• No results found

Trade in services an introductory survey

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2020

Share "Trade in services an introductory survey"

Copied!
12
0
0

Loading.... (view fulltext now)

Full text

(1)

The Economic and Social Review, Vol. 20, No. 1, October 1988, pp. 37-48

Trade in Services: An Introductory Survey

C I L L I A N R Y A N *

Cornell College

Abstract: R e c e n t trade t h e o r y l i t e r a t u r e has d e v o t e d c o n s i d e r a b l e a t t e n t i o n to trade i n services. A t issue is w h e t h e r trade i n services c a n be a d e q u a t e l y e x p l a i n e d b y e x i s t i n g m o d e l s o r w h e t h e r there are l i k e l y to be a n y n e w insights to be gained b y c o n s i d e r i n g services as d i s t i n c t f r o m g o o d s . T h i s p a p e r p r o v i d e s a selective s u r v e y o f the r e l e v a n t t h e o r e t i c a l literature a n d c o n s i d e r s several r e c e n t papers t h a t suggest n e w results c a n be o b t a i n e d b y m o d e l l i n g goods a n d services as d i s t i n c t .

his paper suggests that i n the l i g h t o f recent research i t is w r o n g t o treat X goods and services as always theoretically equivalent. I n the paper I con­ sider several recent articles that have suggested new results and survey some of the standard t h e o r y that is p a r t i c u l a r l y relevant t o the debate o n trade i n services.

Over the years there has been a tendency t o m o d e l goods and services as i f they were equivalent. Indeed, i n all branches o f economic theory authors fre­ q u e n t l y refer t o the subject o f their papers as "goods and services". Several recent developments have led t o a reappraisal o f this treatment o f the t w o concepts. First, the service sector has g r o w n i n importance i n m o d e r n western economies, accounting, for example, for 69 per cent o f GNP i n the U n i t e d States. Secondly, the current r o u n d o f G A T T negotiations is considering several proposals o n the liberalisation o f trade i n services. T h i r d l y , the fact

• P r e p a r a t i o n o f this p a p e r w a s s u p p o r t e d b y the I n s t i t u t e f o r R e s e a r c h o n P u b l i c P o l i c y . I a m grateful for h e l p f u l c o m m e n t s f r o m J i m M e l v i n , J o h n O ' H a g e n , D o n a l d C . C e l l , A ' A m e r F a r o o q i a n d the E d i t o r . A s per u s u a l all r e m a i n i n g errors are s o l e l y m y r e s p o n s i b i l i t y .

(2)

t h a t there has already been considerable liberalisation o f trade i n goods i n the European C o m m u n i t y suggests that the service sector m a y experience the greatest changes w i t h the c o m p l e t i o n o f the i n t e r n a l m a r k e t i n 1992.

There is n o t unanimous agreement, however, o n the need for this reappraisal. This m a y be due t o the belief o f some trade theorists that services can be analysed i n t r a d i t i o n a l models i n precisely the same w a y as goods. The ques­ t i o n is whether services can simply be treated either as final goods i n them­ selves or as intermediate inputs i n t o the p r o d u c t i o n process. Thus the debate i n the literature is centred o n whether there is any fundamental difference between goods and services perse, whether trade i n services can be adequately explained b y existing models and i f so, w h i c h models are m o s t appropriate, and f i n a l l y , whether there are l i k e l y t o be any new insights to be gained b y considering services as distinct f r o m goods i n such models.

Perhaps the least progress has been made o n the first o f these issues, that is, whether there is a fundamental difference between goods and services. H i l l ( 1 9 7 7 ) argues that goods and services have d i s t i n c t characteristics and that they " b e l o n g i n different logical categories" ( H i l l , 1977, p . 3 1 8 ) . A m o n g the key characteristics that differentiate services f r o m goods according t o H i l l are: c o n s u m p t i o n o f a service m u s t take place simultaneously w i t h its pro­ d u c t i o n , services cannot be stored, and they cannot be transferred f r o m one economic u n i t t o another. Thus H i l l claims that "models o f pure exchange economies o f a Walrasian t y p e . . . are q u i t e inapplicable and i r r e l e v a n t " ( H i l l , 1977, p . 3 1 9 ) . While these characteristics are true o f some services such as medical care or personal services, there are other services w h i c h do n o t f i t this d e f i n i t i o n . Services such as management or engineering consulting, can be carried o u t at arm's length b y telephone or post. Many other w r i t e r s have a t t e m p t e d t o define services either f o r m a l l y or t h r o u g h a t a x o n o m y o f activi­ ties they believe t o be services.1 U n f o r t u n a t e l y , as Kravis, Heston and Summers

( 1 9 8 3 ) p o i n t o u t , i t is generally possible t o f i n d an economic a c t i v i t y that is c o m m o n l y agreed t o be a service that does n o t f i t any d e f i n i t i o n proposed. S i m i l a r l y , I n m a n ( 1 9 8 5 , p . 4) suggests t h a t " l i k e beauty, the d e f i n i t i o n o f a service is o f t e n i n the eye o f the beholder."

I n contrast t o H i l l , H i n d l e y and S m i t h (1984) can see no reason for concern at the neglect o f the d i s t i n c t i o n between goods and services. T h e y argue that goods are n o t an homogeneous c o m m o d i t y and that they have many d i s t i n c t characteristics, y e t we w o u l d expect the theory o f comparative advantage t o c o n t i n u e t o h o l d .

Deardorff ( 1 9 8 5 ) argues that debating definitions w i l l inevitably prove

(3)

inconclusive and suggests that the issue can o n l y be resolved b y b u i l d i n g a m o d e l t h a t captures a single characteristic peculiar t o a service, a characteristic " t h a t i n t u i t i o n suggests m a y have a bearing o n trade and comparative advan­ tage, . . . and e x a m i n i n g its i m p l i c a t i o n s " (Deardorff, 1985, p . 6 5 ) . I w o u l d argue t h a t i t is this line o f research t h a t has p r o v e d most successful. T h e models o u t l i n e d i n this paper do n o t suggest that a new t h e o r y is r e q u i r e d to explain all trade i n services, b u t rather t h a t some services can alter the models i n i m p o r t a n t ways leading t o a reversal or a reinforcement o f tradi­

t i o n a l results.

I n the subsequent sections I examine several papers t h a t have i d e n t i f i e d an i m p o r t a n t characteristic o f services and w h i c h derive new results or insights i n t o i n t e r n a t i o n a l trade. I also survey several areas o f trade t h e o r y that are p a r t i c u l a r l y relevant t o trade i n services. Section I I considers three new papers on w h a t are k n o w n as producer services. Section I I I outlines the t h e o r y o f factor m o b i l i t y , an area m a n y economists have suggested is p a r t i c u l a r l y i m p o r ­ t a n t t o the debate. Section I V addresses the issue o f whether free trade i n services w i l l result i n trade i n services becoming more i m p o r t a n t than trade i n goods. Section V considers the existing literature o n t r a n s p o r t a t i o n services and some new results f r o m recent papers. Section V I considers a m o d e l o f education services, while Section V I I outlines future possible research t h a t m a y y i e l d n e w results.

I I C O M P A R A T I V E A D V A N T A G E A N D T R A D E I N P R O D U C E R S E R V I C E S

This section examines three recent papers o n producer services. These are services, such as management or engineering services, w h i c h can be p r o v i d e d b y residents i n one c o u n t r y t o enterprises i n another. D e a r d o r f f (1985) cites the p r o v i s i o n o f those services b y foreign residents as one o f the characteristics that m a y affect the standard results.

I n his frequently c i t e d paper, D e a r d o r f f employs a Heckscher-Ohlin m o d e l where there are t w o countries, t w o factors, one good and a service. The service is n o t tradable and the factors o f p r o d u c t i o n are labour and management.

(4)

sector a service at all i n his m o d e l . C o u n t r y B w o u l d still supply management services i f the non-traded sector p r o d u c e d a g o o d rather t h a n a service. Dear-d o r f f himself notes t h a t the p r i n c i p l e can be rehabilitateDear-d i f i t is reinterpreteDear-d t o apply t o the supply o f management services. I n this case c o u n t r y B has the comparative advantage since the relative salary o f management i n B is lower i n autarky.

D e a r d o r f f claims, however, that such a r e i n t e r p r e t a t i o n w i l l lead t o problems i f the comparative advantage i n c o u n t r y A is based u p o n a technological advantage i n the p r o d u c t i o n o f services. I n this case, although c o u n t r y A has a higher autarky r e t u r n t o management, i t w i l l e x p o r t management services as l o n g as its technological superiority outweighs the relative costliness o f its management.

The apparent v i o l a t i o n o f the principle o f comparative advantage arises because the technological advantage is specific t o the management factor i n c o u n t r y A . This can be seen i f we consider Markusen ( 1 9 8 3 ) where b o t h goods are traded and the factor e m p l o y e d intensively i n the technologically superior i n d u s t r y enjoys a relatively higher r e t u r n . I f management is used intensively in the technologically superior sector, and b o t h factors are m o b i l e , then managers.will migrate t o c o u n t r y A u n t i l returns are equalised. However, i n Deardorff's m o d e l the managers f r o m c o u n t r y B do n o t become technically more p r o f i c i e n t w h e n they provide services i n c o u n t r y A and their effective r e t u r n is l o w e r because w h i l e the r e t u r n per manager i n c o u n t r y A is higher, the r e t u r n per effective management u n i t is lower. Thus, the o n l y way t h a t c o u n t r y B can enjoy the benefits o f c o u n t r y A's superior technology is t o rent the technically superior management services f r o m A i n r e t u r n for goods. The correct i nd icat or o f comparative advantage i n this m o d e l is n o t the r e t u r n t o the management service, b u t rather the r e t u r n per effective management u n i t .

This m o d e l highlights b o t h the importance o f defining the service a c t i v i t y appropriately and the importance o f choosing the appropriate i n d i c a t o r o f comparative advantage w h e n analysing trade i n services.

M e l v i n ( 1 9 8 9 ) highlights an even more i m p o r t a n t result that follows f r o m this m o d e l . I f one c o u n t r y is relatively well-endowed w i t h the m o b i l e or service factor and i f the i n d u s t r y p r o d u c i n g the tradable good uses this factor i n t e n ­ sively, then efficient w o r l d o u t p u t is possible, b u t the trade p att e rn w i l l n o t be as predicted b y the Heckscher-Ohlin Theo rem. The c o u n t r y that is relatively well-endowed w i t h the i m m o b i l e factor w i l l be observed t o be e x p o r t i n g the good that is intensive i n the m o b i l e factor.

(5)

tradable good. I f i t is the m o b i l e factor, the t r a d i t i o n a l fall i n w o r l d trade due t o the i m p o s i t i o n o f a t a r i f f reduces the exports o f the m o b i l e factor, w h i c h i n t u r n causes the o u t p u t o f the tradable g o o d t o f a l l .

Markusen ( 1 9 8 7 ) notes t h a t m a n y producer services, such as engineering and management consulting, require a high i n i t i a l investment i n learning. These services, however, can be p r o v i d e d t o a d d i t i o n a l users at a very l o w cost. Markusen develops a m o d e l similar t o the one i n E t h i e r ( 1 9 8 2 ) i n w h i c h the o u t p u t o f a g o o d is m o d e l l e d as the assembly o f components, and i n Markusen's m o d e l these components are producer services. Since these components are p r o d u c e d w i t h a f i x e d cost and a constant marginal cost, increasing returns t o scale exist. The m a r k e t structure, therefore, is assumed t o take the f o r m o f m o n o p o l i s t i c c o m p e t i t i o n .

Markusen shows that p e r m i t t i n g trade o n l y i n goods is an i m p e r f e c t sub­ stitute for trade i n services, since the gains f r o m specialisation i n services can­ n o t occur. Further, i f a c o u n t r y has m o n o p o l y p o w e r i n trade, a t a r i f f o n i m p o r t s o f producer services reduces specialisation b y servicers and m a y , therefore, cause p r o d u c t i o n and welfare t o decline.

These papers have i m p o r t a n t i m p l i c a t i o n s for t r a d i t i o n a l trade t h e o r y . Trade i n services can lead t o greater gains f r o m trade, t o a v i o l a t i o n o f the Heckscher-Ohlin T h e o r e m and tariffs can lead t o a fall i n welfare even f o r large countries.

I l l S E R V I C E S A N D F A C T O R M O V E M E N T S

This section surveys the t h e o r y o f factor movements i n i n t e r n a t i o n a l trade. We do this because v i r t u a l l y every paper o n this topic cites the fact that factor movements are i m p o r t a n t to the theory o f trade i n services. F o r example, many services require direct contact between the producers and consumers. Thus, medical and dental care, direct education and other personal services require t h a t either the producer or the consumer migrate i f the service is t o be p r o v i d e d b y a non-resident producer. D e a r d o r f f ( 1 9 8 5 ) shows t h a t although one m i g h t expect factor m i g r a t i o n to provide problems for the p r i n c i p l e o f comparative advantage, this is n o t the case.

(6)

c o m p l e m e n t a r y t o trade i n goods. Markusen ( 1 9 8 3 ) develops a m o d e l where b o t h countries have identical factor endowments b u t where one c o u n t r y is technically superior i n the p r o d u c t i o n o f one g o o d , and he shows t h a t factor m o b i l i t y is c o m p l e m e n t a r y t o trade i n goods. I n such a m o d e l , factor migra­ t i o n permits a c o u n t r y t o become relatively better endowed w i t h the factor e m p l o y e d intensively i n its e x p o r t i n d u s t r y , and the v o l u m e o f trade conse­ q u e n t l y increases.

There is also an extensive literature o n o p t i m a l factor m i g r a t i o n policies w h e n a c o u n t r y can discriminate between returns t o domestic and foreign factors. Ramaswami ( 1 9 6 8 ) shows that i f one factor is i m m o b i l e , t h e n the c o u n t r y should a l l o w the m o b i l e factor t o move u n t i l the rents t o the h o m e c o u n t r y are maximised. The economic rationale is simply t h a t i f any c o u n t r y can choose t o either i m p o r t the scarce resource or e x p o r t the abundant factor, then the former p o l i c y is o p t i m a l f r o m the perspective o f the domestic eco­ n o m y since this permits factors t o be used i n the same r a t i o t h r o u g h o u t its e c o n o m y . I f the factors are e x p o r t e d t h e n there is an efficiency loss i n the home c o u n t r y , since its m o b i l e factor is being used more intensively i n one c o u n t r y than another. I f , however, d i s c r i m i n a t i o n is n o t possible then, as Calvo and Wellisz (1983) have shown, i t is preferable t o e x p o r t the abundant factor. K u h n and W o o t o n ( 1 9 8 7 ) , i n a m o d e l where there is sector specific capital and l a n d , o b t a i n a richer set o f possible p o l i c y outcomes, i n c l u d i n g the e x p o r t a t i o n o f b o t h capital and labour i f the home c o u n t r y can discriminate.

I V T H E C H A R A C T E R I S T I C S A P P R O A C H A N D T H E T R A D A B I L I T Y O F S E R V I C E S

I f we relax the i n t e r n a t i o n a l restrictions o n trade i n services are we l i k e l y t o observe more trade i n services i n the future than trade i n goods? I n this section we examine a paper b y Z w e i f e l (1986) that considers this question. I t may be recalled that there exists an extensive literature o n trade i n the pre­ sence o f traded goods w h i c h o f t e n refers to services as examples o f non-traded goods.2 B u t as we have seen already, there are m a n y services that can

be traded. Thus, engineering or management consulting can be conducted b y post, telephone or c o m p u t e r , while repairs and alterations to goods can be c o n d u c t e d b y transferring the p r o d u c t .

Z w e i f e l uses a version o f the demand m o d e l developed b y Lancaster ( 1 9 6 6 ) , i n w h i c h the characteristics o f a good, rather than the good itself, f o r m the arguments o f an agent's u t i l i t y f u n c t i o n . B o t h I n m a n (1985) and K i e r z k o w s k i (1987) have suggested that this may be an appropriate m o d e l for analysing

(7)

trade i n services since m a n y services have several characteristics t h a t can y i e l d consumer u t i l i t y .

The variant o f this m o d e l envisaged b y Z w e i f e l is one i n w h i c h agents can c o m b i n e goods linearly i n order t o o b t a i n a bundle w h i c h m o r e closely repre­ sents their desired bundle o f characteristics. Z w e i f e l suggests t h a t services, however, because o f their nature, cannot be c o m b i n e d i n this fashion. I f a good possessed b y a consumer requires some alteration or repair then the set o f possible outcomes is restricted b y the fact t h a t the i d e n t i t y o f the g o o d m u s t be preserved i n the service process. Z w e i f e l attaches considerable i m p o r ­ tance t o i d e n t i t y preservation as one o f the features o f a service (a r e s t r i c t i o n also n o t e d b y H i l l ) , and hence the range o f permissible changes are l i m i t e d t o some region o f the original characteristics.

The d i f f i c u l t y a b o u t the p r o v i s i o n o f services i n these circumstances, accord­ ing t o Z w e i f e l , is t h a t t h e y are almost never consumed i n linear c o m b i n a t i o n s . This m a y be due t o the fact that i t is d i f f i c u l t t o a p p o r t i o n the degree o f repair or a l t e r a t i o n effected b y an i n d i v i d u a l servicer, the fact that p r o p e r t y rights remain w i t h the i n d i v i d u a l w h o is being serviced or whose good is being serviced or the fact that servicers cannot simultaneously w o r k o n a project and t h a t the efforts o f one servicer m a y impinge o n the o u t p u t o f another. For example, i t is n o t possible t o linearly combine the expert assessment o f t w o cancer specialists o n the need f o r an operation.

Z w e i f e l suggests that the i n a b i l i t y t o combine services linearly implies t h a t services are more l i k e l y t o be traded than goods. Since services cannot be c o m b i n e d t o y i e l d the desired characteristics, the need for variety is greater. I t follows t h a t , since i n t e r n a t i o n a l trade facilitates greater variety w h e n dif­ ferentiated products are p r o d u c e d under increasing returns t o scale, services are m o r e l i k e l y t o be traded t h a n goods.

V T R A N S P O R T S E R V I C E S

U n l i k e other services, t r a n s p o r t a t i o n services have received considerable a t t e n t i o n i n the trade l i t e r a t u r e , w h i c h is n o t surprising given its i m p o r t a n c e in w o r l d trade. K i e r z k o w s k i ( 1 9 8 6 ) , for example, argues t h a t the value o f t r a n s p o r t a t i o n services m a y be as m u c h as 13 per cent o f the value o f w o r l d merchandise trade. This section outlines the existing t h e o r y o n transport services and reports o n several recent papers that y i e l d new results.

(8)

be affected, however, and this w i l l alter e q u i l i b r i u m o u t p u t and c o n s u m p t i o n . The major drawbacks o f the Mundell-Samuelson m o d e l is t h a t transport costs are n o t d e t e r m i n e d endogenously, and that the m o d e l does n o t suggest w h i c h c o u n t r y w i l l supply transport services. Herberg ( 1 9 7 0 ) a t t e m p t e d t o relax the f i x e d cost assumption, b u t he makes the a d d i t i o n a l restrictive assumption that each c o u n t r y m u s t carry its o w n i m p o r t s .

The p r i n c i p a l result o f m o d e l l i n g transport i n this fashion is that high transport costs m a y act as a barrier t o trade, j u s t as do tariffs. This d i s t o r t i o n w i l l also mean t h a t the factor-price-equilisation theorem w i l l n o t be satisfied even i f all the usual necessary conditions are. O n the other hand, the presence o f t r a n s p o r t a t i o n costs does n o t necessarily i m p l y that the price o f i m p o r t s m u s t rise. Iceberg t r a n s p o r t a t i o n costs have the same effect o n offer curves as a tariff, t h a t is, the curve is shifted p r o p o r t i o n a l l y downwards towards the i m p o r t i n g axis. As a consequence, i f the foreign c o u n t r y ' s offer curve is inelastic, then an effect similar t o the Metzler paradox can occur leading t o a l o w e r price for i m p o r t s .

Falvey ( 1 9 7 6 ) and Cassing (1978) i n c o r p o r a t e d the transport service sector i n t o the t r a d i t i o n a l Heckscher-Ohlin m o d e l . B y treating t r a n s p o r t a t i o n as j u s t another p r o d u c t i o n sector, Falvey is able t o allow m a r k e t c o n d i t i o n s t o deter­ m i n e w h i c h c o u n t r y w i l l supply services. As w i t h any Heckscher-Ohlin m o d e l , the result w i l l depend crucially u p o n the relative factor intensities o f the three sectors and the factor e n d o w m e n t o f the countries. I f the service sector is m o r e capital intensive than b o t h o f the goods' sectors then the capital-rich c o u n t r y w i l l produce services. I f t r a n s p o r t a t i o n is m o r e capital intensive than o n l y one o f the goods, then we cannot predict a priori w h i c h c o u n t r y w i l l supply the transport services. Cassing points o u t t h a t for the purpose o f the Metzler paradox i t is i m p o r t a n t t o differentiate between the case where tariffs are imposed o n fob ( p o i n t o f sale) prices and tariffs imposed o n c i f (delivery) prices.

(9)

factor payments. Using a similar m o d e l w i t h f i x e d factors, R y a n also shows t h a t free trade i n services can lead t o a loss o f economic rents and a decline i n welfare f o r a l l agents i n the service i m p o r t i n g c o u n t r y .

K i e r z k o w s k i ( 1 9 8 6 ) suggests t h a t since m a n y services such as shipping and telecommunications are characterised b y oligopolistic m a r k e t structures, i t w o u l d be m o r e appropriate t o use a version o f the i n t r a - i n d u s t r y trade m o d e l such as those e m p l o y e d b y Brander and K r u g m a n (1983) and Brander and Spencer ( 1 9 8 4 ) . K i e r z k o w s k i develops a d u o p o l y m o d e l o f i n t e r n a t i o n a l ser­ vices b y assuming t h a t there are t w o countries each w i t h a well-specified i m p o r t demand f u n c t i o n and each w i t h a shipping c o m p a n y that acts as a C o u r n o t d u o p o l i s t . Each shipping c o m p a n y chooses the q u a n t i t y o f goods i t w i l l carry i n each d i r e c t i o n and perfect c o m p e t i t i o n is assumed t o o b t a i n i n the m a r k e t for goods. K i e r z k o w s k i shows that, ceteris paribus, an increase i n a c o u n t r y ' s costs w i l l reduce the m a r k e t share o f its shipping c o m p a n y , raise the prices o f t r a n s p o r t a t i o n i n b o t h countries and reduce the overall level o f services. I f b o t h countries' costs were t o rise, due t o an o i l price shock for example, then the t o t a l level o f services w o u l d f a l l , b u t the relative m a r k e t share o f each c o u n t r y w o u l d remain constant.

These recent papers have given us a set o f models t h a t p e r m i t a richer set of outcomes t h a n the t r a d i t i o n a l m o d e l . The significance o f these new develop­ ments is something that can o n l y be established b y future empirical testing.

V I E D U C A T I O N A L S E R V I C E S

A n o t h e r area o f the recent trade t h e o r y literature that relates t o trade and services is the literature o n the f o r m a t i o n o f h u m a n capital. F i n d l e y and K i e r z k o w s k i ( 1 9 8 3 ) developed a m o d e l where there are t w o goods, x and y , and t w o factor i n p u t s , skilled and u n s k i l l e d labour. U n l i k e the t r a d i t i o n a l Heckscher-Ohlin m o d e l , the e n d o w m e n t o f these t w o factors is n o t deter-m i n d e d exogenously, b u t rather the q u a n t i t y o f skilled labour is an endogenous variable. T h e y assume that there is a stationary p o p u l a t i o n , i n w h i c h N agents are b o r n ( w i t h a life span o f T periods), and N agents die i n each p e r i o d . Individuals have a choice o f entering the labour force i m m e d i a t e l y or o f c o m b i n i n g their labour i n p u t (for n periods), w i t h a f i x e d educational factor in order t o become skilled workers. I n a c o m p e t i t i v e stationary e q u i l i b r i u m the n u m b e r o f skilled workers i n an economy w i l l depend u p o n the q u a n t i t y of the f i x e d educational factor and the agents' rate o f t i m e preference. Thus in a w o r l d w i t h free trade i n goods, the c o u n t r y w i t h the higher discount rate or the higher stock o f educational capital can be expected to e x p o r t the skilled-labour-intensive good and i m p o r t the unskilled-skilled-labour-intensive good.

(10)

each n a t i o n w i l l depend crucially u p o n the e n d o w m e n t o f the f i x e d educa­ t i o n a l factor. I f there were some w a y o f guaranteeing equal access t o this factor f o r a l l the p o p u l a t i o n i n the w o r l d , then the discounted i n c o m e o f all agents w o u l d be equal. Thus, welfare c o u l d be increased i f foreign labourers c o u l d avail themselves o f the f i x e d educational factor, thereby equalising the r e t u r n t o the educational factor i n the t w o countries. Once again, free trade i n services requires t h a t the receivers o f the service (students) or the providers o f the service (professors) migrate. A l t e r n a t i v e l y , education can be e x p o r t e d via books or, as i n the case o f Britain's Open University, b y television.

This line o f research has considerable p o t e n t i a l i n explaining the problems c i t e d b y Lucas ( 1 9 8 8 ) i n reconciling g r o w t h t h e o r y and the process o f eco­ n o m i c development.

V I I C O N C L U S I O N

As I i n d i c a t e d i n the i n t r o d u c t i o n , I do n o t believe t h a t the debate a b o u t the a p p l i c a b i l i t y o f models o f trade i n goods to trade i n services is one t h a t can be settled i n a definitive manner. L i k e D e a r d o r f f I believe t h a t the o n l y w a y t o settle this question is t o m o d e l w h a t we believe t o be the special features o f services and investigate the a p p l i c a b i l i t y o f t r a d i t i o n a l trade t h e o r y . This paper outlines several models w h i c h y i e l d results t h a t differ f r o m the standard trade results or t h a t add new insight t o our understanding o f inter­ n a t i o n a l trade. The significance o f these new developments has y e t t o be d e t e r m i n e d and future research must evaluate their empirical relevance.

However, a considerable a m o u n t o f theoretical research remains to be done since there are m a n y characteristics o f services w h i c h we have n o t cap­ t u r e d i n the existing models. H i n d l e y and S m i t h ( 1 9 8 4 ) , for example, have n o t e d t h a t licensing and regulation are a feature o f m a n y service industries and some economic rationale has t o be advanced to explain this. I n m a n (1985) has suggested t h a t this m a y be because many services are characterised b y asymmetric i n f o r m a t i o n problems. Thus, i t may be more d i f f i c u l t to assess the q u a l i t y o f a foreign service or the r e p u t a t i o n o f foreign servicer than the q u a l i t y o f a foreign good. This m a y lead to domestic regulation that impedes trade. A m o d e l t h a t can capture this feature o f services is highly desirable.

(11)

F u r t h e r , trade i n financial services as w e l l as trade i n educational services may be relevant i n reconciling the problems c i t e d b y Lucas (1988) w i t h g r o w t h t h e o r y and economic development.

F i n a l l y , Markusen notes that m a n y producer services e x h i b i t features o f inreasing returns t o scale due either t o extensive education requirements or private i n f o r m a t i o n . These specialised producers are also a feature o f m u l t i ­ n a t i o n a l enterprises. F u t u r e research o n these enterprises needs t o evaluate the role o f these producer services.

REFERENCES

B A U M O L , W . J . , 1 9 8 5 . " P r o d u c t i v i t y P o l i c y a n d t h e S e r v i c e S e c t o r " , i n R . P . I n m a n ( e d . ) , Managing the Service Economy: Prospects and Problems, C a m b r i d g e : C a m b r i d g e U n i ­ v e r s i t y P r e s s .

B H A G W A T I , J . N . , 1 9 8 5 . " T r a d e i n S e r v i c e s a n d D e v e l o p i n g C o u n t r i e s " , X t h A n n u a l G e n e v a L e c t u r e d e l i v e r e d a t t h e L o n d o n S c h o o l o f E c o n o m i c s , N o v e m b e r 2 8 .

B R A N D E R , J . , a n d P . K R U G M A N , 1 9 8 3 . " A R e c i p r o c a l D u m p i n g M o d e l o f I n t e r n a t i o n a l T r a d e " , Journal of International Economics, V o l . 1 3 .

B R A N D E R , J . , a n d B . S P E N C E R , 1 9 8 4 . " T a r i f f p r o t e c t i o n a n d i m p e r f e c t c o m p e t i t i o n i n t h e p r e s e n c e o f o l i g o p o l y o v e r e c o n o m i e s o f s c a l e " , i n H . K i e r z k o w s k i ( e d . ) , Mono­

polistic Competition and International Trade, O x f o r d : O x f o r d U n i v e r s i t y P r e s s , p p . 3 1 3 - 3 2 1 .

C A L V O , G . , a n d S . W E L L I S Z , 1 9 8 3 . " I n t e r n a t i o n a l F a c t o r M o b i l i t y a n d t h e N a t i o n a l

A d v a n t a g e " , Journal of International Economics, V o l . 1 3 , p p . 1 0 3 - 1 0 4 .

C A S A S , F . R . , 1 9 8 3 . " I n t e r n a t i o n a l T r a d e w i t h P r o d u c e d T r a n s p o r t S e r v i c e s " , Oxford

Economic Papers ( N e w S e r i e s ) , V o l . 3 5 , N o . 1 ( M a r c h ) , p p . 8 9 - 1 0 9 .

C A S S I N G , J . , 1 9 7 8 . " T r a n s p o r t C o s t s i n I n t e r n a t i o n a l T r a d e T h e o r y : A c o m p a r i s o n w i t h

t h e a n a l y s i s o f N o n - t r a d e d g o o d s " , Quarterly Journal of Economics, N o v e m b e r , p p . 5 3 5 - 5 5 0 .

D E A R D O R F F , A . , 1 9 8 5 . " C o m p a r a t i v e a d v a n t a g e a n d i n t e r n a t i o n a l t r a d e i n i n v e s t m e n t i n s e r v i c e s " , i n R o b e r t M . S t e r n ( e d . ) , Trade and Investment in Services: Canadian/US Perspectives, T o r o n t o : O n t a r i o E c o n o m i c C o u n c i l , p p . 3 9 - 7 1 .

D O R N B U S C H , R . , 1 9 8 0 . Open Economy Macroeconomics, N e w Y o r k : B a s i c B o o k s .

E T H I E R , W . , 1 9 8 2 . " N a t i o n a l a n d I n t e r n a t i o n a l R e t u r n s t o S c a l e i n t h e M o d e r n T h e o r y o f I n t e r n a t i o n a l T r a d e " , American Economic Review, V o l . 7 2 , p p . 3 8 9 - 4 0 5 .

F A L V E Y , R . , 1 9 7 6 . " T r a n s p o r t a t i o n c o s t s i n t h e p u r e t h e o r y o f i n t e r n a t i o n a l t r a d e " , Economic Journal, S e p t e m b e r , p p . 5 3 6 - 5 5 0 .

F I N D L A Y , R . , a n d H . K I E R Z K O W S K I , 1 9 8 3 . " I n t e r n a t i o n a l T r a d e a n d H u m a n C a p i t a l :

A S i m p l e G e n e r a l F . q u i l i b r i u m M o d e l " , Journal of Political Economy, V o l . 9 1 , D e c e m ­ b e r , p p . 9 5 7 - 9 7 8 .

F U C H S , V . R . , 1 9 6 8 . " T h e S e r v i c e E c o n o m y " , National Bureau of Economic Research, N e w Y o r k .

H E R B E R G , H . , 1 9 7 0 . " E c o n o m i c G r o w t h a n d I n t e r n a t i o n a l T r a d e w i t h T r a n s p o r t C o s t s " , Zeitschrift fur die Gesamte Staatswissenschaft, O c t o b e r , p p . 5 7 7 - 6 0 0 .

H I L L , T . P . , 1 9 7 7 . " O n g o o d s a n d s e r v i c e s " , The Review of Income and Wealth, N o . 4 ,

(12)

H I N D L E Y , B . , a n d A . S M I T H , 1 9 8 4 . " C o m p a r a t i v e a d v a n t a g e a n d t r a d e i n s e r v i c e s " ,

The World Economy, V o l . 7 , p p . 3 6 9 - 3 9 0 .

I N M A N , R . P . , 1 9 8 5 . " I n t r o d u c t i o n a n d O v e r v i e w " , i n R . P . I n m a n ( e d . ) , Managing the

Service Economy: Prospects and Problems, C a m b r i d g e : C a m b r i d g e U n i v e r s i t y P r e s s . K I E R Z K O W S K I , H . , 1 9 8 6 . " M o d e l l i n g I n t e r n a t i o n a l T r a n s p o r t a t i o n S e r v i c e s " , I . M . F .

R e s e a r c h P a p e r , D M / 8 6 / 3 5 .

K I E R Z K O W S K I , H . , 1 9 8 7 . " R e c e n t A d v a n c e s i n I n t e r n a t i o n a l T r a d e T h e o r y : A S e l e c t i v e

S u r v e y " , Oxford Review of Economic Policy, V o l . 3 , N o . 1.

K R A V I S , I . B . , A . H E S T O N , a n d R . S U M M E R S , 1 9 8 3 . " T h e S h a r e o f S e r v i c e s i n E c o n o m i c

G r o w t h " , i n F . G . A d a m s a n d G . H i c k m a n ( e d s . ) , Global Econometrics: Essays in Honour of Lawrence R. Klien, C a m b r i d g e , M a s s .

K R U G M A N , P . , 1 9 7 9 . " I n c r e a s i n g R e t u r n s , M o n o p o l i s t i c C o m p e t i t i o n a n d I n t e r n a t i o n a l

T r a d e " , Journal of International Economics, V o l . 9 , p p . 4 6 9 - 4 7 9 .

K U H N , P . , a n d I . W O O T T O N , 1 9 8 7 . " I n t e r n a t i o n a l f a c t o r m o v e m e n t s i n t h e p r e s e n c e o f a f i x e d f a c t o r " , Journal of International Economics, V o l . 2 2 , p p . 1 2 3 - 1 4 0 .

L A N C A S T E R , K . , 1 9 6 6 . " A N e w A p p r o a c h t o C o n s u m e r T h e o r y " , Journal of Political

Economy, V o l . 7 4 , p p . 1 3 2 - 1 5 7 .

L E V E S O N , I . , 1 9 8 5 . " S e r v i c e s i n t h e U . S . E c o n o m y " , i n R . P . I n m a n ( e d . ) , Managing the

Service Economy: Prospects and Problems, C a m b r i d g e : C a m b r i d g e U n i v e r s i t y P r e s s . L U C A S , R . E . J r . , 1 9 8 8 . " O n t h e M e c h a n i c s o f E c o n o m i c D e v e l o p m e n t " , Journal of

Monetary Economics, V o l . 2 2 , p p . 3 - 4 2 .

M A R K U S E N , J . R . , 1 9 8 3 . " F a c t o r M o v e m e n t s a n d C o m m o d i t y T r a d e a s C o m p l e m e n t s " , Journal of International Economics, V o l . 1 3 , p p . 3 4 1 - 3 5 6 .

M A R K U S E N , J . R . , 1 9 8 9 . " T r a d e i n P r o d u c e r S e r v i c e s a n d i n O t h e r S p e c i a l i s t I n t e r ­ m e d i a t e I n p u t s " , American Economic Review ( f o r t h c o m i n g ) .

M E L V I N , J . R . , 1 9 8 9 . " T r a d e i n S e r v i c e s : A H e c k s c h e r - O h l i n A p p r o a c h " , Journal of Poli­

tical Economy ( f o r t h c o m i n g ) .

M U N D E L L , R . A . , 1 9 5 7 a . " I n t e r n a t i o n a l T r a d e a n d F a c t o r M o b i l i t y " , American Eco­ nomic Review, V o l . 4 7 , p p . 3 2 1 - 3 2 5 .

M U N D E L L , R . A . , 1 9 5 7 b . " A G e o m e t r y o f T r a n s p o r t C o s t s i n I n t e r n a t i o n a l T r a d e T h e o r y " , Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science ( A u g u s t ) , p p . 3 3 1 - 3 4 8 .

R A M A S W A M I , V . K . , 1 9 6 8 . " I n t e r n a t i o n a l F a c t o r M o v e m e n t s a n d t h e N a t i o n a l A d v a n ­

t a g e " , Economica, V o l . 3 5 , p p . 3 0 9 - 3 1 0 .

R Y A N , C , 1 9 8 7 . " T r a d e i n I n t e r m e d i a t i o n S e r v i c e s " , u n p u b l i s h e d P h . D T h e s i s , U n i v e r s i t y

o f W e s t e r n O n t a r i o .

S A M U E L S O N , P . A . , 1 9 5 4 . " T h e T r a n s f e r P r o b l e m a n d T r a n s p o r t C o s t s ; I I : A n a l y s i s o f

E f f e c t s o f T r a d e I m p e d i m e n t s " , Economic Journal ( J u n e ) , p p . 2 6 4 - 2 6 9 .

References

Related documents

Asst Finance Executive Consultant-SKP Cross Consultant Head Finance CFO Director - Finance Technical Head Accounts Executive VP-Finance MD Finance Executive Manager

It had been so long since I ‗had to‘ produce new musical material, having reached the point of creative activity desiring distraction or unconsciousness more than distracting

Generally, there are two primary legal approaches to internet contract enforcement: The United States model that relies on basic notice requirements to establish and

Real Internet Malware Sample Configuration Analysis Results Internal logs Traffic Log Emulated Internet Filtering Rules Sandbox Access Controller OS Image Config Analysis

In the government contracting world, a proposal is initiated when the government needs a good or service, and asks companies to submit offers explaining how they would complete the

Significant, positive coefficients denote that the respective sector (commercial banking, investment banking, life insurance or property-casualty insurance) experienced

– We visit the oldest leaf of tree. We empty its set of preceding letters. Then we move up 7 letters. We move the head node to this node. We set its set of preceding letters equal