.001 0.003*** 0.000 0.002*** 0.000 * p<0.1. **p<0.05. ***p<0.001.
Specifically,spatialproximitytoCardiffBusstopstendsto ben-efitpropertiesatthehighendofthelocalrealestatemarket.The strongestpositiveexternalitiescanbeobservedinpropertiesabove the80%pricequantile,witheveryadditionalbus stopwithin a 1500mbufferzone,forexample,contributingtoanincreaseby about0.22%inpropertysalepricethroughlandvaluebetterment. Thecorrespondingfigureforthecheaperpropertiesishalvedto around0.11%.
Policyimplications
Theresultsofourregressionanalysisbasedonempiricaldata fromCardiff havesomeimportantpolicyimplications.First and foremost,theoutcomesofourordinaryleastsquareregressionand multilevelmodellinganalysisprovideconvincingevidenceto sup-portaclassicGeorgisthypothesisinthecaseofCardiffBus,thata significantpartoftheaddedlocalpropertyvaluesdoescomefrom thelandbeneaththem,ormorespecifically,fromthelandplots’ geographicadjacencytothebusstoplocations.Thisfinding jus-tifiesapotentialpolicyinterventionintermsoffinancingCardiff Busthroughalandvaluetaxmechanism,giventhesubstantiated positiveexternalitiesyieldedbyCardiffBus.
Second,theresultsofourquantilecalibrationentailsomeeven moreintriguingpracticalinsights.Wefindthatthepositive exter-nalitiesofCardiffBusaredistributedunevenlyamongproperties atdifferentpricelevelsinthelocalrealestatemarket.Generally speaking,accordingtoTable6,propertiesatthehighend(atthe80% and90%quantiles)ofthemarkettendtobenefitmorethanthoseat thelowend(atthe10%and20%quantiles).Thisimplicatesa neces-sitytoexerciseprogressivelandvaluetaxation,wherebyproperties atdifferentpricelevelsneedtobetaxedatdifferentrates,sothat theunevendistributionofpositiveexternalitiescanbeaccordingly captured.Ourestimation,basedonthenumberofbusstopswithin a1500mradiusofeveryindividualpropertyincludedinoursample data,suggestsatentativelandvaluebettermenttaxrateof0.11% pernewbusstopforthefirsttierofpropertieswhicharepriced below
£
195,000and0.22%forthesecondtierofpropertieswhich areofhighermarketvalues.Wenoticeasomewhatsimilarprogressivetaxationmechanism alreadyincorporatedinCardiff’sexistingcounciltaxsystem,which divideslocalresidential propertiesinto ninedifferentbands by theirestimatedvaluesandappliesincrementaltaxrates.Thereis thusapossibilityofintroducinganembryoniclandvaluetax ele-mentintothecurrentcounciltaxscheme,dependingonhowwe translatethequantilehedonicapproachfeaturedinthisstudyinto thecounciltaxationsystemusedinpracticeandalsoonwhethera largeenoughdatasetcoveringtheentireCardiffCounciljurisdiction willbecomeavailableinthenearfuture.
Third, our overall empirical analysis defies a conventional wisdomthatpublicinfrastructure alwaysservespublicinterest.
Arguably,thecase ofCardiffBusillustratesafree-ridescenario,
wherein the most wealthy property owners, intentionally or
unintentionally,endupextractingthevaluesofpubliclyfunded transport infrastructures. Asimilar findinghasalso beenmade recentlybyBanisterandThurstain-Goodwin(2011,pp.216–221), whosuggestlandvaluebettermentcreatedbytherailnetworks tobeevenmoreextensive.Inthissense,levyinglandvaluetax isnotonlytocaptureeconomicexternalities,butalsotoensure socioeconomicjusticeandfairness,aspertheEdwardiantradition.
Conclusionandfutureresearch
Inthispaper,weexplorethepotentialviabilityoflevyingland valuetaxwithinalocalUKcontext.Wefocusontheempiricaland technicalaspectsbyaskinghowtoassessthespatialisedrelations betweenthelocalpublictransportinfrastructuresandtheland val-uesofnearbyresidentialproperties.Weanswerthisquestionby studyingthecaseofCardiffBus.Basedonourmultileveland quan-tilehedonicanalysis,wefindstrongevidencewithregardtothe positiveexternalitiesofCardiffBusnetworktowardsthemarket valuesofnearbyresidentialproperties.Giventheuneven external-itydistributionbetweenpropertiesatdifferentpricelevels,wecall foraprogressivelandvaluetaxscheme.
Becauseofthepoliticalcontextofourstudy,weconsideraction researcha key directionof ourfuture research.We would like totakemore opportunitiesto useourresearchtoeducate and informthegeneralpublicaboutwhylandvaluetax(LVT)isan economicallyaswellassociallydesirableidea.Potential opposi-tionstoLVTareless likelyfromanefficiencyperspective,since mostclassicresearchhasalreadyconfirmedthatpurelytaxingon incomesfromlandwould notdistortresource allocation(Mills,
1981;Tideman,1982;Wildasin,1982).Morerecentresearchalso
showsthatitisactuallyeasierthanthoughttoimplementneutral ornon-distortionallandtaxation(Arnott,2005).Evenwitherrors inlandvaluation,thecollectionofLVThasbeenfoundtoresult innomore distortionsthan theconventionalproperty taxation scheme(Chapmanetal.,2009).ResistancestoLVTarethusmore likelyaboutthedistributionaleffectsoflandtaxation,orputsimply, regardinghowtosplitthebillsthatfundpublicinvestments. Con-troversialasthisquestionis,wehopeourcurrentstudyandfuture researchonlandvaluetaxwillhelpthevotersmakeaninformed decision.
Acknowledgements
The research reported in this paper is funded by the
BritishAcademy/LeverlulmeSmallResearchGrantinitiative(ref: SG122122).Allerrorslurkinginthepaperaretheauthors’.
Y.Wangetal./LandUsePolicy42(2015)381–391 391
References
Al-Mosaind,M.A.,Dueker,K.J.,Strathman,J.G.,1993.Light-railTransitStationsand PropertyValues:AHedonicPriceApproach.CenterforUrbanStudies,Schoolof UrbanandPublicAffairs,PortlandStateUniversity,Portland,OR,USA.
Anas,A., Arnott, R.,Small, K., 1998. Urbanspatial structure. J. Econ. Lit.36, 1426–1464.
Andelson,R.V.,2000.Land-valueTaxationAroundtheWorld:StudiesinEconomic
ReformandSocialJustice.Blackwell,Oxford.
Anselin,L.,1988.SpatialEconometrics:MethodsandModels.Springer,London.
Arnott,R.,2005.Neutralpropertytaxation.J.PublicEcon.Theory7(1),27–50.
Banister,D.,Thurstain-Goodwin,M.,2011.Quantificationofthenon-transport ben-efitsresultingfromrailinvestment.J.Transp.Geogr.19(2),212–223.
Barker,K.,2006.BarkerReviewofLandUsePlanning:FinalReport,
Recommenda-tions.H.M.TreasuryStationeryOffice,Norwich.
Belsley,D.A.,Kuh,K.,Welsch,R.E.,1980.RegressionDiagnostics:Identifying Influ-entialDataandSourcesofCollinearity.JohnWiley&Sons,NewYork.
Bollinger,C.R.,Ihlanfeldt,K.R.,1997.Theimpactofrapidrailtransitoneconomic development:thecaseofAtlanta’sMARTA.J.UrbanEcon.42,179–204.
Bourassa,S.C.,1990.Landvaluetaxationandhousingdevelopment:effectsofthe propertytaxreforminthreetypesofcities.Am.J.Econ.Sociol.49(1),101–111.
Bourassa,S.C.,1992.Economiceffectsoftaxesonland.Am.J.Econ.Sociol.51(1), 109–113.
Bowes,D.R.,Ihlanfeldt,K.R.,2001.Identifyingtheimpactsofrailtransitstationson residentialpropertyvalues.J.UrbanEcon.50(1),1–25.
Breusch,T.S.,Pagan,A.R.,1979.Asimpletestforheteroscedasticityandrandom coefficientvariation.Econometrica47(5),1287–1294.
Chapman,J.I.,Johnston,R.J.,Tyrrell,T.J.,2009.Implicationsofalandvaluetaxwith errorinassessedvalues.LandEcon.85(4),576–586.
Debrezion,G.,Pels,E.,Rietveld,P.,2007.Theimpactofrailwaystationsonresidential andcommercialpropertyvalue:ameta-analysis.J.RealEstateFinanc.Econ.35, 161–180.
Debrezion,G.,Pels,E.,Rietveld,P.,2011.Theimpactofrailtransportonrealestate pricesanempiricalanalysisofthedutchhousingmarket.UrbanStud.48(5), 997–1015.
DepartmentforTransport,2007.NationalPublicTransportAccessNodes,v2.2.
http://www.dft.gov.uk/naptan/schema/schemas.htm(accessed14.08.13). Dubin,R.A.,Sung,C.-H.,1987.Spatialvariationinthepriceofhousing:rentgradients
innon-monocentriccities.UrbanStud.24,193–204.
Duncan,C.,Jones,K.,Moon,G.,1998.Context,compositionandheterogeneity:using multilevelmodelsinhealthresearch.Soc.Sci.Med.46(1),97–117.
Dye,R.F.,England,R.W.,2010.AssessingtheTheoryandPracticeofLandValue
Taxation.LincolnInstituteofLandPolicy,MA,USA.
Edmonds,R.G.,1984.Atheoreticalbasisforhedonicregression:aresearchprimer. RealEstateEcon.12(1),72–85.
Ferrari,L.,Berlingerio,M.,etal.,2012.Measuringtheaccessibilityofpublictransport usingpervasivemobilitydata.IEEEPervasiveComput.12(1),26–33.
George,H.,1879.ProgressandPoverty.Schalkenberg,NewYork,Reprinted1962.
Geurs,K.,vanWee,B.,2004.Accessibilityevaluationofland-useandtransport strategies:reviewandresearchdirections.J.Transp.Geogr.12(2),127–140.
Hattersley,R.,2004.TheEdwardians.LittleBrown,London.
Heikkila,E.,Gordon,P.,Kim,J.I.,Peiser,R.B.,Richardson,H.W.,Dale-Johnson,D.,1989.
WhathappenedtotheCBD-distancegradient?Landvaluesinapolycentriccity. Environ.Plan.A21(2),221–232.
Hess,D.B.,Almeida,T.M.,2007.Impactofproximityto lightrailrapidtransit onstation-areapropertyvaluesinBuffalo,NewYork.UrbanStud.44(5–6), 1041–1068.
Ihlanfeldt,K.R.,Shaughnessy,T.M.,2004.Anempiricalinvestigationoftheeffects ofimpactfeesonhousing andlandmarkets.Reg.Sci.UrbanEcon.34(8), 639–661.
Jones,J.,Bullen,N.,1994.Contextualmodelsofurbanhouseprices:acomparisonof fixedandrandom-coefficientmodelsdevelopedbyexpansion.Econ.Geogr.70 (3),252–272.
Kain,J.K.,1992.Thespatialmismatchhypothesis:threedecadeslater.Hous.Policy Debate.3(2),371–392.
Koenker,R.,2005.QuantileRegression.CambridgeUniversityPress,Cambridge.
Koenker,R.,2007.quantreg:QuantileRegression.Rpackageversion4.10.
Koenker,K.,Bassett,G.,1978.Regressionquantiles.Econometrica.46(1),33–50.
Koenker,R.,Hallock,K.,2001.Quantileregression:anintroduction.J.Econ.Perspect. 15(4),43–56.
Lee,S.S.,Webster,C.J.,Melián,G.,Calzada,G.,Carr,R.,2013.Apropertyrightsanalysis ofurbanplanninginSpainandUK.Eur.Plan.Stud.21(10),1475–1490.
Lucas,K.,2006.Providingtransportforsocialinclusionwithinaframeworkfor environmentaljusticeintheUK.Transp.Res.A:PolicyPract.40(10),801–809.
Machado,J.A.F.,Mata,J.,2005.Counterfactualdecompositionofchangesinwage distributionusingquantileregression.J.Appl.Econom.20(4),445–465.
Marx,K.,1867.DasKapital,Bd.1.MEW,Bd.23.,pp.405.
Maxwell,D.,Vigor,A.,2005.TimeforLandValueTax?InstituteforPublicPolicy Research,London.
Mills,D.E.,1981.Thenon-neutralityoflandvaluetaxation.Natl.TaxJ.34(1), 125–129.
Newman,P.,Kenworthy,J.R.,1999.SustainabilityandCities:Overcoming Automo-bileDependence.IslandPress,WashingtonDC.
Orford,S.,2000.Modellingspatialstructuresinlocalhousingmarketdynamics:a multi-levelperspecitive.UrbanStud.13(9),1643–1671.
Orford,S.,2010.Towardsadata-richinfrastructureforhousing-marketresearch: derivingfloor-areaestimatesforindividualpropertiesfromsecondarydata sources.Environ.Plan.B:Plan.Des.37(2),248–264.
Petrella, F.,1988. HenryGeorgeandtheclassicalscientificresearchprogram:
George’smodificationofitandhisrealsignificanceforfuturegenerations.Am. J.Econ.Sociol.47(3),371–384.
Pigou,A.C.,1920.TheEconomicsofWelfare,4thed.Macmillan,London.
Rasbash,J.,Steele,F.,Browne,W.J.,Goldstein,H.,2012.AUser’sGuidetoMLwiN, v2.26.CentreforMultilevelModelling,UniversityofBristol,Bristol,UK.
Ricardo,D.,1891.PrinciplesofPoliticalEconomyandTaxation.G.BellandSons, London.
Rosen,S.,1974.Hedonicpricesandimplicitmarkets:productdifferentiationinpure competition.J.Polit.Econ.82(1),34–55.
Ryan, S., 1999. Property values and transportation facilities: finding the
transportation-landuseconnection.J.Plan.Lit.13(4),412–427.
Rybeck,R.,2004.Usingvaluecapturetofinanceinfrastructureandencourage com-pactdevelopment.PublicWorksManag.Policy8(4),249–260.
Short,B.,1997.LandandSocietyinEdwardianBritain.CambridgeUniversityPress, Cambridge.
Smith,A.,1863.AnInquiryintotheNatureandCausesoftheWealthofNations.A. andC.Black,London.
Smith,J.J.,Gihring,T.A.,2006.Financingtransitsystemsthroughvaluecapture.Am. J.Econ.Sociol.65(3),751–786.
TheTelegraph,2012.GeorgeOsborneMayHavetoRaiseVATto25%toBalance
the Budget, Retrieved from: http://www.telegraph.co.uk/news/uknews/
9701989/IFS-George-Osborne-may-have-to-raise-VAT-to-25-to-balance-the-budget.html(17.05.13).
TheUKParliament,1990.TownandCountryPlanningAct.
TheUKParliament,2008.PlanningAct.
TheUKParliament,2012.LandValueTaxBill.
Tideman,T.N.,1982.Ataxonlandvalueisneutral.Natl.TaxJ.35(1),109–111.
WalesOnline,2012.CardiffBusFaresCouldRiseforSecondTimeinFourMonths,
Retrieved from:
http://yourcardiff.walesonline.co.uk/2012/02/27/cardiff-bus-could-rise-for-second-time-in-four-months/(18.05.12).
Wenzer,K.C.,2000.Land-valueTaxation:TheEquitableandEfficientSourceofPublic Finance.MESharpe,NewYork.
Wildasin,D.E.,1982.Moreontheneutralityoflandtaxation.Natl.TaxJ.35(1), 105–108.
Wyatt,M.D.,1994.Acriticalviewoflandvaluetaxationasaprogressivestrategyfor urbanrevitalization,rationallanduse,andtaxrelief.Rev.Radic.Polit.Econ.26, 1–25.