• No results found

THE NEO-CLASSICAL THEOREM AND THE TWO-SECTOR MODEL OF ECONOMIC GROWTH

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "THE NEO-CLASSICAL THEOREM AND THE TWO-SECTOR MODEL OF ECONOMIC GROWTH"

Copied!
5
0
0

Loading.... (view fulltext now)

Full text

(1)

THE NEO-CLASSICAL THEOREM

AND THE TWO-SECTOR MODEL OF ECONOMIC GROWTH

BY MASAO FUKUOKA AND KUNIO KAWAMATA

Introduction

Recent issues of the Review of Economic Studies have produced a sizable literature on a two-sector model of economic growth, the main incentive for which is in find-ing sufficient conditions to ensure the relative stability of a "Golden-age" growfind-ing equilibrium.1) At the same time, the special issue of the Review on Production Func-tions and Economic. Growth contains a number of papers concerning the "Neo-classical Theorem," which states the conditions for the highest consumption path obtainable in a system growing at its "natural" rate.2) Since the latter works have mostly been posed in terms of the aggregate production function, it may be of some interest to study the theorem in a somewhat broader setting of a two-sectoral economy, where investment-goods and consumption-goods are produced by different production func-tions. Thus the purpose of the present paper is to investigate the validity of the theorem in the context of the two-sectoral growth model as has been developed in the literature earlier mentioned. A similar attempt was undertaken by Mordecai Kurz,3) but his analysis was confined exclusively to the case of Cobb-Douglas produc-tion funcproduc-tions. We shall treat the problem in a more general model as formulated by Uzawa [17] and many others including Shirai [13], Takayama [16], Drandakis [4], Arnano [1], Inada [5] and Kawamata [7].4)

The next section will describe briefly the structure of the basic model just as the necessary preliminaries for the following analysis. The main results will be given in the third section, where it will be shown that all propositions of the Neo-classical Theorem remain invariant for the two-sector model under consideration. To this we shall append the final section which provides a few remarks on the case of Kaldorian saving functions.

Preliminaries

The basic model, which is now well-known, may be summarized as follows. There are two-sectors in the economy; sector 1 produces investment-goods and sector 2

1) Uzawa [19], [20], Solow [15], Takayama [18], Drandakis [4], Inada [5], [6], and Amano [1]. 2) Robinson [12], Meade [10], Champernowne [3], and Black [2]. As for earlier formulations, see

Swan [17] and Phelps [11].

3) Kurz [8].

4) However, our result might be regarded as a special case of Professor Solow's even more general treatment. See, Solow [16]. We are indebted to Professor Samuelson for this remark.

(2)

-69-consumption-goods. Let F1 (K1, L1) and F2 (K2, L2) be the quantity of the investment-goods Y1 and that of the consumption-goods Y2 respectively, where Ki and Li are the quantities of capital and labor allocated to sector i. Both capital and labor are fully employed so that the sum of K1 and K2 equals the total available amount of capital K, and similarly that of L1 and L2 the total amount of labor L. As the allocation of the factors is competitively determined, the marginal-productivity equalities aree always satisfied. Consumption forms a certain fraction 1-s of total gross income, and savings as residuals are all invested. Investment-goods depreciate ("evaporate") at a fixed rate of depreciation ƒÊ, and labor expands at an exogenously-determined rate n.

Denoting the price of the i-th goods by pi, the rental rate of capital by ƒÁ, and the wage rate of labor by w, we can write down all the relations described above as

(1) Y1=F1 (K1, L1,), Y2=F2 (K2, L2)

(2) K1+K2=K

(3) L1+L2=L

aF, &F2 - _ &F, - aF2

(4) p1 OK , _ -p2 8K2 r' p' &L, p2 aL2 =w (5) p2Y2= (1-s)(rK+ wL) (6) K=Y,-,pK (7) L=nL.

Under the assumptions of (a) constant returns to scale, and (b) positive marginal productivities, (1)~(7) are further restated as

(8) y1=f1(k1)l1, Y2-f2 (k2)l2 (9) k1l1,+k2l2=k (10) l1+l2=1 (11) ƒÖ+k,-f-'k,) f (t)+k2- f;(k'') ,,( (k,) , f2 (Q

(12)

p° f2'(k2)

f, (k,) (13) y2=(1-s)(m+k)fZ (k2)

(14)

= k

kl

where

kr=

Ki

, k=

L , l,=

L , yi-Xi

, W=-W,

P__h

and f1(k;)=F;(k„ 1).

It has been proved that, with additional assumptions of (c) fi"(ki)<0 , and (d)fi (0) =** , fi(**)=0, either if the investment-goods sector is always less capital intensive than the consumption-goods sector, or if the elasticity of substitution between total capital and total labor is not less than unity, a path of balanced growth is uniquely .determined, and any growth process approaches the balanced path in its relative

configuration.

(3)

November 1965 M. Fukuoka and K. Kawamata: The Neo-classical Theorem

Main Results

Suppose now that either of the above conditions for relative stability is satisfied. Then, from the long-run viewpoint, it may be considered that a balanced path is always realized in accordance with each possible set of parameters including the fraction of income saved and invested s. The Neo-classical Theorem is concerned with the problem: What is the best value of the saving ratio s in the sense that it maximizes the consumption level per head along each path of "Golden-age" steady configuration?

In view of (8), (9), (10), (11) and (13), we obtain

(15) k= k,k2+swk,+(1-s)wk2 (1-s)kl+skz+w

Accordingly, if we substitute (15) into (13), and use (11) again, we can easily verify that the consumption level to be maximized is expressed in the form

(16) y2= (1-s)(w+k,)fz(k2) (1-s)k,+skz+w ,On the other hand, by (15), equation (14) may be rewritten as

k __ s(w+h2)fi(k1)

(17) k k

1k2+swk1+(1-s)wk2 -(n+~1),

so that, by putting k**/k=0, the "Golden-age" steady path is characterized by the condition

(18) s(w+k2)f 1(k,) - (n+ p) (k1k2+swk1 + (1-s)wk2) = 0.

With all these considerations, our problem is now framed in terms of a familiar con-strained maximum problem maximizing (16) subject to constraint (18). Following the conventional procedure, fix a Lagrangean expression as

(19) 4(s,

w, A)

= (11

s)(c

+ ,)f

+m)

+A[s(w+k2)fl(k1)-(n+p)(k,k2+swk,+(1-s)wk2)],

where *** is a Lagrangean multiplier, and maximize **by varying s, ** and **. A straightforward calculation shows that the following first-order conditions have to be satisfied. (20) as 80 -_ (w+k1)(w+k2)f2(k2) +A[(w+k2)f1(k1)+(n+p)(k2-k1)w]=0, [(1-s)k1+sk2+w]2

00 - (1-s)[s((o

+k2)2

dkl

+(1-s)(w+k1)2

d +s(k2-k1)(w+k2)f2(k2)]

(21) a (w+k2)[(1-s)k1+sk2+w]2

-d(n+p)

[sw(w+k2)2

d+(1-s)w(w+k1)2

m

L]

k2

+(1-s)(k2-k1)(w+k,)k2

( =0, w+k1)(w+k2) and

(22)

a0=s(w+k2)f1(k1)-(n+i)(k1k2+swk,+(1-s)wk2)=0.

From (20) and (22), one gets

_ s (w+k2)f2(k2)

(23) '1

n+,u +,U[(1-s)kl+skz+w]2k2 '

(4)

(24) [(1-s)(w+k,)k2-s((o+kz)w]

• [s(w+k2)2

dw'

+(1-s)(w+k,)2

do

]=0.

Hence, in view of dk1/dw$0, dk2/dw+0, it is obvious that (25) (1- s)(w+k,)k2= sw(w+k2)

must hold along any "Golden-age" path with the highest consumption. Now, using (11), we can verify that (25) is equivalent to

s(w+k2)f,(k,) _ L

(26)

k,k2+swk,+(1-s)wk2

With the condition of balanced growth (18), the left side of (26) equals n+**, which is the sum of the "Golden-age" rate of capital growth plus the rate of depreciation. On the other hand, by (4), the right side of (26) equals the gross rate of profit r/p,. Accordingly it follows that

(27)

K**

=n=

pl -u,

i. e., the rate of capital accumulation at its natural rate equals the net rate of profit. Then from (4), (6) and (27), it immediately follows that

(28) p,Yi=rK.

Investments equals profits. Finally, from the homogeneity postulate, (2), (5) and (28), it is easy to see

(29) s= rK+wL '

which says that the fraction of income invested equals the relative share imputed to profits.

Thus we have seen that the decomposition into two sectors does not affect the Neo-classical Theorem at all.

Additional Remarks

In developing the two-sector models of economic growth, some writers assume that there are certain differences between saving rates from profits and wages. In this section we shall show that this decomposition also leaves the validity of the theorem unaffected.

Let the fraction of profits saved be sp and that of wages be s.. Then the equation (5) becomes

(30) p2Y2=(1-sp)rK+(1-sa) WL,

and accordingly (16) and (18) become

(31) y2= [(1-sw)w+(1-sp)k,]f2(k2) (1-sp k,+spk2+w and

(32) (saw+spk2)f,(k,) - (n+,u)(k,k2 +s„wk,+ (1-s„ )wk2) =0 respectively. Similar but a little more laborious calculation gives us

(33) (1-sp)(w+k,)k2=smw(w+k2)

in the place of (25). Hence, to see if the theorem is still valid, we only need to rewrite (26) as

(5)

November 1965 M. Fukuoka and K. Kawamata: The Neo-classical Theorem

(34) k ik2+s,, oki+(1-sw)cok2 (So) +spk2).f2(kl) -f' '(W and (29) as

rK wL __ rK

(35) sp

rK+wL +s'° rK+wL rK+wL'

In concluding our paper, it is interesting to note that (33) implies

rK2

(36) rK_2+wL2 _ wL, - 1-sp ' s„ rK~ + wLl

I.e., the ratio of capital's relative share in the consumption-goods sector to labor's relative share in the investment-goods sector equals the ratio of laborers' propensity to save to capitalists' propensity to consume.

Keio University

REFERENCES

[ 1 ] Amano, A., "A Further Note on Professor Uzawa's Two-sector Model of Economic Growth," Review of Economic Studies, April 1964, pp. 97-102.

[ 2 ] Black, J., "Technical Progress and Optimum Savings," Review of Economic Studies, June 1962, pp.238-240.

[ 3 ] Champernowne, D. G., "Some Implications of Golden Age Conditions when Savings equal Profits," Review of Economic Studies, June 1962, pp. 235-237.

[

4] Drandakis, E. M., "Factor Substitution in the Two-sector Growth Model," Review of Economic Studies, October 1963, pp. 217-228.

[ 5 ] Inada, K., "On a Two-sector Model of Economic Growth: Comments and a Generalization,"

Review of Economic Studies, June 1963, pp. 119-127.

[6] Inada, K., "On the Stability of Growth Equilibria in Two-sector Models," Review of Economic Studies, April 1964, pp. 127-142.

[ 7 ] Kawamata, K., "Nibumon Keizai Model ni okeru Kinko Seicho ni tsuite," Mita Gakkai Zasshi, January 1964, pp. 21-42.

[ 8 ] Kurz, M., "A Two-sector Extension of Swan's Model of Economic Growth," International nomic Review, Vol. 4, 1963, pp. 68-79.

[ 9 ] Meade, J. E., A Neo-classical Theory of Economic Growth, 2nd ed., 1962.

[10] Meade, J. E., "The Effect of Savings on Consumption in a State of Steady Growth," Review of Economic Studies, June 1962, pp. 227-234.

[11] Phelps, E., "The Golden Rule of Accumulation: A Fable for Growthmen, American Economic Review, September 1961, pp. 638-643.

[12] Robinson, J., "A Neo-classical Theorem," Review of Economic Studies, June 1962, pp. 219-226. [13] Samuelson, P. A., "Comment," Review of Economic Studies, June 1962, pp. 251-254.

[14] Shirai, T., "Shinkotenha-teki Keizai Seicho Riron ni kansuru ichi Kenkyu," Keizaigaku, Vol. 12, No. 2, pp. 108-149.

[15] Solow, R. M., "Notes on Uzawa's Two-sector Model of Economic Growth," Review of Economic Studies, October 1961, pp. 48-50.

[16] Solow, R. M., "Comment," Review of Economic Studies, June 1962, pp. 255-257.

[17] Swan, T. W., "Of Golden Ages and Production Functions," International Economic Association,

Round Table on Economic Development with Special Reference to East Asia, April 1960, pp. 1-14. [18] Takayama, A., "On a Two-sector Model of Economic Growth: A Comparative Static Analysis,"

Review of Economic Studies, June 1963, pp. 95-104.

[19] Uzawa, H., "On a Two-sector Model of Economic Growth," Review of Economic Studies, October 1961, pp. 40-47.

[20] Uzawa, H., "On a Two-sector Model of Economic Growth: II," Review of Economic Studies, June 1963, pp. 105-118.

References

Related documents

Results suggest that the probability of under-educated employment is higher among low skilled recent migrants and that the over-education risk is higher among high skilled

Cest cet aspect que nous allons maintenant analyser a partir de deux mesures de la consommation agregee d'energie, une mesure thermique, soit la fommle (I) et une mesure

But that is Marx’s exact point in discussing the lower phase of communism: “Right can never be higher than the economic structure of society and its cultural development which

19% serve a county. Fourteen per cent of the centers provide service for adjoining states in addition to the states in which they are located; usually these adjoining states have

Field experiments were conducted at Ebonyi State University Research Farm during 2009 and 2010 farming seasons to evaluate the effect of intercropping maize with

Biological control is the use of living organisms, such as predators, parasitoids, and pathogens, to control pest insects, weeds, or diseases.. Other items addressed

National Conference on Technical Vocational Education, Training and Skills Development: A Roadmap for Empowerment (Dec. 2008): Ministry of Human Resource Development, Department

Quality: We measure quality (Q in our formal model) by observing the average number of citations received by a scientist for all the papers he or she published in a given