• No results found

Financial aspects of Public-Private Partnership

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Financial aspects of Public-Private Partnership"

Copied!
22
0
0

Loading.... (view fulltext now)

Full text

(1)

Financial aspects of

Public-Private Partnership

UDK: 351.712(497.4)

Livijo Sajko

Faculty of Philosophy, University of Rijeka livijo.sajko@ri.t-com.hr

ABSTRACT

The growth of public requests is evident in the case of Croatia, but also pre-sent in every European country, with the government’s lack of ability to secure sufficient financial income. The look for additional sources of finan-cing, in order to build public infrastructure, is directed therefore more and more to the private financing capital and to public-private partnerships. Together with such trends, one of the main questions that arise is, whether the employment of private capital in PPP-projects is valid from the economy point of view? If the overall project costs in the PPP-model are lower than the one in the traditional public sector model, calculated with the method of a Public Sector Comparator, the decision can be made to employ private capital in PPP-projects, which is valid from the economy point of view. Key words: public-private partnership, public requests, private capital, Pub-lic Sector Comparator

1.

Introduction

In the projects realised through the public-private partnership (PPP) model, the public sector transfers the performance of public tasks to the private sec-tor. By transferring the public tasks to a private partner, a mobilization effect of the intellectual, human and financial capital of the private sector is attained, which makes the public service delivery more efficient. For this purpose a general PPP-model has to be developed, to fit in different types of PPP and to mobilize private capital, needed for the overcome of capital shortages in public budgets for the construction of public infrastructure.

The growth of public requests is evident. On the other side a lack of ability to secure sufficient financial incomes in the public budgets is present, with the need for additional sources of financing. Such sources can be secured trough private capital in financing PPP-projects. That may be the reason for a fast de-veloping European PPP-market. But the question that rises more and more

(2)

often in such a situation is, whether the employment of private capital in PPP-projects is valid from the economy point of view?

To give an answer to this question, the functions and importance of pri-vate investors has to be taken in consideration. A Public Sector Comparator (PSC) has to be developed, in order to decide about financing the PPP-project by private or public capital possible. Several private capital sources are avail-able for this purpose.

In the case analysis of the City of Monheim (Germany) it becomes evi-dent, how a PPP-project can be financed by private capital, even if the financial costs are higher than in a traditional model of building public infrastructure.

2.

General theoretical characteristics of

Public-Private Partnership

2.1 The general model of PPP and of financing the PPP-projects

The basic characteristic of a PPP is the cooperation and collaboration of public and private partners in public services delivery, in a more effective way. In order to reach such a goal, there is no need for competition between the public and private sector, but only for cooperation and partnership (Smith, 1999, p. 131-137).

The certainty of building up partnership relations has its origins in the prin-cipal-agent theory and property-rights theory (Otten, 2005, p. 7-8). By the im-plementation of these theories into PPP-projects, it is figured out, that the public sector's interest is to reach a common welfare, while the private partner aims for a profit, which may lead to the conflict of interest. It is therefore the main objective to make the private partner reach his profit, but in a way that will ensure common welfare. Further on, both partners will feel motivated to make the project successful, if they have ownership rights over the PPP-project. As public tasks are public goods, these ownership rights can be trans-ferred to the private partner only over a limited time and only with a strong control of the public sector over the performance of the private partner. This calls for a careful and detailed preparation of the PPP-project and the contracts that are related to the project.

(3)

Picture 1: The general model of PPP-participants and the PPP-project financing Loan agreement Financing contract Design & construction contract Maintenance & managing contract

Public Sector Private Sector

Project Contract Project Society Sponsors Investors Banks Private Sector Construction Private Sector Management Loan agreement Financing contract Design & construction contract Maintenance & managing contract

Public Sector Private Sector

Project Contract Project Society Sponsors Investors Banks Private Sector Construction Private Sector Management

Source: PPP – Initiative NRW (2004): Finanzierungsleitfaden, Finanzministerium NRW, p. 17

Therefore, the establishment of a joint (public/private) project society is recommended, as a general model of PPP. Ownership rights and obligations of the partners in the joint project society are regulated by a special project con-tract. The design and the building of the public project are regulated by design-ing and construction contracts, as well as the financdesign-ing of the public project is

(4)

regulated by loan agreements or financing contracts. In the end, the operating of the public project has to be regulated by maintenance and managing con-tracts. All these contracts are bundled in one main PPP-project contract.

The main criterion in the transfer of public tasks to the private sector is the “value for money” principle. As the private sector uses public resources in work and as it is receiving compensation for this work from the public sector or/and from the final users, it has to produce the public product or service in a way, that ensures some main values or outcomes (efficiency, effectiveness, savings, quality). This is reached by optimal allocation of the business risks between the public and private partners (PPP-Initiative NRW, 2003, p. 13).

If the public sector transfers to the private partner only one part of the public tasks (build and operate), then we can talk about a build-operate-transfer or BOT-model. The ownership over the public project is also transferred to the private partner, but must be given back to the public sector after the conclu-sion of the contract. The public sector will detain 51% of the ownership over the joint project society, with the possibility of controlling the private partner. The risks are taken over by that partner, who has more efficiency in the risk management of a specific business risk.

If the public sector transfers all the public tasks (design, build, finance, operate) to the private sector, we can talk about a design-build-finance-operate or DBFO-model. The ownership over the public project and the ownership over the joint project society is transferred to the private partner, but has also to be given back to the public sector after the conclusion of the PPP-contract. By bundling the public tasks in one transfer to the private sector, a better motiva-tion of the private partner is created in the performance of public service deliv-ery. The public sector will keep supervision and controlling rights over the pro-ject society and the private partner (PPP-Initiative NRW, 2003, p. 16-17).

2.2 Public-private partnership – definition and classification

PPP can be therefore defined as a joint cooperation activity of the public and private sector and as complex and long-term contract collaborations in public service delivery.

The main characteristics of PPP’s are:

• A long-term (20 to 25 years) collaboration between the public and

(5)

• A transfer of ownership to the private partner but only over a lim-ited period;

• An optimal allocation of business risks between the public and

private sector and

• An overall responsibility of the private partner in public service

de-livery, controlled by the public sector.

The PPP is positioned between the traditional model of public service delivery and privatisation and can appear in several forms (Gasteyer, 2003, p. 11-14):

• Informal cooperation’s – exchange of information between the

partners;

• Public law cooperation’s – concessions;

• Civil law cooperation’s – long-term rent, leasing, supply and

ren-dering contracts;

• Partial privatisation – a minority transfer of constitution rights to a

private partner;

• Social law cooperation’s – public-private joint project societies.

3.

Public requests and possibilities of how to

finance them

3.1 Trends related to the growth of public requests in the case of Croatia

The growth of public requests is present in every European country, in all public administration sectors, especially in the transportation of goods and people.

In chart 1 the development of the transportation of goods and passen-gers, in the case of the Republic of Croatia, in the period from 1996 to 2005, is presented. The transport of passengers by railroads has grown by 36,9%, while the transport of goods has increased by 29,6%. The transport of passengers in maritime ports in Croatia has increased by 121%, while the transport of goods grew by 87,5%. The travelers' traffic in the airports has grown by 144%, while the transport of goods by air grew by 16,3%, with the

(6)

fact that 86% of the overall transport of travelers and goods is realised by the Zagreb Airport (Zagreb Airport, Statistics).

Chart 1: Transports of goods and travelers in the Republic of Croatia

0 10.000 20.000 30.000 40.000 50.000 60.000 70.000 80.000 90.000 100.000 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 Year ('00 0) Travelers transported by railroad (000) Goods transported by railroad (000 t) Travelers transported by roads (000) Goods transported by roada (000 t) Figures of travelers in sea ports (000) Figures of goods in sea ports (000 t) Travelers transported by air traffic (000) Goods transported by air traffic (t) 0 10.000 20.000 30.000 40.000 50.000 60.000 70.000 80.000 90.000 100.000 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 Year ('00 0) Travelers transported by railroad (000) Goods transported by railroad (000 t) Travelers transported by roads (000) Goods transported by roada (000 t) Figures of travelers in sea ports (000) Figures of goods in sea ports (000 t) Travelers transported by air traffic (000) Goods transported by air traffic (t)

Source: Republika Hrvatska – Državni Zavod za Statistiku, Statisti~ki ljetopis 2006

The most important changes are present in the road traffic. Unfortunately, statistic data for this segment were not registered prior to 2001. While in the period between 1996 and 2005 the number of travelers transported by roads decreased by 25%, the percentage of goods transported in the same way grew by 44%, in the period from 2001 to 2005. In the period considered, the number of registered vehicles increased by 78% (from 1.008.878 vehicles to 1.790.971), with the automobiles share grown by 66%, which can explain the

(7)

decrease of public road transport of passengers (Republika Hrvatska – Državni Zavod za Statistiku, Statisti~ki ljetopis 2006).

Similar growth tendencies exist also in other public segments, such as electrical energy production, maritime and shore transit of passengers, oil pipe-lines, water supply, drainage networks and similar.

3.2 Public requests financing trends in the case of Croatia and the City of Rijeka

To evaluate the fiscal conditions in the public budgets and to identify the financial assets that are available to be invested, in order to satisfy the previ-ously determined requests, a public financial analysis framework has been used (Sikiri}, 2004, p. 307-309).

The chart 2 clearly shows that the net operative results of the City of Ri-jeka, if we exclude the year 2002, are negative. A negative net operative result suggests, that there remained no financial capacity for further indebtedness.

Further on, the capital outlays are in principle higher than the capital reve-nues. If movements of capital revenues and capital outlays are added to the operative result, requests for capital assets are obtained. These requests can be fixed in the amount of 15,2 million of Kuna in 2005 to 58,3 million Kuna in 2004, with the tendency of a strong growth in the period between 2002 and 2004.

The chart 3 demonstrates how the City of Rijeka meets its capital assets requests. In the period of 2002 to 2004 this problem was resolved by new indebtedness. In the period that follows, the administration resolved the capital assets request by issuing of securities. This trend is demonstrated through the growth of the net financial transactions, with loan income and disbursement items eliminated.

Analysing the local administrations in the Republic of Croatia as a whole and applying the same financial analysis method, the following results are gained: in the period from 2003 to 2006, capital requests grew from 385 mil-lion Kuna to 1,4 bilmil-lion Kuna. The main instrument of meeting these requests in the stated period was the stipulation of loan agreements. The local administra-tions were averagely indebted by 525 million Kuna a year. The net financial transactions (securities) in the year 2004 resulted in 108 million Kuna of reve-nues. In 2006, the same figures amounted to 222 million Kuna (Ministarstvo financija Republike Hrvatske, Državni Prora~un).

(8)

Chart 2: Capital assets requests – City of Rijeka Year 3.189 -6 0. 676 -4 5. 7 45 -1 4. 2 40 -9 .1 97 -1 9. 245 24.543 -1 2. 555 -1 .047 -28.9 2 9 -16. 05 6 -36.1 3 3 -58. 30 0 -1 5. 2 87 -3 8. 12 6 -70.000 -60.000 -50.000 -40.000 -30.000 -20.000 -10.000 0 10.000 20.000 30.000 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 Kn ('0 00)

net operative result (capital revenues - capital outlays} capital assets requests

Year 3.189 -6 0. 676 -4 5. 7 45 -1 4. 2 40 -9 .1 97 -1 9. 245 24.543 -1 2. 555 -1 .047 -28.9 2 9 -16. 05 6 -36.1 3 3 -58. 30 0 -1 5. 2 87 -3 8. 12 6 -70.000 -60.000 -50.000 -40.000 -30.000 -20.000 -10.000 0 10.000 20.000 30.000 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 Kn ('0 00)

net operative result (capital revenues - capital outlays} capital assets requests

Year 3.189 -6 0. 676 -4 5. 7 45 -1 4. 2 40 -9 .1 97 -1 9. 245 24.543 -1 2. 555 -1 .047 -28.9 2 9 -16. 05 6 -36.1 3 3 -58. 30 0 -1 5. 2 87 -3 8. 12 6 -70.000 -60.000 -50.000 -40.000 -30.000 -20.000 -10.000 0 10.000 20.000 30.000 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 Kn ('0 00)

net operative result (capital revenues - capital outlays} capital assets requests

Source: Grad Rijeka, Prora~un

In the National Budget of Croatia, in the same period, regular outlays are constantly higher than the regular incomes, what causes negative net opera-tive results (3,7 billion to 8,8 billion Kuna). The National Budget has no financial capacity for further debts. The capital outlays are far above the capital income, which creates a growth of capital assets requests from 5,7 billion Kuna in 2002 to 10,3 billion Kuna in 2004. During the next two years, this trend stagnated to 8,7 billion Kuna in 2005 and 9,7 billion Kuna in 2006. The State administration averagely debits by 3 billion Kuna and the issuing of securities results in an income of 5,5 billion Kuna a year (Ministarstvo financija Republike Hrvatske, Državni Prora~un).

(9)

Chart 3: Indebtness and net financial transactions – City of Rijeka 29.687 27.515 60.840 0 0 4.854 -3.354 4.672 -873 50.857 -10.000 0 10.000 20.000 30.000 40.000 50.000 60.000 70.000 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 Year Kn ('000)

new debts net financial transactions resulting

in no new debts 29.687 27.515 60.840 0 0 4.854 -3.354 4.672 -873 50.857 -10.000 0 10.000 20.000 30.000 40.000 50.000 60.000 70.000 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 Year Kn ('000)

new debts net financial transactions resulting

in no new debts

Source: Grad Rijeka, Prora~un

A similar development of fiscal conditions in the public budgets of other European countries can be identified, as well as the financial assets that are available to be invested, in order to satisfy the requests.

3.3 Public-private partnership development

In such circumstances, with the state's lack of ability to secure sufficient financial incomes, it is not reasonable to stop the public infrastructure in its growth and development. The look for additional sources of financing, in order to build public infrastructure, is directed therefore to the private capital and to

(10)

PPP’s. The trends of the PPP-market can be taken as an indicator for such a development.

According to available data, it is possible to take an insight on the PPP-market development for France and Germany, as data for Croatia or other countries are not available.

Chart 4: French PPP market

14 7 3 3 1 28 9 5 3 5 5 4 3 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 tr ans po rt he alth defen se ju stice wast e ac commod atio n te lecom m un ications reside nce educ at ion activities Number of projects 2005 2006 14 7 3 3 1 28 9 5 3 5 5 4 3 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 tr ans po rt he alth defen se ju stice wast e ac commod atio n te lecom m un ications reside nce educ at ion activities Number of projects 2005 2006

Source: Public Private Finance, Europe Country Studies

During the year 2005 a total of 28 PPP-projects have taken place in France, with the number increased during the 2006 to 62 projects. Chart 4 demonstrates that in France in 2006 projects in the segment of transport of travelers and goods reduplicated. The projects entering the segment of health, justice and waste disposal are slightly growing. The PPP-models have also found an application in other fields of the public sector, as social welfare accommodations, telecommunications, residential buildings and education.

In Germany, during 2005, a total of 40 projects has been realised, which number increased in 2006 to a total of 106 projects. As shown in chart 5, the German PPP-market is growing in the field of transportation, health, social accommodation, telecommunication, residential units, and education.

(11)

Chart 5: German PPP market tr ansport healt h def en se just ice wa st e acco mmod atio n te lecomm un ications re si de nce ed uc atio n activities Number of projects 2005 2006 8 2 4 3 3 20 15 6 4 3 24 4 12 38 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 tr ansport healt h def en se just ice wa st e acco mmod atio n te lecomm un ications re si de nce ed uc atio n activities Number of projects 2005 2006 8 2 4 3 3 20 15 6 4 3 24 4 12 38 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 8 2 4 3 3 20 15 6 4 3 24 4 12 38 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40

Source: Public Private Finance, Europe Country Studies

4.

Financing of Public-private Partnership Projects

4.1 Functions and importance of a private investor When public infrastructure is built by a PPP-model, what is more and more the case as we could see, one of the main questions that arise is, whether the employment of private capital in PPP-projects is valid from the economy point of view?

Chart 6 shows that the interest rates at the money market in Croatia have a positive movement. From 2000 and on, the interest rates have been fixed at a rate below 5%. The movement of the discount rate of the central bank is also positive, what makes financing through the issuance of securities also favourable, since the discount rate is also below 5%. Such trends are similar to other European countries.

(12)

Chart 6: Interesand and discount rates in the Republic of Croatia 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 Year % money market interest rates NBC discount rate 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 Year % money market interest rates NBC discount rate 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 Year % money market interest rates NBC discount rate

Source: Hrvatska Narodna Banka, Statistika

This points to a favourable condition in financing the public infrastructure projects directly by the public sector. The engagement of private capital will regularly require higher interest rates then the ones described above.

But then the private partner takes over no refinancing liability, which sig-nificantly lowers his readiness to be as efficient as possible. The motivation of the private sector to optimise costs within the entire cycle of the project is brought to almost zero. His motivation to rationalize total project costs is sig-nificantly diminished. Certain functions which are brought by the private part-ner, such as promptness of capital accessibility, evaluation of the project, su-pervision, optimisation of overall costs and dividing of risks and efficiency, are lost if the private partner is not included in the project.

4.2 Financing costs and conditions of financing

The financing costs cannot be considered isolately, but through the total project costs that came up in the overall duration of the project. It is necessary to elaborate comparable feasibility prognosis, called also Public Sector

(13)

Com-nancers, contained within the agenda item „financial costs“, may be compen-sated through savings, realised by more efficiency of the private partner, in other project items, such as „design“, „build“ or „operate“.

Let us assume that the PSC will have the item „finance“ entered at the side of the PPP-model higher then the one entered at the side of the traditional model. An isolated consideration of financial costs in such a way will lead us to a decision towards financing the infrastructure project by the public sector. If we then assume that the remaining items (design, build, operate and others) in the PSC are less in the PPP-model than in the traditional model, an isolated consideration of this costs can create a decision of transferring this public tasks to the private partner – the public sector will finance and the private part-ner will design, build and operate.

If we make the public tasks transfer decision in such a way and not by comparing the overall project costs, we will loose the mentioned advantages of the private investor, which can eliminate the savings or lessen amounts in the project items design, build and operate.

Picture 2: Comparable calculation of PPP project feasibility – PSC

TRADIONAL MODEL PPP MODEL

Finance Business risk

Design Build

CALCULATION RESULT

Transaction and other administration costs

Business risk

Design Build

CALCULATION RESULT

Transaction and other administration costs

Finance

Operate Operate

TRADIONAL MODEL PPP MODEL

Finance Business risk

Design Build

CALCULATION RESULT

Transaction and other administration costs

Business risk

Design Build

CALCULATION RESULT

Transaction and other administration costs

Finance

Operate Operate

(14)

Therefore the overall project costs (calculation results) have to be consi-dered. If the calculation result in the traditional model is lower than in the PPP-model, the project will be realised directly through the public sector. If the calculation results show that the traditional model is more expensive than the PPP-model, the project can be realised through PPP. The transfer of bundled public tasks is therefore recommended.

4.3 Capital sources

As it has been discussed, the public sector can finance an infrastructure project directly from the public budgeted expenditures or by the capital acquired by issuing securities. Should the public sector not dispose with such options, which is very often the case, private capital can be invested through PPP. In both cases we talk about own capital investments (Jur~i}, 2001, p. 141).

But the private partner, who is engaged for the design, build, finance and operate of the public project (a construction company for example) is mostly also not disposing with his own capital. In this case the established PPP-project society has several capital sources for financing a PPP-PPP-project (see picture 1): banks, sponsors and investors.

If the partners make a loan agreement with commercial banks then they have the obligation to pay back the credit with interests. Sponsors are active investors, investing their own capital directly into the ownership structure of the PPP-project society, rendering the capital available in every phase of the project development. The payback of the sponsor’s investment can be secured by commercial businesses performed trough the PPP-project society. Inves-tors or passive invesInves-tors are investing also own capital, but without managing the business or property. The payback of such an investment is long-term ori-entated, trough the profit of the PPP-project society.

It is not often possible to develop commercial businesses and to ensure high and stabile profits or regular incomes from users fees by the PPP-project society. This is mostly the case in non-commercial public sectors, like public education or public health. For this reason, the most usual form of financing the PPP-project is a loan or credit agreement with a commercial bank (Jur~i}, 2001, p.140-144; Merna, 2002, p. 130-134; Walker, 1999, p. 83-97).

A special capital source is the „Mezzanine capital“. It is typically used to finance the expansion of existing companies. Mezzanine financing is basically

(15)

debt capital that gives the lender the rights to convert to an ownership or equity interest in the company, if the loan is not paid back in time and in full. Since mezzanine financing is usually provided to the borrower very quickly, this type of financing is aggressively priced, with the lender seeking a return with an interest rate of 20-30%. (PPP-Initiative NRW, 2004, p. 29).

5.

Case analysis – City of Monheim, Germany

In Croatia some new PPP-projects have been launched. As these projects are the beginning of their development, data collection is so far not possible. Therefore a case analysis of a PPP-project of the City of Monheim, in the county of Nordrhein-Westfalen in Germany, is presented (http://www. monheim. De/stadtprofil/schulen/ppp/).

In 2001 the City of Monheim was faced with a high demand of school sanitation, because 12 of 13 city school complexes (40 school objects) were build before 1980, in which time no maintain investments for the school build-ings where made. At the same time a lack of capital expenditures for this pur-pose was figured out, in an average amount of 7,5 mil euro a year, with the goal to finish the sanitation of the school buildings up to 2006. In such circum-stances a decision was made, to realise the school sanitation by a PPP.

After the employment of PPP-advisers in 2002, a PPP-model for school sanitation was developed, with the following characteristics:

• As only school building sanitation is considered, there is no need

for a new design of the school buildings.

• The public tasks that will be transferred to the private partner are

therefore building, financing and operating of the school objects (BFO-model of PPP).

• The establishment of a project society, whereby the public and

pri-vate partners will have equal shares in ownership, will realise the BFO-model, but the director of the project society must be from the public sector.

• The duration of the partnership is fixed by 25 years.

• The private partner will make loan agreements with a commercial

bank for financing the PPP-project.

• All the 12 schools will be bundled into one major PPP-project.

(16)

After the presentation of the proposed PPP-model to public officials in 2002, a new decision was made: during 2003 the PPP-school project has to be tested on his economics by a Public Sector Comparator. The research and the results of this test (Jacob, 2003, p. 21) are shown as follows:

• The sanitation of 12 schools with 40 objects will cost the public

sector 28 mil euro in building costs, 9,8 mil euro in financing costs, 16 mil euro in operating costs and 46,2 mil euro in administration cost, including the salary of public employees, if the project is real-ised in a traditional way.

• The realization of the school project with a PPP-model will cost the

project society 21 mil euro in building costs, 10,3 mil euro in fi-nancing costs, 14,4 mil euro in operating costs and 41,8 mil euro in administration costs, including the salary of employees of the pro-ject society.

• The overall cost of the traditional model for 25 years is 100 mil

euro, whereby the overall cost of the PPP-model for the same pe-riod is 87,5 mil euro, which makes a saving of 12,4 mil euro or 12,4%.

• Fragmented the savings are: 25% in building, 10% in operating and

11% in administration costs, only the financing costs are higher for 5% in the PPP-model.

After the PSC the decision was made to launch in 2003 an international European wide public tender for PPP in the City of Monheim, with the transfer of build, finance and operate to the private partner. The German construction company “Kircher/Serco GmbH” has in this tender shown the best solutions for realising the PPP-project. Up to 2006 the sanitation of the school objects has been done, while the operating business of the schools goes on until 2029.

6.

Conclusion

The growth of public requests is evident in the case of Croatia, but also present in every European country, in all public administration sectors.

On the other side, the capital expenditures are higher than the capital revenues in the public budgets and the request for capital assets has a ten-dency of strong growth, what is clearly shown in the case of the City of Rijeka.

(17)

resolved by new indebtedness, even when there is no financial capacity for further indebtedness. Therefore, new methods of financing public infrastruc-ture are used, like the issuing of securities. The same public budget statuses are recognized on the level of the whole local administration and in the Na-tional Budget of Croatia.

In such circumstances, the look for additional sources of financing, in or-der to build public infrastructure, is directed more and more to the private capi-tal and to PPP. This can be proved by the development of the French and German PPP-market, with a growth of PPP-projects over 200% a year (2005/2006), mostly in the public sectors of transportation, public health care and public education.

As the implementation of PPP-projects is growing more and more, one of the main questions that arise more and more often is, whether the employ-ment of private capital in PPP-projects is valid from the economy point of view?

The financial trends presented in the case of Croatia, but also similar to other European countries, are pointing to favourable interest and discount rates in financing public infrastructure projects directly by the public sector. The engagement of private capital regularly requires higher interest rates.

But to give a final answer to such a question, the financial costs cannot be viewed isolated. It is necessary to develop a Public Sector Comparator, for the analysis of the overall project costs. If this cost in the PPP-model results in a lower amount than the costs of a traditional model, the project will be realised through PPP. If the calculations show that the PPP-model is more expensive than the traditional one, the project will be performed directly through the pub-lic sector. In the case analysis of the City of Monheim it can be clearly seen, that the overall cost for 25 years of the traditional model is 100 mil euro, whereby the overall cost of the PPP-model for the same period is 87,5 mil euro. That makes a saving of 12,4 mil euro or 12,4%, though the financing costs where higher for 5% in the PPP-model.

The PPP-projects are realised in several stages and consist of several pub-lic tasks, transferable to the private sector. When total project costs are taken in consideration, then the higher financial costs, which appear when private financing of public infrastructure is employed, may be compensated by the savings reached by the private partner in total project costs (i.e. in individual tasks of public ventures transferred to the private partner). This is the conse-quence of a major efficiency of the private sector in relationship to the public

(18)

sector, but also a consequence of better private partner efficiency, when sev-eral public tasks are bundled and transferred as one public venture. This gives the private partner more freedom for efficient economic acting.

In such a way, a clear picture in terms of figures is obtained, which evi-dently shows how the employment of private capital will reflect not only to financial costs, but also to other ventures within the PPP-model, and what the financial and other costs will be, in case where the private capital is left aside. If the overall project costs in the PPP-model are lower than the ones reached by the public administration, the decision can be made to build public infra-structure by PPP-models and the employment of private capital in PPP-projects will be valid from the economy point of view.

Livijo Sajko has graduated at the Faculty of Tourism and Hotel management in Opatija and is a student on the master’s study of Public Administration at the Faculty of Eco-nomics in Rijeka, University of Rijeka. He is a lecturer at the Faculty of Philosophy in Rijeka, teaching entrepreneurship, and a member of the Rijeka City Council for eco-nomic development and entrepreneurship.

(19)

Bibliography

• Gasteyer, T. (2003): Prozessleitfaden Public Private Partnership, Clifford Chance Pünder, Frankfurt am Main.

• Grad Rijeka, Prora~un, http://www.rijeka.hr.

• Hrvatska Narodna Banka, Statistika, http://www.hnb.hr/statistika/hstatistika.htm • Jacob, D. (2003): Erstellung eines Gerüsts für einen PSC bei 4 Pilotprojekten im

Schulbereich, Technische Universität Bergakademie Freiberg, Fakultät für Wirtschaftswissenschaften, Freiberg.

• Jur~i}, D., Veljkovi}, D. (2001): Financiranje kapitalnih projekata lokalnog javnog sektora, Vitagraf, Rijeka.

• Merna, T., Njiru, C. (2002): Financing Infrastructure Projects, Thomas Telford, London. • Ministarstvo financija Republike Hrvatske, Državni Prora~un, http://www.mfin.hr. • Otten, N. (2005): Kooperation zwischen öffentlichen und privatwirtschaftlichen

Par-tnern, Kölner Arbeitspapiere zur internationalen Politik, 2005, Nr. 21. • Public Private Finance, Europe Country Studies,

http://www.publicprivatefinance.com.

• Public Private Partnership – Initiative NRW (2003): Der PPP-Eignungstest, Finan-zministerium NRW.

• Public Private Partnership – Initiative NRW (2004): Finanzierungsleitfaden, Finan-zministerium NRW.

• Public Private Partnership – Initiative NRW (2003): Organisationsmodelle, Finan-zministerium NRW.

• Public Private Partnership – Initiative NRW (2003): Wirtschaftlichkeitsvergleich, Finanzministerium NRW.

• Republika Hrvatska – Državni Zavod za Statistiku, Statisti~ki ljetopis 2006, http://www.dzs.hr.

• Sikiri}, S. (2004): Ekonomska decentralizacija i lokalna samouprava - Upravljanje financijama i prora~unom lokalne samouprave, Sveu~ili{te Rijeka, Ekonomski Fakul-tet Rijeka, Rijeka

• Smith, A. (1999): Privatized Infrastructure: The Role of Government; Thomas Tel-ford, London

• Stadt Monheim am Rhein, http://www.monheim.de/stadtprofil/schulen/ppp/.

• Walker, C., Smith, A. (1999): Privatized Infrastructure: The BOT Approach, Thomas Telford, London

• Zra~na luka Zagreb, Zagreb Airport, Poslovne informacije, Promet, Statistika • http://www.zagreb-airport.hr/hr/poslovne_4_4/index.aspx

(20)

POVZETEK

FINAN^NI VIDIKI JAVNO-ZASEBNEGA

PARTNERSTVA

Temeljna zna~ilnost javno-zasebnega partnerstva (JZP) je sodelovanje javnega in zasebnega partnerja pri zagotavljanju javnih storitev. Teorija o principalu in agentu ter teorija o lastninski pravici služita kot teoreti~ni okvir, ki nam kaže, da je glavni cilj JZP zagotoviti, da zasebni partner ustvarja dobi~ek na tak na~in, da so hkrati izpolnjeni interesi javnega sek-torja oz. t.i. skupno dobro. Oba partnerja bosta motivirana, da projekt JZP uspe, ~e bosta imela v njem lastninsko pravico. Zato je kot splo{en model za JZP priporo~ljiva ustanovitev skupnega podjetja.

Glavni kriterij pri prenosu javnih nalog v zasebni sektor je na~elo “ustvarjanja dodatne vrednosti”. Zasebni sektor uporablja javne vire in prejema povra~ilo za svoje delo iz javnega sektorja in/ali v obliki naro~nine uporabnikov. Zato bi moral zasebni partner zagotoviti dolo~ene standarde (zmogljivost, u~inkovitost, prihranki, kvaliteta) pri zagotavljanju javnih storitev. To je mogo~e dose~i z optimalno razporeditvijo poslovnih tveganj med javnim in zasebnim partnerjem. V primeru da javni sektor prenese zgolj del javnih nalog (izgradi in upravljaj) na zasebnega partner-ja, potem je to model »izgradi-upravljaj-prenesi« ali BOT. ^e javni sektor prenese vse javne naloge (razvij, izgradi, financiraj, upravljaj) na zasebni sektor, potem je to model »razvij- izgradi-financiraj-upravljaj« ali DBFO.

JZP lahko potemtakem definiramo kot sodelovanje javnega in zaseb-nega sektorja ter kot kompleksno in dolgoro~no pogodbeno sodelovanje pri zagotavljanju javnih storitev brez dokon~nega prenosa lastni{tva na zasebnega partnerja. JZP se nahaja med tradicionalnim modelom zagota-vljanja javnih storitev in privatizacijo, ki se pojavlja v razli~nih oblikah.

V vseh evropskih državah, v vseh sektorjih javne uprave se je {tevilo javnih zahtevkov pove~alo. Na Hrva{kem se je med letoma 1996 in 2005 prevoz potnikov z železnico pove~al za 36,9 %, medtem ko je prevoz tovo-ra natovo-rasel za 29,6 %. Prevoz potnikov v morskih pristani{~ih na Hrva{kem se je pove~al za 121 %, medtem kot je prevoz tovora narasel za 87,5 %. Potni{ki promet na letali{~ih se je pove~al za 144 %, medtem kot je prevoz tovora po zraku narasel za 16,3 %. Cestni promet je doživel najve~je spre-membe. Medtem ko je med letoma 1996 in 2005 {tevilo potnikov v cestnem prometu upadlo za 25 %, je med letoma 2001 in 2005 prevoz tovora v

(21)

cest-Okvir javne finan~ne analize uporabljamo za oceno fiskalnih pogojev v javnih prora~unih in za identificiranje finan~nih sredstev, ki so na voljo za investicije, da bi zadostili predhodno ugotovljenim zahtevkom. V primeru mesta Reka so kapitalski zahtevki zna{ali 15,2 milijona kun v letu 2005 in 58,3 milijona kun v letu 2004 – s tendenco hitre rasti. Težavo so re{ili z novim zadolževanjem in z izdajo vrednostnih papirjev.

Analiza lokalnih uprav na Hrva{kem z enako metodo finan~ne analize je pokazala, da so kapitalski zahtevki hitro nara{~ali. Med letoma 2003 in 2006 se je ta vrsta zahtevkov pove~ala s 385 milijonov kun na 1,4 milijarde kun. Glavni instrument za zadostitev tem zahtevkom v navedenem obdob-ju je bilo dolo~ilo posojilnih pogodb. V povpre~obdob-ju so bile lokalne uprave zadolžene za 525 milijonov kun na leto. Neto finan~ne transakcije (vredno-stni papirji) so v letu 2004 dali 108 milijonov kun prihodkov.

V državnem prora~unu Hrva{ke v istem obdobju so se kapitalski zah-tevki pove~ali s 5,7 milijarde kun v letu 2002 na 10,3 milijarde kun v letu 2004. V naslednjih dveh letih je ta trend stagniral pri 8,7 milijarde kun v letu 2005 in pri 9,7 milijarde kun v letu 2006. V povpre~ju so bilanco državne uprave bremenili za 3 milijarde kun, da bi zadostili navedenim zahtevam. Izdaja vrednostnih papirjev je dala prihodek v vi{ini 5,5 milijarde kun na leto.

V pogojih, ko je nemogo~e zagotoviti zadostne prilive za izgradnjo javne infrastrukture, se javni sektor za dodatne vire financiranja obrne na zasebni kapital in JZP. Razvoj trga JZP v Franciji in Nem~iji je to jasno pokazal. Leta 2005 so v Franciji realizirali 28 projektov JZP; leta 2006 je {tevilka narasla na 62 projektov. Leta 2005 so v Nem~iji izpeljali 40 projek-tov JZP; leta 2006 je {tevilka narasla na 106 projekprojek-tov. Ker se uporaba projektov JZP pove~uje, se kot eno glavnih vpra{anj zastavlja vpra{anje, ali je uporaba zasebnega kapitala v projektih JZP ekonomsko upravi~ena?

Gibanje obrestnih mer na denarnem trgu na Hrva{kem je bilo pozitiv-no. Od leta 2000 naprej so bile obrestne mere ustaljene pod 5 %. Taki trendi, ki so podobni tistim v drugih evropskih državah, kažejo na ugodne pogoje pri financiranju projektov javne infrastrukture neposredno iz jav-nega sektorja, ker vklju~itev zasebjav-nega kapitala pogosto zahteva vi{je obrestne mere.

Da bi dali kon~ni odgovor na zgornje vpra{anje, bi morali razviti Pri-merjalnik za javni sektor (PSC), tako da bi bilo mogo~e primerjati celotne stro{ke projekta. ^e model JZP v primerjavi s tradicionalnim modelom

(22)

javnega sektorja izkaže nižjo vsoto celotnih stro{kov projekta, potem bo projekt izveden z modelom JZP, tudi ~e so stro{ki financiranja vi{ji.

Ker je na Hrva{kem ve~ina modelov JZP {e na za~etku, zaradi ~esar je bilo zbiranje podatkov do zdaj nemogo~e, predstavljam analizo primera {olskega projekta JZP mesta Monheim (Nem~ija, Zvezna dežela Severno Porenje-Vestfalija). Potem ko so razvili model JZP, so se odlo~ili, da bodo finan~ni vidik projekta JZP testirali s PSC. Rezultati testa so bili, da bi celo-tni stro{ki po tradicionalnem modelu za 25 let zna{ali 100 milijonov evrov, medtem ko bi celotni stro{ki projekta JZP za isto obdobje zna{ali 87,5 mili-jona evrov. Torej bi prihranili 12,4 milimili-jona evrov ali 12,4 %, pa ~eprav bi bili po modelu JZP stro{ki financiranja vi{ji za 5 %.

Torej, ~e so celotni stro{ki projekta v okviru modela JZP nižji od stro{kov v okviru tradicionalnega modela javnega sektorja, se je mogo~e odlo~iti za izgradnjo javne infrastrukture z uporabo zasebnega kapitala, ker je to ekonomsko upravi~eno.

References

Related documents

Also, both diabetic groups there were a positive immunoreactivity of the photoreceptor inner segment, and this was also seen among control ani- mals treated with a

Field experiments were conducted at Ebonyi State University Research Farm during 2009 and 2010 farming seasons to evaluate the effect of intercropping maize with

Collaborative Assessment and Management of Suicidality training: The effect on the knowledge, skills, and attitudes of mental health professionals and trainees. Dissertation

penicillin, skin testing for immediate hyper-.. sensitivity to the agent should

19% serve a county. Fourteen per cent of the centers provide service for adjoining states in addition to the states in which they are located; usually these adjoining states have

Three key aspects were predominant in her grieving process: (a) spiritual beliefs, involving the performing of rituals to “call” and communicate with Nannay’s spirit over 40

Method: This study investigates patients with type 2 diabetes and hypertension for which concentrations of total high-density lipoprotein (HDL) and low-density lipoprotein

Species known from Cyprus, Greece, Portugal, Spain, Algeria, Egypt, Eritrea, Libya, Morocco, Namibia, Nigeria, South Africa, Sudan, Tanzania, Tunisia, Zimbabwe, Afghanistan,