• No results found

Exchange rates, capital, output and debt when nominal interest rates are policy parameters

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2020

Share "Exchange rates, capital, output and debt when nominal interest rates are policy parameters"

Copied!
23
0
0

Loading.... (view fulltext now)

Full text

(1)

The Economic and Social Review, Vol. 22, No. 1, October, 1990, pp. 1-23

Exchange Rates, Capital, Output and Debt

When Nominal Interest Rates are Policy

Parameters

P.J.N. S I N C L A I R *

Brasenose College, Oxford and Queen's University, Canada

I I N T R O D U C T I O N

R

ecent years have witnessed a growing number o f attempts t o reduce i n f l a t i o n by a p o l i c y o f raising n o m i n a l interest rates. Since 1988, such measures have been particularly pronounced i n Australia, Canada and the U n i t e d K i n g d o m . I t is i m p o r t a n t t o ask h o w higher interest rates can help t o lower i n f l a t i o n , w h a t factors determine the speed and reliability o f the mechanisms involved, and, above a l l , w h a t the side-effects o f such policies may be.

The purpose o f this paper is t o explore various mechanisms t h r o u g h w h i c h n o m i n a l interest rates may affect the course o f i n f l a t i o n , i n the c o n t e x t o f an open economy m o d e l where exchange rates are freely floating. The m a i n focus o f a t t e n t i o n is u p o n h o w o u t p u t and income react, i n the short r u n and the l o n g , to a change i n the n o m i n a l rate o f interest. This calls for an e x p l i c i t treatment o f the markets for capital and labour, as well as for m o n e y . None of these markets is assumed to clear instantaneously. I n t e r n a t i o n a l capital m o b i l i t y , and the authorities' a b i l i t y t o influence the e v o l u t i o n o f the n o m i n a l

Dublin Economics Workshop Guest Lecture, Fourth Annual Conference of the Irish Economics Associ­ ation, Kilkenny, 18-20 May 1990.

(2)

m o n e y stock, are b o t h taken t o be qualified rather than perfect.This paper aims t o incorporate i m p o r t a n t features o f the w o r l d i n t o the story. The task o f keeping matters as simple as possible has necessitated a somewhat cavalier treat­ ment o f m i c r o f o u n d a t i o n s . Rational expectations and optimising behaviour are n o t w h o l l y absent, b u t play a l i m i t e d role. The c o m p l e x i t y o f the m o d e l makes i t appropriate to concentrate chiefly o n the impact and steady-state effects o f p o l i c y changes, b u t there is some discussion o f the character o f the transition between t h e m .

I n f l a t i o n cannot persist indefinitely w i t h o u t some accommodating increases i n the n o m i n a l money supply. To the extent that sustained i n f l a t i o n depends u l t i m a t e l y o n the g r o w t h rate o f the n o m i n a l stock o f m o n e y , this paper argues that there are t w o possible routes f r o m a higher n o m i n a l rate o f interest to slower i n f l a t i o n . One takes the f o r m o f a negative effect from the real rate of interest o n the rate o f monetary g r o w t h . We m i g h t t h i n k o f the central bank b u y i n g indexed bonds, for example: such open market operations w o u l d tend t o exert d o w n w a r d pressure on real interest rates and, at least tempor­ a r i l y , raise the n o m i n a l m o n e y g r o w t h rate. Some commentators have argued that the great post-World War I I i n f l a t i o n is u l t i m a t e l y traceable to central bank attempts t o h o l d interest rates d o w n i n the 1950s and 1960s. T o this " W i c k s e l l i a n " view we may add a second, rival account o f h o w higher interest rates c o u l d depress m o n e y g r o w t h . This postulates that the money market need n o t clear instantaneously. I n accordance w i t h the monetary approach to the balance o f payments, or the buffer stock theory o f m o n e y , money demand and m o n e y supply may t e m p o r a r i l y diverge. A n increase i n the n o m i n a l rate o f interest should l o w e r money demand. I f an excess supply of money results, the money supply g r o w t h rate may shrink. A different, b u t similar agument is t r a d i t i o n a l l y p r o p o u n d e d by the Bank o f England: c u t t i n g the g r o w t h o f monetary aggregates calls for r e d u c t i o n i n the g r o w t h of banks' assets, and this i n t u r n requires a higher rate o f interest to cut the demand for loans and advances. I n this paper, b o t h mechanisms are allowed for.

(3)

wage rates i n the face o f u n e m p l o y m e n t , b u t boosted b y d o w n w a r d pressure on the exchange rate.

The paper is organised as follows. Section I I discusses a number o f features o f standard simple exchange rate models w h i c h appear at variance w i t h the facts o f the w o r l d , and i n need o f m o d i f i c a t i o n . Section I I I then proceeds t o lay o u t the equations o f a m o d e l designed t o reflect those concerns, and i n w h i c h , i n particular, the domestic n o m i n a l interest rate becomes a p o l i c y parameter. Section I V examines the long-run solutions o f the m o d e l i n the steady state. I n Section V , a t t e n t i o n switches t o the i m p a c t effects o n the key variables o f interest, and t o the t r a n s i t i o n . Section V I offers some i m p o r ­ tant qualifications and concludes.

I I SOME F A C T O R S T H A T A M O D E L O F F L O A T I N G R A T E S N E E D S T O T A K E I N T O A C C O U N T

Standard exchange rate models that allow for sluggish price adjustment (such as Dornbusch (1976) and Buiter and M i l l e r (1981)) have many virtues. B u t some o f their features are controversial. Here is a list o f nine respects i n w h i c h there is a case f o r seeking t o generalise t h e m :

(a) The n o m i n a l m o n e y supply is treated as a p o l i c y parameter, that can be set costlessly b y the authorities at any desired level. This assump­ t i o n was regarded as innocuous i n the 1970s. B u t the 1980s saw a major shift away from m o n e t a r y targetry towards interest rate mani­ p u l a t i o n i n m a n y financial centres. The collapse, i n 1 9 8 2 , o f the Fed's N e w Operating Procedures w h i c h had been i n t r o d u c e d i n 1979, is perhaps the most celebrated example o f this.

(b) Factor markets are o n l y i m p l i c i t i n the standard models. There is a need to incorporate markets for capital and labour, and hence pro­ d u c t i o n functions. Once money wage rates make their appearance, i t seems desirable t o a l l o w for possible (at least partial) i n d e x a t i o n , and also hysteresis effects that associate m o n e y wage g r o w t h t o the rate of change, and n o t j u s t the level, o f u n e m p l o y m e n t .

(c) The standard models treat " n a t u r a l o u t p u t " , or productive p o t e n t i a l , as exogenous, and t y p i c a l l y constant over t i m e . O n the other hand, aggregate demand is deemed t o fall as interest rates rise. The p r o b l e m here is that i f i t is investment t h a t responds to interest rates, and natural o u t p u t varies w i t h the stock o f capital, natural o u t p u t m u s t become endogenous.

(4)

m o n e y demand, and, perhaps, money wage rates reacts, needs t o dis­ play a l i n k w i t h the home currency value o f foreign goods prices. A t one extreme, one m i g h t wish t o allow the possibility o f inertia i n the c o n s u m p t i o n real wage rate, for instance.

(e) I n t e r n a t i o n a l capital m o b i l i t y is deemed to be perfect. I t seems wise t o allow this t o be high b u t f i n i t e , and n o t necessarily i n f i n i t e . (f) The interest p a r i t y c o n d i t i o n is generally assumed independent o f

the home country's net foreign asset p o s i t i o n . B u t countries deep i n external debt may have t o offer a p r e m i u m on their interest rates. (g) The trade balance is o n l y i m p l i c i t , and the role o f net interest, profits

and dividends i n the current account o f the balance o f payments is ignored. There is a case for m o d e l l i n g the trade account e x p l i c i t l y , and adding net interest flows t o i t .

(h) When f o r w a r d exchange rates are i n t r o d u c e d , the p r e m i u m o n f o r w a r d foreign currency is taken t o reflect agents' expectations o f the spot exchange rate d r i f t perfectly. B u t bankers often claim that f o r w a r d foreign exchange premia are aligned o n interest differentials (to t h w a r t arbitrage), rather than the reverse, and particularly so i n the thinner and longer markets.

(i) The price o f (domestically produced) goods is assumed sluggish, to reflect sluggishness i n money wage rates that are o n l y i m p l i c i t . I n practice, there seems m u c h to be said for the view that goods prices adjust faster than money wage rates, and some case for e x p l o r i n g the idea that goods prices are " j u m p " variables while money wage rates are n o t . " M e n u costs" appear to be most serious i n labour markets.

What follows is a m o d e l that tries t o extend the standard story t o allow for these nine issues.

I l l T H E M O D E L

The m o d e l proposed here consists o f fifteen equations. Unless specified to the c o n t r a r y , upper case R o m a n letters refer to levels o f variables, and lower case t o their natural logarithms, while Greek l o w e r case letters denote par­ ameters. A n overdot is a time derivative. A n asterisk denotes overseas, w i t h the value o f the variable defined i n foreign currency. Overbars and tildes are defined as they occur.

(5)

Q ( t ) = Q ( t ) + K ( t ) + B ( t ) + e ( ms- md) (2)

c o n s u m p t i o n : Q ( t ) + e ( ms- md) e > 0.

K ( t ) = 0 K ( p - R ) = 0 ( a Q ( t ) - R K ( t ) ) (3)

d > 0. p : rate o f p r o f i t (= a Q / K f r o m p r o d u c t i o n f u n c t i o n ( 9 ) ) .

B ( t ) = ^ c ( t ) - 02( Q ( t ) - Q ( t ) ) - R Z ( t ) (4)

j3j,|32 > 0. Z ( t ) : net overseas debts (real).

" d W = + " i ^ O - T ? 2r + P W + U - ^ M O (5)

p = 0p + ( l - 0 ) ( p * + s ) = p + ( l - 0 ) c • (6)

(c(t) = p * ( t ) + s(t) - p ( t ) ) .

Q ( t ) = Y K ^ ^ N1- " (7)

Q(°°) = Y Ka( ° ° ) N1-a (8)

Q ( t ) = Y K ^ t j N W1- " (9)

w - p = l n ( l - a ) + q - n = I n ( l - a ) + ( y + a ( k - q ) ) / ( l - a ) (10)

w - p : l o g p r o d u c t real wage; k , n logs o f current capital and e m p l o y m e n t ; y : l o g technology index.

w ( t ) = w0( t ) + / c j ( p ( t ) + ( l - 0 ) c ( t ) ) + K2n ( t ) (11)

K j : i n d e x a t i o n coefficient; K 2 : hysteresis coefficient.

1 > KL > 0; K2 > 0.

w0( t ) = (1-Kl)n + 6 ( n ( t ) - n ) (12)

£(t) = f ( r - r * - f ( t ) -7Z ( t ) ) (13)

f > 0. f = f o r w a r d p r e m i u m on foreign exchange.

f ( t ) = + x ( c ( - ) - c ( t ) ) ) + ( l - X ) ( r - r * - T ? ( t ) ) (14)

(6)

B ( t ) + £ ( t ) = 0. (15)

E q u a t i o n (1) describes the e v o l u t i o n o f the money supply. I t specifies the g r o w t h rate o f the n o m i n a l money supply ( Ms; ms i n logs) i n terms o f the real rate o f interest, R, and the money market disequilibrium (as reflected by the difference between ms and md, the l o g a r i t h m o f n o m i n a l money demand). E q u a t i o n (2) closely resembles the short-run money demand g r o w t h equation postulated, and very successfully estimated for the U n i t e d States, by Baba, H e n d r y and Starr (1990). The disequilibrium term is an error correction mechanism. I t captures the idea that money supply g r o w t h rises when there is excess demand for m o n e y , and more slowly i n the presence o f excess supply. The money supply g r o w t h rate is assumed to fall i f the real interest rate goes u p ; as we shall see later, t h a t w i l l happen f o l l o w i n g a rise i n the n o m i n a l rate of interest. So (1) is b u i l t on the n o t i o n that raising the n o m i n a l rate o f interest w i l l succeed i n c u t t i n g money supply g r o w t h , at least i n the long r u n .

E q u a t i o n (2) defines the level o f real aggregate demand ( Q ( t ) at date t ) . This consists o f domestic c o n s u m p t i o n and investment spending (the latter equals K ( t ) : capital does n o t depreciate, so that gross and net investment are equal, and government current and capital spending, i f any, is aggregated w i t h the private sector's) and the current account surplus, B ( t ) . Consumption spending is modelled as current natural o u t p u t w i t h the current value of the capital stock ( Q ( t ) ) , w h i c h is a m y o p i c f o r m o f permanent income. ( I t is m y o p i c i n that households are n o t assumed to l o o k ahead to future levels o f natural o u t p u t when the capital stocks may differ.) Consumption is also assumed t o react to money market d i s e q u i l i b r i u m .

Investment is given by E q u a t i o n (3). Here I f o l l o w T o b i n ( 1 9 6 9 ) . Invest­ ment is taken t o be p r o p o r t i o n a l t o the gap between the current rate o f p r o f i t (the marginal p r o d u c t o f capital, derived f r o m the Cobb-Douglas p r o d u c t i o n f u n c t i o n ) and the real rate o f interest. E q u a t i o n (4) presents the current account surplus, B ( t ) , w h i c h includes real interest income on net overseas assets ( - R Z ( t ) ) , and the trade surplus. The trade surplus is deemed to be linear i n t w o variables — the log o f competitiveness (c(t)), and the difference between current real aggregate demand, Q ( t ) , and its current e q u i l i b r i u m value of natural o u t p u t , Q ( t ) . This gap can be thought of as the imbalance i n the p r o d u c t market.

(7)

Equations (7), (8) and (9) all give different p r o d u c t i o n functions for out­ p u t . A l l are based o n the Cobb-Douglas, i n constant returns f o r m . E q u a t i o n

(7) defines current productive p o t e n t i a l i n terms o f current capital ( K ( t ) ) , and the supply o f labour, N , w h i c h is taken t o be stationary and exogenous. E q u a t i o n (9) relates actual current o u t p u t t o current capital and current e m p l o y m e n t , N ( t ) . The demand for labour and the supply o f labour can differ. By contrast, (8) describes long r u n productive p o t e n t i a l , Q(°°), w h i c h relates o u t p u t i n the l o n g r u n t o the long-run capital stock, K(°°) and the supply o f labour N .

Various features o f the labour m a r k e t appear i n the n e x t three equations, (10), (11) and (12). E q u a t i o n (10) defines the p r o d u c t real wage c o n f r o n t i n g producers, o n the assumption o f perfect c o m p e t i t i o n . I n (11), the money wage rate ( w ( t ) at t i n logs) has a core element, wQ (t), and may also vary w i t h the expenditure price index t o allow for possible i n d e x a t i o n , and w i t h the level o f e m p l o y m e n t . This last t e r m introduces a possible hysteresis effect. Hysteresis i n the labour market is m o d e l l e d most simply by the n o t i o n that the rate o f increase i n money wage rates may vary w i t h the rate of change, and n o t j u s t the level, o f u n e m p l o y m e n t . I f this relationship is linear, i t can be integrated i n t o a l i n k between the levels o f the money wage and employ­ ment. Finally, (12) gives the dynamics o f the core element o f the money wage rate, i n terms o f domestic goods price i n f l a t i o n (ir) and the excess supply o f labour, n - n ( t ) i n logs.

The last three equations r e t u r n t o external aspects o f the system. Equa­ t i o n (13) gives the net i n f l o w o f international capital, the surplus o n the capital account o f the balance o f payments. The parameter f reflects the interest-elasticity o f capital flows. I t embraces the standard case o f perfect international capital m o b i l i t y at one extreme (f = °°) as well as t o t a l i m m o b i l i t y at the other (f = 0). The parameter 7 captures, i n the simplest linear fashion, the risk p r e m i u m coefficient t o be attached to a c o u n t r y w i t h a negative net foreign asset p o s i t i o n . The variable f ( t ) is the f o r w a r d p r e m i u m on foreign exchange, w h i c h is defined by (14). Here, the parameter X denotes the extent t o w h i c h the f o r w a r d p r e m i u m is governed by expectations o f relative i n f l a t i o n and the e v o l u t i o n o f competitiveness. I n the standard models, X is set i m p l i c i t l y at u n i t y . But (14) allows X t o fall below u n i t y , t o reflect the "bankers' s t o r y " described i n p o i n t (h) above: according t o that account, f o r w a r d rates are simply aligned on interest differentials. Lastly, (15) states that the exchange rate is freely floating w i t h no i n t e r v e n t i o n o n the part o f the authorities (other than i n the f o r m o f interest rate m a n i p u l a t i o n ) .

I V L O N G R U N A N A L Y S I S

(8)

i n the n o m i n a l rate o f interest. I n the long r u n , the gap between the supply of labour and the demand for labour ( n - n ) disappears. So does that between aggregate demand ( Q ( t ) ) and long-run productive p o t e n t i a l (Q(°°)). The capital stock adjusts t o set the rate o f p r o f i t equal t o the real rate o f interest. So K vanishes, as does Z .

I t follows that the m o n e y supply g r o w t h rate, rh, equals the rate o f infla­ t i o n . There is no d r i f t i n technology, labour supply or capital, so that Q(°°) is stationary. Because (1) implies that

m = ~ M r - w )

once the m o n e y m a r k e t imbalance vanishes, the rate o f i n f l a t i o n settles d o w n

to ( M0- M1r ) / ( 1_M1) , and the real interest rate t o ( r - j u0) / ( l - j U j ) . Since

1 > ^1 b y assumption, i n f l a t i o n and m o n e y g r o w t h b o t h decrease i n the n o m i n a l interest rate, and the real rate o f interest increases i n the n o m i n a l rate.

The increased n o m i n a l rate o f interest therefore raises the real rate o f interest. This means that the long-run stock of capital, and hence the long-run level of o u t p u t , b o t h d r o p . K = Oimplies, f r o m (2), t h a t a Q ( ° ° ) = R K ( ° ° ) . Hence

K ( ~ ) = N C a Y / R ^ / U - o O and Q(°°) = Y ^ a Y / R )0"1"0 0' . T u r n i n g t o the ex­

ternal variables, begin b y c o m b i n i n g (13) and (14) to y i e l d

Z ( t ) = r X ( r - r * - 7 Z ( t ) - r r + 7 T * -X( c ( a ) - c ( t ) ) ) (16)

N e x t define R*, the foreign real rate o f interest, as r*-n*, and set c ( t ) equal to c(°°). N o w make Z vanish, as i t must i n the steady state. E q u a t i o n (16) n o w furnishes solutions for the long-run values of net debts, Z , and the l o g a r i t h m of competitiveness: Z = ( R - R * ) / ? and c(°°) = RZ/(3j). This implies that our increased n o m i n a l rate o f interest w i l l serve to raise net overseas debts and depress the real exchange rate i n the long r u n . (The first o f these results always happens; the second, p r o v i d e d only that the domestic real interest rate is at least half as great as the overseas real rate, a c o n d i t i o n guaranteed unless the home c o u n t r y has sufficiently large net overseas assets.) The reasoning for this is clear: a higher n o m i n a l interest rate attracts capital f r o m overseas, as w e l l as m a k i n g existing debts more expensive t o service. So i t tends to drive d o w n the real exchange rate i n the long r u n , i n order to generate the neces­ sary trade balance i m p r o v e m e n t required t o make r o o m for the enhanced debt servicing costs.

Figure 1 illustrates some o f these relationships. The lower r i g h t quadrant

depicts the negative l i n k between TI and r. This line slopes up given that

1 > j U j , w i t h a gradient o f n1l(l~n1 ). The lower left quadrant portrays the

(9)

Figure 1: The Long-Run Links Between Nominal and Real Interest Rates, Inflation, and Domestic and National Product.

Q - R Z [ = G N P ]

/ Q[=GDP]

/ /

Q (output); Q - R Z (national income)

/

/

//

R *

R (real rate of interest) r (nominal rate

of interest)

/

/

(10)

gradient o f - (1-Mj )• I n the upper left quadrant the negative influence o f the real rate o f interest o n long-run domestic p r o d u c t , Q(°°), appears as an un­ b r o k e n curve, while that for national p r o d u c t ( Q ( ° ° ) - R Z ) as a b r o k e n one. The t w o curves intersect where R = R * , since at this p o i n t net overseas debts, and hence debt servicing costs, vanish. C o m b i n i n g these three relationships r u n n i n g f r o m the n o m i n a l rate o f interest.to domestic p r o d u c t establishes a d o w n w a r d sloping curve, w h i c h presents itself i n the upper right quadrant. Its elasticity is - a r / ( l - a ) ( l - j U j ) ( r - j uQ) .

These long-run effects o f a permanent rise i n the home country's n o m i n a l rate o f interest are essentially ceteris paribus. That is t o say, that is w h a t happens w h e n other variables are kept fixed. I n particular, the values o f f iQ

(the constant t e r m o n the m o n e y g r o w t h equation) and R * (the foreign real rate o f interest) have been h e l d constant. There are t w o i m p o r t a n t cases where some o f the effects o f a higher n o m i n a l rate o f interest are neutralised. One o f these arises w h e n the j u m p i n domestic interest rates matches rises i n over­ seas rates. Suppose R * increases, once and for all, by a given a m o u n t , and that r is raised enough t o bring R up by the same a m o u n t , so that R = R * through­ o u t . I n this case, none o f the external effects materialise. N e t overseas debts, and the real exchange rate remain unchanged. B u t the internal effects con­ tinue t o operate. I n f l a t i o n drops. The real cost o f capital facing domestic firms has risen. So the domestic stock o f capital keeps d w i n d l i n g u n t i l the rate o f p r o f i t has climbed up to i t . O u t p u t ( b o t h domestic and national, for they are equal n o w ) must also go d o w n as a result o f the squeeze o n capital.

I n the second case, neither the internal nor the external repercussions o f the higher domestic n o m i n a l interest rate arise. This is so, at least, for the

real variables i n the system. T h a t is the p o s i t i o n when the j u m p i n the home

1 n o m i n a l rate o f interest offsets a parallel rise i n nQ, the autonomous intercept

on the money supply g r o w t h equation. I n that event, the real rate o f interest stays unchanged. So there is n o alteration i n the e q u i l i b r i u m values o f capital or natural o u t p u t , and no effect, either, o n long-run competitiveness or net indebtedness. There is some effect, however, o n the n o m i n a l variables. The steady state rate o f i n f l a t i o n rises by the increase i n I t w o u l d have gone up still more had r n o t increased. The n o m i n a l exchange rate w i l l depreciate faster, or appreciate slower, to match the higher domestic i n f l a t i o n rate. B u t , as (16) testifies, n o t h i n g happens t o the capital account o f the balance o f payments, at least i n the longer r u n , since the changes i n r and TT offset each other exactly. On the other hand, had the level o f r been raised enough to keep i n f l a t i o n constant, the real r a t e ' o f interest w o u l d have gone up, w i t h qualitative effects o n the real variables i n the system resembling w h a t hap­ pened i n the i n i t i a l case where j uQ and R* were given.

(11)

eco-n o m y models. The classic paper to display a positive loeco-ng-rueco-n l i eco-n k betweeeco-n the rate o f m o n e y g r o w t h and the level o f real o u t p u t is T o b i n ( 1 9 6 5 ) . There, faster m o n e y g r o w t h tilts p o r t f o l i o s i n favour o f real as opposed t o financial assets, and stimulates savings, so that the capital-output r a t i o rises and the real rate o f interest declines. Hence, a r e d u c t i o n i n steady state i n f l a t i o n is associated w i t h a rise i n the real interest rate and a squeeze o n o u t p u t . The o n l y difference between our results and Tobin's is the fact that T o b i n makes the rate o f n o m i n a l m o n e y g r o w t h the key p o l i c y parameter, while the n o m i n a l rate o f interest is assumed independent o f the rate o f i n f l a t i o n . I n the present m o d e l , o f course, m o n e y supply g r o w t h is endogenous, and i n f l a t i o n is governed, i n the long r u n , by the n o m i n a l rate o f interest.

I n the O p t i m u m Q u a n t i t y o f M o n e y family o f models that begin w i t h Friedman ( 1 9 6 9 ) , o n the other hand, the real rate o f interest is generally governed independently o f monetary variables by the forces o f demography, p r o d u c t i v i t y and t h r i f t . The n o m i n a l rate o f interest diverges f r o m i t by an a m o u n t necessarily equal to expected i n f l a t i o n , i f foresight is perfect. I n a steady state that obeys the golden r u l e , the n o m i n a l interest rate equals the rate o f money g r o w t h ; and the latter is o f course taken t o be exogenous. When labour supply is endogenous i n a Ramsey-type m o d e l o f i n t e r t e m p o r a l o p t i m i s a t i o n w i t h m o n e y , faster m o n e y g r o w t h t y p i c a l l y lowers o u t p u t . I f the government finances its spending f r o m seignorage and other forms o f distortionary t a x a t i o n , as i n Poterba and Rotemberg ( 1 9 9 0 ) or Sinclair ( 1 9 9 0 ) , the door is left ajar for the possibility that o u t p u t and i n f l a t i o n rise together i n the long r u n , so l o n g as the rate o f i n f l a t i o n is l o w enough. B u t a l o w n o m i n a l interest rate is always associated w i t h l o w money g r o w t h . The benefits o f p l e n t i f u l real balances to w h i c h i t gives rise are the r e w a r d for sus­ tained abstinence i n the money g r o w t h rate. A high n o m i n a l interest rate indicates r a p i d i n f l a t i o n . I t is n o t a device for reducing i t . This is essentially the view that predominates, also, i n recent w o r k on interest rate targeting, such as Barro ( 1 9 8 9 ) .

I n practice, the n o m i n a l interest rate is b o t h an i n d i c a t o r o f anticipated i n f l a t i o n and an instrument for c u t t i n g actual i n f l a t i o n . The t e r m structure o f interest rates provides a f o r u m w i t h i n w h i c h this paradox can be resolved. A d o w n w a r d sloping y i e l d curve on unindexed bonds, for example, can p o i n t t o t i g h t monetary p o l i c y being applied n o w t o cut i n f l a t i o n , a p o l i c y t h a t agents believe w i l l succeed. Nearly all the existing literature concentrates o n the n o m i n a l interest rate's role as p o i n t e r t o future i n f l a t i o n . Buiter and M i l l e r (1981) is a rare e x c e p t i o n : for t h e m , a high n o m i n a l interest rate generally reflects a reduced m o n e y g r o w t h rate, rather than a high one. I f the present paper errs i n stressing the i n f l a t i o n brake role o f n o m i n a l interest rates too strongly, I can plead that this view requires more exposure and detailed analysis,

(12)

before w o r k can proceed o n a richer m o d e l w i t h an e x p l i c i t t e r m structure

that allows one to study both roles together.

V T H E I M P A C T E F F E C T S

This section moves f r o m the steady state to the impact effects o f an increase i n the n o m i n a l rate o f interest. I shall assume that the n o m i n a l rate is raised once and for a l l , and unexpectedly. Agents have enough knowledge o f the m o d e l to infer the long-run consequences this w i l l have for the real rate and the real exchange rate, c(°°). Investment proceeds according to E q u a t i o n (3) above, subject t o the proviso that R is the steady state real cost o f capital (and n o t r less the current, or anticipated immediate rate o f i n f l a t i o n as cap­ t u r e d b y p ) . This assumption allows us t o c o m p u t e the impact effects o f the rise i n r d i r e c t l y , w i t h o u t having t o solve backwards for the course o f antici­ pated i n f l a t i o n . I n its defence, i t can be said that the absence o f depreciation makes a " p e r m a n e n t " cost o f capital concept a l i t t l e more palatable.

Start w i t h Equations (2) t o (4). T o t a l d i f f e r e n t i a t i o n establishes that

( l - a 0 + j 32) d Q = - ( 0 K + Z ) d R - e d md + ^ d c . (17)

We m a y t h i n k o f (17) as an IS curve i n derivative f o r m . Given that r (and R ) are n o w parametric, i t w o u l d be w r o n g to go o n t o eliminate d R f r o m (17) to establish an expression for aggregate demand, as one w o u l d w i t h Dornbusch (1976) for example. What has to be eliminated f r o m (17) is the money demand t e r m (we have assumed, i n deriving ( 1 7 ) , that the money supply level was n o t affected i m m e d i a t e l y by the higher r ) . E q u a t i o n (5) implies

d md = 171 dq - i ?2d r + dp + ( l - 0 ) d c . ( 1 8 )

» The short r u n supply side o f the system can be gleaned f r o m (10) and ( 1 1 ) . They i m p l y

( 1 - Kx) d p = d q + K l( l - 0 ) d c . \l9)

Meanwhile, the key competitiveness — o u t p u t — interest rate links can be set out f r o m ( 4 ) , (15) and ( 1 6 ) , w h i c h together y i e l d

(0X +xfX)dc = 02d Q + ( Z - f A ) d R + x f X d c M . (20 )

N e x t , recall the long-run results f r o m Section I V . These tell us that d R =

2 R - R *

(13)

(20) i n terms o f Q and r alone, w h i l e (17)-(19) can be c o m b i n e d t o eliminate

dp and d md and o b t a i n a second equation l i n k i n g c to Q and r. Remember

that the price o f domestically produced goods is a j u m p variable, n o t a pre­ determined sluggard as i n Dornbusch ( 1 9 7 6 ) . The end result is a system

d Q dc dp _dp_

w h i c h gives the i m p a c t effects u p o n the domestic goods price level, p , and the domestic expenditure price index, p , as w e l l as domestic o u t p u t and the

real exchange rate. I n ( 2 1 ) , A} = ( x5- X j X4) / ( 1 - J U j ) ( j 32X j + x2+ x3) ; A2 =

( p ^ + x j a - M j V C ^ + x r X ) ; A3 = A1(a+ K2) / Q ( l - a ) ( l - K1) + A ^ f l - * ) /

(1-K j ) and A4 = A3 + A2 ( 1 - 0 ) ; and X j t o x5 are defined as:

= e ( l - 0 ) / ( l -K l) - p x

x2 = 1-aO + j32

a + K2

6 Q ( l - a ) ( l -K l)

x4 = Z - f X ( l -x( 2 R - R * ) / V )

x5 = er)2(l-vl) - OK - Z .

The immediate impression one gains f r o m inspecting (21) is t h a t p r e t t y well a n y t h i n g can happen. This is true. Domestic o u t p u t , competitiveness, and the price level — w i t h or w i t h o u t the foreign goods — can go up or d o w n on i m p a c t f o l l o w i n g a j u m p i n the n o m i n a l rate o f interest. B u t the results are easier to understand and i n t e r p r e t than may seem at first sight.

Begin w i t h A j , the coefficient that tells us h o w domestic o u t p u t reacts t o the higher n o m i n a l rate o f interest. There are five channels o f influence r u n ­ n i n g f r o m r t o Q:

(a) via investment, K

(b) via debt charges and competitiveness

(14)

(c) via capital inflows and competitiveness

(d) f r o m foreseen steady state competitiveness to competitiveness n o w (the c(°°) t e r m )

(e) via the imbalance i n the m o n e y market created by higher r. This chan­ nel can be subdivided i n t o :

(e(i)): a direct c o n s u m p t i o n effect

(e(ii)): an i n d i r e c t consumption effect r u n n i n g f r o m debt charges to competitiveness and the expenditure price index

(e(iii)): as (e(ii)), b u t originating from the change i n capital i n f l o w (e(iv)): as (e(ii)), b u t originating f r o m the foreseen change i n steady

state competitiveness.

Each o f these channels needs t o be explained i n t u r n . Channel (a) is simple. The higher n o m i n a l interest rate betokens a permanently higher real cost o f capital. T h a t n o w stands above the current rate o f p r o f i t , i f they were pre­ v i o u s l y equal. So there w i l l be d o w n w a r d pressure on investment, depressing

aggregate demand i n the short r u n . Channel (b) squeezes aggregate demand directly i f the c o u n t r y has net foreign debts: a higher real interest rate o n these debts worsens the current account o f the balance o f payments. Chan­ nel (c) is also straightforward. Higher interest attracts capital f r o m abroad, i m p r o v i n g the capital account o f the balance o f payments at the previous exchange rate: and, since there is free floating, the spot exchange rate should tend t o appreciate. The consequent r e d u c t i o n i n competitiveness worsens the trade balance and squeezes aggregate demand. Channel (d) is a l i t t l e harder to grasp. We k n o w that the higher interest rate w i l l increase the country's net overseas debts, and that servicing them w i l l call u l t i m a t e l y for a lower real exchange rate i n order to generate the necessary improvement i n the trade balance. We k n o w this; and the agents i n the m o d e l are also assumed to k n o w this. So, depending o n the magnitude of--the parameter x (which is the coef­ ficient on the current/long-run exchange rate discrepancy i n the f o r w a r d p r e m i u m equation, ( 1 4 ) ) , there w i l l have t o be some negative pressure on the real exchange rate n o w i n a n t i c i p a t i o n o f the long-run effect. A n y tendency for depreciation n o w qualifies, or even reverses, the mechanism o u t l i n e d for channel ( c ) : the trade balance improves, and aggregate demand recovers.

We n o w get to the most intricate part o f the story, the various effects operating under channel (e). The central idea is that domestic expenditure is boosted w h e n there is an excess supply o f m o n e y . This is not the same t h i n g as a real balance effect, which w o u l d make consumption react t o m - p or m - p . N o w a j u m p i n the n o m i n a l rate o f interest cuts money demand

(15)

finally on aggregate demand via c o n s u m p t i o n , b u t the way i n w h i c h they generate changes i n excess money balances differs. A l l o f them affect the excess supply o f money t h r o u g h the price level. So e(ii), w h i c h induces d o w n ­ w a r d pressure on the exchange rate i f the c o u n t r y has negative net overseas assets, acts t o squeeze c o n s u m p t i o n by boosting the price level (expenditure d e f i n i t i o n , p ) and m a k i n g for an excess demand for m o n e y . The same happens w i t h e(iv): the expectation o f higher future debt charges acts t o depress the exchange rate n o w , w i t h similar consequences. B u t e(iii) runs i n the opposite d i r e c t i o n : a capital i n f l o w worsens competitiveness, t r i m m i n g p and m a k i n g for an excess supply o f m o n e y . None o f these four mechanisms under the (e) heading operates i f e vanishes. Effect e(ii) is the excess money balances counter­ part o f channel ( b ) , e(iii) o f channel (c), and e(iv) o f channel (d).

The next task is to i d e n t i f y each o f these effects and channels w i t h par­ ticular terms i n Ax, the coefficient for dQ i n (21). Channel (a) can be p i n ­ p o i n t e d as the - OK term i n xg. I t is clear that this imparts a negative influence on Q. Channel (b) operates t h r o u g h the - Z t e r m i n x5, again an unambigu­ ously negative effect;1 this is qualified, b u t never reversed, by the p r o d u c t o f Z i n x4 w i t h - ( l + x f V ^ i ) ~ 1 t e r m i n X j . Channel (c) is captured by the pro­ duct o f - f X i n x4 and the same term i n X j , and (d) by the p r o d u c t o f t h a t same term i n Xj w i t h the expression xf^(2R-r*)/j3j 7 i n x4. I t is clear that channel (c) imparts a negative influence o f r on Q, and (d) a positive one. F i n a l l y , the (e) channel. This is identifiable t o all terms i n A j that c o n t a i n the parameter e. Effect e(i) operates through the er)2(l-iiy) t e r m i n x5; e(ii) can be traced to the p r o d u c t o f Z i n x4 w i t h the e term i n X j , and e(iii) and e(iv) likewise to the other elements i n x4 m u l t i p l i e d by that term i n X j . We have focused u p o n the numerator o f A j i n this discussion; the denomin­ ator is j u s t the familiar m u l t i p l i e r , w h i c h has t o be positive for stability.

The coefficients A2, A3, and A4, w h i c h tell us h o w competitiveness, and the home country's factor cost and expenditure price indices react t o the higher rate o f interest, are easier t o i n t e r p r e t . The numerator o f A2 contains t w o terms: a direct effect, x4( l - / U j )_ 1, w h i c h we saw operating i n channels (b), (c) and ( d ) , and an i n d i r e c t effect, |32 A j , w h i c h reflects the fact that i f Q rises (falls), the trade balance w i l l worsen ( i m p r o v e ) , so that a cleanly floating exchange rate w i l l have t o depreciate (appreciate). The denominator of A2 reminds us that the magnitude o f all these competitiveness effects w i l l be smaller, the greater the international m o b i l i t y o f capital (the higher is f ) , the more the f o r w a r d rate reflects expectations o f future exchange rate changes (the higher is X) and the faster the process o f convergence on the steady state (the higher is x)- The home goods price index p rises or falls w i t h

(16)

domestic o u t p u t , as the A j t e r m testifies; we can interpret (a+n 2) / ( l - a ) ( l - K t)

as the reciprocal o f the elasticity of aggregate supply. B o t h the i n d e x a t i o n

coefficient K l and the hysteresis coefficient K 2 serve t o make home supply

less price elastic. B u t there is also a second t e r m i n A3, w h i c h reflects the

i n d e x a t i o n l i n k from foreign goods prices i n home currency and the level o f domestic money wage rates. Lastly, the home country's expenditure price index, p , is a l i t t l e more sensitive t o r than p , b y virtue o f the exchange rate

t e r m A2 ( 1 - 0 ) that is added to i t : often, n o t always, A2 and A3 w i l l have the

same sign.

I t is interesting t o examine the roles played i n shaping these results by the exotic parameters w h i c h are absent f r o m simple, standard models. They i n c l u d e :

the interest-sensitivity o f international capital flows

the sensitivity o f the forward p r e m i u m o n foreign exchange t o the expected exchange rate t r e n d

the m o n e y wage i n d e x a t i o n coefficient the m o n e y wage hysteresis coefficient

the coefficient o f the exchange rate d r i f t o n the gap between the cur­ rent and long-run expected exchange rates

the sensitivity o f spending t o excess money the real-interest sensitivity o f money g r o w t h

the sensitivity o f investment t o the p r o f i t / i n t e r e s t gap.

The i m p a c t o f these parameters is as follows. We shall focus a t t e n t i o n on the implications each o f them has for the magnitude and sign o f the short-run effect o f the rate o f interest o n Q, given by the value o f A j i n E q u a t i o n ( 2 1 ) . First, f and X. These t w o parameters have qualitatively identical effects, since they o n l y enter as a p r o d u c t . Greater i n t e r n a t i o n a l capital m o b i l i t y (J) therefore has j u s t the same implications as an increase i n the sensitivity o f the f o r w a r d rate to the expected exchange rate t r e n d (X). The sign o f dQ/dr res­ ponds ambiguously to a rise i n f or X. There are t w o things that matter here. First, whether the exchange rate is driven up or d o w n by the increase i n the rate o f interest. T h a t depends on whether x ( 2 R - R * ) exceeds or falls short o f j 3 j 7 . I f i t exceeds i t , the depressive effect o f the knowledge o f a lower long-run exchange rate — w h i c h has t o d r o p , to improve the trade balance enough to defray the higher debt charges — dominates the direct effect, and depreci­ ation ensues. B u t w i t h l o w enough x , there w i l l be appreciation. The other factor w h i c h matters here is h o w o u t p u t reacts t o an exchange rate change. I f the exchange rate appreciates, competitiveness declines; that hurts the trade balance; and domestic aggregate demand goes d o w n . O n the other hand, appreciation pushes d o w n the cost o f living (since foreign goods become

(17)

cheaper i n domestic currency). I f money wage rates are l i n k e d to the cost o f living by a p o w e r f u l i n d e x a t i o n scheme, this effect w i l l be all the stronger, since the prices o f home produced goods w i l l tend t o be forced d o w n t o o , b u t i t w i l l be present even w i t h o u t i n d e x a t i o n . The drop i n the cost o f living w i l l cut the domestic demand for m o n e y , and that i n t u r n generates an excess supply o f m o n e y i f the m o n e y m a r k e t i n i t i a l l y cleared; and so long as e > 0 that implies higher aggregate demand. The n o r m a l view is that higher interest rates at home induce the exchange rate to appreciate and this w i l l be defla­ t i o n a r y for o u t p u t . I n that case, higher f or X make for an increased l i k e l i h o o d of a negative effect o f r on Q. This w i l l also be so i f the exchange rate falls (in a n t i c i p a t i o n o f those higher future debt charges) and aggregate demand is squeezed by the m o n e y market effects o f higher prices at home. B u t i f either the exchange rate depreciates or appreciation is expansionary for aggregate demand (and o n l y one o f these conditions applies), raising f or X w i l l make d Q / d r likelier to be positive. Finally, f and X also appear o n the denominator of A j ; here, their role is to dampen (enhance) the value o f the m u l t i p l i e r depending o n whether e ( l - 0 ) > ( < ) (3j ( 1 - K j ) .

N e x t , coefficients Kj and K2, w h i c h capture the way money wage rates

respond t o the cost o f living p , and the level o f e m p l o y m e n t . We have termed t h e m the " i n d e x a t i o n " and "hysteresis" coefficients. The i n d e x a t i o n coef­ ficient makes the supply o f domestic goods less elastic. A rise i n the price level gets transmitted i n t o m o n e y wage rates, and so prices rise even further. The i m p l i c a t i o n o f this is that the size o f the m u l t i p l i e r for Q is cut. So m u c h

is plain f r o m one o f the ways K1 enters the denominator o f A1 (in the term

x3 ). T o this extent, K J lowers the size o f | A j |. I t also plays a second role, so

long as e > 0. A higher value o f the i n d e x a t i o n coefficient makes i t likelier that a real exchange rate depreciation cuts o u t p u t , b y raising the price level more — and hence money demand more — than w o u l d have occurred other­ wise. Increased money demand means lower spending, given that e > 0. This effect is evident f r o m the numerator o f A j , and also its denominator.

The hysteresis coefficient, K2, simply makes supply less elastic. A n increase

i n domestic e m p l o y m e n t pushes up wage rates. (The hysteresis effect is more familiar i n the time derivatives, as a l i n k between money wage g r o w t h and

the rate o f change i n u n e m p l o y m e n t . ) So the result o f raising «2 is t o reduce

the size o f the m u l t i p l i e r for Q. This can be seen f r o m its presence i n the x3

term i n the denominator o f A j .

(18)

slowly towards their long-run e q u i l i b r i u m levels. I n our m o d e l , the really i m p o r t a n t effect o f raising the value o f x is t o make depreciation likelier w h e n the interest rate goes u p . This is so because o f the negative long-run l i n k between the rate o f interest and the real exchange rate (higher interest means higher debt charges, hence a larger trade surplus, w h i c h can o n l y be engineered in the l o n g r u n by increasing competitiveness). Higher x strengthens the p u l l of this long-run effect o n the current value o f the exchange rate. That result — higher x makes for an increased change o f depreciation after a j u m p i n interest rates — assumes that the real interest rate at home is no less than half its foreign value. N o w whether an increased chance o f depreciation makes i t likelier that o u t p u t goes up turns o n the relative size o f e ( l - 0 ) - ^ ( l - K j ) , as we saw i n our discussion o f J and X.

The n e x t parameter to consider is e. This gives the sensitivity o f spending to excess m o n e y balances. I f e were zero, a higher rate o f interest w o u l d almost certainly i m p l y a lower level o f Q. The o n l y force tending t o raise out­ put i n such circumstances is the d o w n w a r d pressure on the exchange rate that w o u l d come through a n t i c i p a t i o n o f higher future long-run debt charges. So the chief significance o f e is t o make i t m u c h likelier that a higher rate o f interest has a perverse, positive i m p a c t o n aggregate demand. The simplest

: way this can happen is t h r o u g h r e d u c t i o n i n money demand stemming directly

f r o m the higher rate o f interest (effect (e(i)) above). Higher e also makes i t more probable that depreciation squeezes aggregate demand, as we have seen; and since the exchange rate impact o f higher r is uncertain, the significance of that effect for the sign o f dQ/dr is uncertain.

. N e x t , n j . This coefficient captures the feedback f r o m the real rate o f interest o n the rate o f m o n e y g r o w t h . I t shapes the l i n k between the n o m i n a l and real rates o f interest. Higher jUj means that the long-run i n f l a t i o n rate drops more — and that the real interest rate therefore goes up more — f o l l o w ­ ing a given j u m p i n the n o m i n a l rate. U n l i k e the other parameters considered here, /Xj has i m p o r t a n t long-run implications, and plays o n l y a m i n o r role i n the short r u n . The other parameters have bearing o n l y o n the short r u n .

F i n a l l y , 6, the coefficient i n the investment equation. Increasing the value o f 8 means m a k i n g the capital stock close the gap between the rate o f p r o f i t and the cost o f capital more q u i c k l y . The role o f 0 is a simple one. I t deter­ mines the size o f the direct, negative effect o f a higher rate of interest on aggregate demand r u n n i n g through investment. So higher 6 must make a negative value o f A j likelier.

(19)

We k n o w f r o m Section I V that o u t p u t and capital b o t h have to fall i n the l o n g r u n as a consequence o f a higher rate o f interest. We also k n o w that out­ p u t can rise or fall i n the short r u n . For the transition t o display rising levels o f o u t p u t , i t is sufficient that aggregate demand should decline i n the short r u n by more than i n the long. Is this case o f " o u t p u t o v e r s h o o t i n g " possible? The answer is yes. I t is possible for the j u m p i n the rate o f interest t o force aggregate demand d o w n so m u c h at once that i t then goes up subsequently. A comparison o f the long-run results for Q i n . Section I V w i t h A j i n (21) reveals t h a t this is likeliest w h e n t w o parameters are particularly high (j3j, the derivative o f the trade balance w i t h respect to l o g competitiveness, a n d 0 , the m u l t i p l i c a t i v e constant i n the investment e q u a t i o n ) , given that the exchange rate appreciates i n i t i a l l y . The precise c o n d i t i o n for this to happen simplifies, when b o t h e and x go to zero, t o 00j > 1 - j 3 j f X ( l - a ) / K . I n these c i r c u m ­ stances, the levels o f o u t p u t and e m p l o y m e n t rise over t i m e during the tran­ s i t i o n , while the capital stock shrinks. The fact that e m p l o y m e n t collapses early and climbs back later means that money wage increases fall away very q u i c k l y , and tend t o rise a l i t t l e later. The appreciation i n the exchange rate w h i c h occurs at once, and is subsequently u n w o u n d , also imparts a negative influence o n i n f l a t i o n early and a positive one later. So this is a case where the good and the bad news f r o m the higher rate o f interest are concentrated right at the beginning.

I t is also possible for aggregate demand t o j u m p so m u c h o n i m p a c t that the stock o f capital actually rises i n i t i a l l y . For this t o occur, the positive pres­ sure f r o m higher o u t p u t o n the rate o f p r o f i t must exceed the increase i n the real cost o f capital t o w h i c h the higher rate o f interest gives rise. This state o f affairs is n o t probable, b u t i t can happen. I t is at its likeliest w h e n the interest-elasticity o f money demand is m u c h greater than the income interest-elasticity, aggre­ gate supply is price elastic, and spending is highly sensitive t o excess m o n e y . The exact c o n d i t i o n for investment t o rise i n the short t e r m , i n the face o f the higher rate o f interest, is

a + K„ aA j 02e ( l - 0 )

R T? 1( 1 - / X , ) > T? 9 + — ? + — Y1/ *1" " ) [ 1 + - ^ - ]

'll Mi ; '2 ( 1 - 0 0 ( 1 - * ! ) Re M l " " ! )

when the i n i t i a l value o f Z is zero. The i n t u i t i o n here is n o t hard:.the higher rate o f interest creates a big excess supply o f m o n e y , boosting spending, and the size o f this effect is greatest w h e n money demand is highly interest elastic and spending reacts strongly t o excess m o n e y .

(20)

liable t o delay. The c o n d i t i o n for the capital stock to rise i n i t i a l l y is a great deal more stringent than for a positive i m p a c t effect o n o u t p u t . The latter is necessary b u t n o t sufficient for the former. A variety o f possible time paths for domestic o u t p u t and the stock o f capital are illustrated i n the different panels o f Figure 2.

We have seen t h a t o u t p u t can e x h i b i t overshooting behaviour, changing o n impact by more than is needed t o achieve long-run e q u i l i b r i u m . Is the same true o f the real exchange rate? I t turns o u t that competitiveness can go up on i m p a c t b y more than the long-run e q u i l i b r i u m requires. The idea here is that the higher rate o f interest generates a large excess supply o f money, w h i c h

calls for a high value of T J2, the interest semi-elasticity o f money demand.

Spending then j u m p s sharply. The parameter 02, w h i c h does d u t y for the

"marginal propensity t o i m p o r t " i n standard Keynesian models, is big enough t o ensure a major surge i n i m p o r t s . This imparts negative pressure o n the spot exchange rate, and all the more so i f f and X are small (so that i t is largely the current account o f the balance o f payments, n o t the capital account, that ' determines the exchange rate). For the real exchange rate t o overshoot, the effect j u s t described has to dominate the various other mechanisms at w o r k . When the i n i t i a l value o f Z is zero, real exchange rate overshooting w i l l arise i f and o n l y i f

02e ( W )

/ 32e T? 2( l -Ju1) > 0 K | 32 + r X ( x2+ X 3 ) + ( R /7) [ l - a 0 + x3 + ] .

Pi (1 K-i )

Except i n this strange and somewhat u n l i k e l y case, the real exchange rate depreciates during the transition to long-run e q u i l i b r i u m . This tends to raise the rate o f i n f l a t i o n d u r i n g the t r a n s i t i o n , and especially so when ( 1 - 0 ) , the

expenditure weight for foreign goods, and nl, the i n d e x a t i o n coefficient, are

b o t h large. There is another factor w o r k i n g i n the same d i r e c t i o n . The stock o f capital is shrinking. This exerts u p w a r d pressure on the price level o f domestically p r o d u c e d goods, relative to the money wage rate. However, transitional i n f l a t i o n is l o w e r e d by t w o other mechanisms. U n e m p l o y m e n t is inevitable at some stage i n the transition, and quite likely t h r o u g h o u t i t ; this cuts the g r o w t h o f m o n e y wage rates. A n d the higher rate o f interest leads at once t o an excess supply o f m o n e y . That automatically lowers the

rate o f m o n e y g r o w t h , as long as i t lasts, via parameter f i2.

V I C O N C L U S I O N S A N D Q U A L I F I C A T I O N S

(21)

Figure 2: Various Possible Time Paths for Capital and Domestic Output Following a Rise in the Nominal Rate of Interest 0

K, stock of capital case a: the normal case: Q falls on impact, and Q and K both

fall in the transition

K, stock of capital case b: output overshooting (Q falls on impact by more than

the long run requires, so it recovers during the transition)

K , stock of capital case c: impact effect on Q positive, but Q and K both fall in

the transition

(22)

of direct capital account effects p o i n t i n g i n that direction). I t is also widely believed that the rate o f monetary g r o w t h has negligible long-run real effects i n either open or closed economies.

I n the f r a m e w o r k o f the m o d e l proposed i n this paper, all these propositions become d o u b t f u l , and three o f them are definitely controverted. A higher rate o f interest does n o t boost savings; i f a n y t h i n g , i t tends t o squeeze t h e m , t e m p o r a r i l y , by inducing an excess supply o f m o n e y . The short-run impact of a higher rate o f interest u p o n investment is qualitatively ambiguous: i t is j u s t possible that the j u m p i n c o n s u m p t i o n lifts the rate o f p r o f i t enough t o offset — however briefly — the rise i n the cost o f capital. I f that happens, investment goes up i n i t i a l l y . Far f r o m i m p r o v i n g the current account of the balance o f payments, the higher rate o f interest w i l l almost certainly worsen i t i n the short r u n (it must do so i f the c o u n t r y has negative net overseas assets) t h r o u g h a number o f mechanisms: higher debt charges; pressure o n the exchange rate, w h i c h may well result i n l o w e r competitiveness; the stimulus to consumer spending via excess m o n e y . Recent experience i n Australia and the U n i t e d K i n g d o m , where policies o f high interest rates have failed to lower massive current account balance of payments deficits, or dent private sector spending, seem t o corroborate these findings w e l l . I n the long r u n , a higher rate o f interest w i l l definitely lead to a lower real exchange rate (in order to improve competitiveness enough t o provide the trade surplus that defray the extra overseas debt servicing costs). A n d there are real long-run effects f r o m the p o l i c y o f higher interest rates and lower monetary g r o w t h : an unambigu­ ous decline i n the domestic capital stock, domestic o u t p u t , net overseas assets and national income.

These are among the paper's key findings. What should be said by way o f qualification? The most serious l i m i t a t i o n o f the analysis, i n the author's view, is that we have been l o o k i n g o n l y at the effect o f permanent changes i n the domestic n o m i n a l rate o f interest. A temporary rise i n the interest rate, subsequently undone, should leave no enduring legacy. The fall i n capital and rise i n debt w i l l eventually be reversed. So w i l l the effects i t may have on

the rate o f i n f l a t i o n .

(23)

and o p t i m i s a t i o n t h a t ought t o precede i t . Some o f these shortcomings the author hopes t o s u r m o u n t i n later w o r k .

What this paper has aimed t o do, however, is t o enlarge the standard approach t o open economy macroeconomic and exchange rate m o d e l l i n g by t a k i n g e x p l i c i t account o f several issues o f b o t h theoretical and practical i m p o r t a n c e . These include the need t o move away f r o m treating the m o n e y stock, or its g r o w t h rate, as a p o l i c y parameter, and instead t o regard n o m i n a l interest rates as p o l i c y instruments; the need t o endogenise " n a t u r a l o u t p u t " by i n c o r p o r a t i n g e x p l i c i t factor markets and a mechanism t o drive the dynamics o f the capital stock; the need t o bring hysteresis and i n d e x a t i o n i n t o the behaviour o f wages; and the need t o allow for the possibilities o f less than perfect i n t e r n a t i o n a l capital m o b i l i t y and imperfect foresight i n for­ w a r d foreign exchange markets. We have seen t h a t these various factors can be c o m b i n e d i n a f o r m a l setting, and that the resulting model's i m p l i c a t i o n s differ considerably f r o m those o f standard models.

REFERENCES

B A B Y , Y . , D. H E N D R Y , and R . S T A R R , 1990. "The Demand for Money in the United States", Review of Economic Studies, forthcoming.

B A R R O , R., 1989. "Interest Rate Targeting", Journal of Monetary Economics, V o l . 23. B U I T E R , W., and M. M I L L E R , 1981. "Monetary Policy and International Competitive­

ness", in W. Eltis and P. Sinclair (eds.), The Money Supply and the Exchange Rate, Oxford: Oxford University Press.

D O R N B U S C H , R . , 1976. "Exchange Rate Dynamics", Journal of Policial Economy, Vol. 84.

F R I E D M A N , M., 1969. "The Optimum Quantity of Money", in M. Friedman (ed.), The

Optimum Quantity of Money and Other Essays, Chicago: Aldine Press.

P O T E R B A , J . , and J . R O T E M B E R G , 1990. "Inflation and Taxation with Optimizing Governments", Journal of Money Credit and Banking, Vol. 22.

S I N C L A I R , P., 1990. "Inflation, Output and Welfare in the Long Run", mimeo. T O BIN, J . , 1965. "Money and Economic Growth", Econometrica, Vol. 33.

T O B I N , J . , 1969. "A General Equilibrium Approach to Monetary Theory", Journal of

References

Related documents

On an Alienware m17x model (using only a single core) the synthesis of our three tissue types would usually converge after It was our experience that the algorithm

We combine a recently released input-output table for maquiladora industries with detailed longitudinal data on value added, gross exports, employment by skill

Whilst nine States known to possess nuclear weapons have not ratified the treaty and will not be subject to its prohibitions, as an internationally binding law, the TPNW has

Impact of RPL objective functions on energy consumption in Ipv6 based wireless sensor networks.. Abdelhadi Eloudrhiri Hassani, Aicha Sahel,

Given the high prevalence of HIV infection in the Kenya and a high rate of TB/HIV co-infected patients, this study sought to determine predictors of low BMI among

Intel ® ® Wide Wide Dynamic Dynamic Execution Execution Intel Intel ® ® Intelligent Intelligent Power Power Capability Capability Intel Intel ® ® Advanced Advanced Smart

Reflective memoing regarding the project as a whole; an audit trail that traces the development of the project, with links to examples and evidence Notes regarding key issues in a

HA: Public access does affect agricultural landowners’ willingness to enter into a conservation easement.. The empirical model was estimated as a multinomial logit using