• No results found

Econ 201 Lecture 17. The marginal benefit of expanding output by one unit is the market price. Marginal cost of producing corn

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Econ 201 Lecture 17. The marginal benefit of expanding output by one unit is the market price. Marginal cost of producing corn"

Copied!
6
0
0

Loading.... (view fulltext now)

Full text

(1)

Econ 201 Lecture 17 The Perfectly Competitive Firm Is a Price Taker (Recap)

The perfectly competitive firm has no influence over the market price. It can sell as many units as it wishes at that price.

Typically, a "perfectly" competitive industry is one that consists of a large number of sellers, each of which makes a highly standardized product.

An example is corn production.

Profit-maximization for the perfectly competitive firm Profit = Total revenue - total cost

Q. How much output should a perfectly competitive firm produce if its goal is to earn as much profit as possible? A. It should keep expanding output as long as the marginal benefit of doing so exceeds the marginal cost. The marginal benefit of expanding output by one unit is the market price.

The marginal cost of expanding production by one unit is the firm's marginal cost at its current production level. Example 17.1. Consider a corn grower whose marginal cost of growing corn is labeled MC in the diagram. If this grower can sell as many bushels of corn as he chooses to at a price of $5 per bushel, how many bushels should he sell in order to maximize profit?

$/bushel Thousands of bushels of corn/yr 5 Marginal cost of producing corn Price 12 9 6 4 6

The profit-maximizing quantity for the perfectly competitive firm is the one for which price = MC.

Imperfect Competition Monopoly = "single seller"

Example: Time Warner Cable in the Ithaca market for cable TV service Oligopoly = "few sellers"

Example: AT&T, Sprint, and MCI in the market for long-distance telephone service Monopolistic competition: Many sellers, each with a differentiated product

Example: Local gasoline retailing Five Sources of Monopoly

1. Exclusive control over important inputs Example: Perrier's mineral spring 2. Economies of Scale (Natural monopoly)

Example: Local telephone service 3. Patents

Example: Polaroid cameras & film 4. Government licenses or franchises

Example: Burger King on Mass Pike 5. Network Economies

(2)

2 Most enduring source of monopoly is economies of scale.

Scale Advantage in the Old Economy

Two widget producers, Acme and Ajax, each have fixed costs of $200,000, and variable costs of $0.80 per widget.

Acme Ajax

annual production: 1,000,000 units 1,200,000 units

fixed costs: $200,000 $200,000

variable costs: $800,000 $960,000

total costs: $1,000,000 $1,160,000

cost per widget: $1.00 $0.97

Ajax, the high volume producer, has only a small cost advantage.

Scale Advantage in the New Economy

In the new economy, fixed costs are $800,000, reflecting the growing importance of the information and ideas in the product. Variable costs are only $0.20/widget.

Acme Ajax

annual production: 1,000,000 units 1,200,000 units

fixed costs: $800,000 $800,000

variable costs: $200,000 $240,000 total costs: $1,000,000 $1,040,000

cost per widget: $1.00 $0.87

Now Ajax has a much larger cost advantage.

This cost advantage becomes self reinforcing, as more and more of the market goes to Ajax:

Acme Ajax

annual production: 500,000 units 1,700,000 units

fixed costs: $800,000 $800,000

variable costs: $100,000 $340,000

total costs: $900,000 $1,140,000 cost per widget: $1.80 $0.67

Monopoly, oligopoly, and monopolistically competitive firms have in common the fact that the demand curves for their goods are downward sloping.

Price

Quantity D

For convenience, we will refer to any of these three types of imperfectly competitive firms as monopolists. The demand curve facing a perfectly competitive firm is a straight line at the market price.

$/unit of output

Price

Quantity

(3)

3 Marginal Revenue

The marginal benefit to a competitive firm of selling an additional unit of output is the market price. By contrast, the marginal benefit to a monopolist of selling an additional unit of output is less than the market price. The reason is that it must cut its price in order to sell an extra unit of output, and this means that it will earn less on the output is was selling thus far.

Example 17.2. A monopolist with the demand curve shown in the diagram is currently selling 3 units of output at a price of $7 per unit. What is its marginal benefit from selling an additional unit?

Price Quantity D 6 10 4 10 3 7

Total revenue from the sale of 3 units = $7x3 = $21 Total revenue from the sale of 4 units = $6x4 = $24 So marginal revenue from the fourth unit is $3, which is less than both the original price and the new price.

Example 17.3. A monopolist with the demand curve shown in the diagram is currently selling 4 units of output at a price of $6 per unit. What is its marginal benefit from selling an additional unit?

Price Quantity D 6 10 4 5 10 5

Total revenue from the sale of 4 units = $6x4 = $24 Total revenue from the sale of 5 units = $5x5 = $25 So marginal revenue from the fifth unit is $1.

Example 17.4. A monopolist with the demand curve shown in the diagram is currently selling 5 units of output at a price of $5 per unit. What is its marginal benefit from selling an additional unit?

Price Quantity D 4 10 6 10 5 5

Total revenue from the sale of 5 units = $5x5 = $25 Total revenue from the sale of 6 units = $6x4 = $24 So marginal revenue from the sixth unit is -$1

The Marginal Revenue Curve for a Monopolist For the monopolist in the preceding examples:

(4)

4 Price Quantity D 10 10 5 5 MR

For any monopolist with a straight-line demand curve: Price Quantity MR a Q 0 a/2 Q /2 0

For a straight-line demand curve: P = a - bQ The corresponding MR curve: MR = a - 2bQ For calculus-trained students:

MR = dTR/dQ TR = PQ = aQ-bQ2

so MR = a - 2bQ

Example 17.5. Find the marginal revenue curve for the monopolist whose demand curve is given by D in the diagram. Price Quantity D 8 16 4 MR 8 Price Quantity D 8 16

Profit-maximization for the monopolist Profit = total revenue - total cost

Q. How much output should a monopolist produce if its goal is to earn as much profit as possible? A. It should keep expanding output as long as the marginal benefit of doing so exceeds the marginal cost. The marginal benefit of expanding output by one unit is marginal revenue at the current output level. The marginal cost of expanding production by one unit is the firm's marginal cost at the current output level. Example 17.6. Consider a monopolist with the demand and marginal cost curves shown in the diagram.

(5)

5

True or False: The profit-maximizing level of output for this monopolist is 9 units. $/unit of output Quantity Marginal cost 18 9 6 12 D $/unit of output Quantity Marginal cost 18 9 6 12 D 4 8 6

At 9 units of output, marginal cost is 6 and marginal revenue is zero. Therefore the gain from contracting output ($6/unit) is less than the loss from contracting output ($0/unit). And this means that the monopolist cannot be maximizing profit at a quantity of 9 units.

The profit-maximizing quantity for the monopolist is the one for which MR = MC, in this case 6 units of output. At that level of output the monopolist will charge a price of $8/unit.

Example 17.7. Consider the profit-maximizing monopolist in Example 17.6. At the profit-maximizing level of output, what is the benefit to society of an additional unit of output? What is the cost to society of an additional unit? Is this situation efficient from society's point of view?

$/unit of output Quantity Marginal cost 18 9 6 12 D 4 8 6

The marginal benefit to society of an additional unit of output is $8. The marginal cost of an additional unit is only $4. This means that society would gain a net benefit of $4 per unit of output if output were expanded from the profit-maximizing level.

Note that the monopolist would love to expand output if it could do so without having to sell the current output at a lower price.

Example 17.8. If this monopolist maximizes profit, by how much will total economic surplus be smaller than the maximum possible economic surplus?

Price Quantity 18 12 D 9 6 MC

(6)

6 P Q 18 12 D 9 6 MC Consumer surplus Producer surplus

Loss in economic surplus from monopoly:

P Q 18 12 D 9 6 MC MR 6 8 4 Loss in surplus Consumer surplus Producer surplus

References

Related documents

How the study was conducted The researchers used a 3-D global atmospheric download to predict how the radioactive material download move over earth and a health-effects model to see

In the first half of 2013, advanced economies strengthened, with an upturn in Japan and the recession in the euro area running out, while growth in most emerging markets

Quality: We measure quality (Q in our formal model) by observing the average number of citations received by a scientist for all the papers he or she published in a given

How Many Breeding Females are Needed to Produce 40 Male Homozygotes per Week Using a Heterozygous Female x Heterozygous Male Breeding Scheme With 15% Non-Productive Breeders.

This work looks at the application of one-dimensional diffusion-edited ¹H NMR spectroscopy (1D DOSY) and ¹H NMR with suppression of the ethanol and water signals to the

All corporations lawfully existing and doing business in the Philippines on the date of the effectivity of this Code and heretofore authorized, licensed or

Evolution of the Soul: The Transformative Connection between Cultural Consciousness, Spirituality, and Self-Empowerment for African American Community College Adult Learners.

Evidence shown in the documentary analysis of the second written submission (section 6.3.8) indicated little change in demonstration of using formal recognised SCONUL