• No results found

Subprime Lending In the Primary and Secondary Mortgage Market

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Subprime Lending In the Primary and Secondary Mortgage Market"

Copied!
21
0
0

Loading.... (view fulltext now)

Full text

(1)

Finance Faculty Research and Publications

Finance, Department of

1-1-2002

Subprime Lending In the Primary and Secondary

Mortgage Market

Anthony Pennington-Cross

Marquette University, anthony.pennington-cross@marquette.edu

Published version.

Journal of Housing Research

, Vol. 13, No. 1 (2002): 31-50.

Publisher Link

. © 2002

American Real Estate Society. Used with permission.

Anthony Pennington-Cross was affiliated with the Office of Federal Housing Enterprise Oversight at

the time of publication.

(2)

Subprime Lending in the Primary

and Secondary Markets

Anthony Pennington-Cross*

Abstract

This article provides an exploratory analysis of the role of subprime lending through an examination of the spatial distribution of Federal Housing Administration (FHA)-eligible home purchase loans in the primary and secondary mortgage markets. Loan originations are aggregated to the metropolitan statis-tical area level to examine the proportion of the market served by FHA, prime, and subprime lenders. The article then examines whether subprime lenders hold their loans in portfolio or sell them to private conduits.

Primary market results indicate that subprime lenders are more active in cities with worse economic risk characteristics. Secondary market results indicate that although subprime lenders sell most loans, they are more likely to hold loans in portfolio when economic risks are improving in historically high-risk locations. Finally, when more loans are originated in underserved census tracts, subprime lenders are much more likely to hold loans in portfolio.

Keywords: Asymmetric information; Primary mortgage market; Secondary mortgage market; Sub-prime mortgage market

Introduction

Borrowers who use subprime lending face a tiered pricing schedule and can pay interest rates 400 basis points higher than in the prime market. Lending standards also are enforced in a flexible manner, and low-documentation lending programs such as "No Income Verification" or "No Ratio" are available for borrowers with good credit history and a strong asset base (Steinbach 1998).

After loan origination, the servicing of current and seriously delinquent loans tends to be less automated and more labor intensive in the subprime market. This has led, at least in part, to estimates that the cost of servicing is four times higher for subprime loans (Kogler 1997). Most of the unique factors associated with subprime lending relate to the price the borrower pays and the costs of originating and servicing the loans. Another factor is that the secondary market treats subprime loans differently than prime loans. For instance, very few subprime mortgages are held in portfolio by the financial institutions that originate the loans. Most loans are sold as whole loans to private investors or are securitized as asset-backed securities

* Anthony Pennington-Cross is an Economist at the Office of Federal Housing Enterprise Oversight.

The author was the Director of Research at the Mortgage Bankers Association of America Research Institute for Housing America when this article was submitted. The views expressed in this research are those of the author and do not represent policies or positions of the Mortgage Bankers Association of America Research Institute for

(3)

Hous-(ABS). This contrasts with prime loans, which typically are securitized as mortgage-backed securities (MBS).l

Although using a subprime lender to purchase a home or refinance an existing mortgage may be the most expensive option available to the borrower, the sub prime market has been grow-ing dramatically. For instance, between 1993 and 1998, the subprime market as a whole grew by more than 1,400 percent, from approximately 70,000 to 10,540,000 loans (Joint Center for Housing Studies of Harvard University 2000). In contrast, the whole market grew less than 22 percent. On average, subprime home purchase loans-which made up approximately 23 percent of all sub prime loans-grew 900 percent during the same period. Therefore, although the refinance segment of the subprime market is larger than the home purchase segment, subprime lending has made strong inroads in the home purchase market. In fact, sub prime purchases constituted more than 5 percent of the purchase market by 1998.2

The effect of local risk factors on the fraction of the market that uses sub prime lending is examined in this article, as is the decision of sub prime lenders to hold loans in portfolio or sell them to private conduits. This article extends previous work by Ambrose and Pennington-Cross (2000) that examined similar relationships for prime mortgages.

The basic premise of the first part of the analysis is that in areas with more risk, more bor-rowers are likely to use subprime mortgage financing because of differences in underwriting standards and the shape of the risk distribution. Risks vary by location and over time. Using local economic conditions as a proxy for risk, the relationships between these indicators and the market shares of prime, Federal Housing Administration (FHA), and sub prime lending in more than 300 metropolitan statistical areas (MSAs) are examined.

The second part of the analysis examines what a lender does after the sub prime loan is orig-inated. A sub prime lender can retain the mortgage in portfolio or sell the mortgage to a pri-vate conduit. Two primary questions are addressed. First, do subprime originators change their selling/retaining behavior as local economic conditions change? Second, if behavior does change, what patterns are visible, and what might the results mean?

This article examines the home purchase segment of the sub prime market. It focuses only on loans that meet FHA loan limits to highlight results on the relationships between prime, sub-prime, and FHA lending. Although data limitations need to temper any conclusions drawn, results show that subprime lending in the primary and secondary mortgage markets IS

responsive to local economic conditions and clearly differentiated from prime lending.

I ABS and MBS are very similar in that both are securities created from cash flow generated from loans that are

backed by assets such as a home or car. In general, although mortgages are backed by an asset (real estate), they are securitized in the MBS market. However, at least traditionally, all home equity lines of credit and fixed-term loans, which tend to make up a large share of subprime loans, are securitized in the ABS market.

2 All data tabulations are taken from the Joint Center for Housing Studies of Harvard University's The State of the

Nation's Housing 2000 report, table A-II. This report obtains its data from the Home Mortgage Disclosure Act

(HMDA) data sets, which do not include manufactured housing. Subprime lending is defined as loans made by sub-prime specialists identified by the U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development and based on industry sources, denial rates, refinance share, and lender name. These fii,'Ures may overstate the growth in subprime

lend-ing as a result of (1) changes in the way entities (especially mortgage bankers) report to HMDA, and (2) increasing

(4)

The following sections of this article provide background and motivation for the empirical approach, detail the data sources and definitions of variables, discuss the results, and, lastly, provide a concluding discussion.

Background and Motivation

The selection of mortgage type has been studied extensively in the primary mortgage market. For example, Brueckner and Follain (1988), Sa-Aadu and Sirmans (1995), Capone and Cun-ningham (1992), Phillips and VanderHoff (1994), and Tucker (1989) examined the choice between adjustable-rate and fixed-rate mortgages. Similarly, Dhillon, Shilling, and Sirmans (1990) studied the choice between 15-year and 30-year fixed-rate mortgage contracts. Other studies have examined the choice between conventional and government-insured mortgages using microdata on individual households (Gabriel and Rosenthal 1991; Goodman and Nichols 1997; Hendershott, LaFayette, and Haurin 1997; Linneman and Wachter 1989; Pennington-Cross and Nichols 2000). Loan products offered by subprime lenders provide more alternatives for borrowers and should be included as one possible outcome.

Lenders use standards (payment-to-income ratios, loan-to-value ratios, and credit history) to limit credit and prepayment risks. Because FHA lending standards are more lenient than prime lending standards, wealth- and income-constrained borrowers are more likely to use FHA mortgage financing. Sub prime financing is even less strict than FHA financing with respect to maximum front-end and back-end payment-to-income ratios. Credit history also plays a large role in the qualification process. Although subprime lenders allow 60 percent debt ratios and even current bankruptcies, they also may require a 30 percent down payment to mitigate the perceived risks of high debt ratios and poor credit history. In total, the mort-gage market has the ability to provide mortmort-gages to a wide range of borrowers, as lenders use a variety of approaches to compensate for weaknesses of an application. This flexibility is most visible in subprime lending, where credit scores and down payments can compensate for unverifiable income and high debt ratios.3

Assuming borrowers are utility maximizing, they will choose the lowest cost mortgage avail-able. Prime loans are the least costly, FHA loans are more costly, and subprime loans are the most costly; therefore, rational borrowers should prefer prime mortgages to FHA mortgages and FHA mortgages to subprime mortgages. Let Si represent the proportion of FHA-eligible borrowers in MSA

i

that select a sub prime mortgage, such that

(1)

where Xi is a matrix of variables that captures variation in local economic risk and demographic factors, and 0p ' (")/, and (-), are prime, FHA, and subprime underwriting standards, respectively. Assuming that prime underwriting standards are tighter than FHA underwriting standards,

3 The characteristics of the subprime lending environment are derived from Weicher (1997), Steinbach (1998),

and the Sub-Prime Funding Corporation Underwriting Manual, downloaded from the Web site <http://www.allstatecapital.com/manuaI2.html> on 3/17/98.

(5)

and FHA standards are tighter than subprime standards (e, > @/ >

(H»),

then an increase in

local economic risk results in fewer borrowers meeting prime lending standards and an increase in subprime originations

(asj a\;

>

0).

The effect on FHA market share is more ambiguous and depends on the shape ofthe risk distribution. Because the majority of the mort-gage market uses prime financing, it is likely that an increase in risk will increase FHA's mar-ket share. This article examines the prime/FHNsubprime outcome as a multinomial logit model that represents a cross-sectional analysis at the MSA level of the percent of FHA-eligi-ble mortgages originated as prime, FHA, and subprime loans.

The second part of the analysis focuses on the disposition of FHA-eligible subprime loans in the secondary market. Although the government-sponsored enterprises (Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac) dominate the secondary market for prime loans, this article assumes that they did not purchase subprime loans during this period. Rather, the outlets in the secondary market for subprime loans have been private conduits that securitize and provide credit enhancements.

Previous analysis of the secondary market is very limited. Canner and Gabriel (1992) exam-ined the role oflender specialization in the secondary markets, whereas Hendershott and Vil-lani (1980) examined the impact of the secondary market on the cost of mortgage lending. Benjamin, Heuson, and Sirmans (1997) showed that for adjustable-rate loans, lenders who hold loans in portfolio are sensitive to factors that affect the long-term costs and benefits. Pre-sumably this concern is dominated by the probability of the loan terminating through default or prepayment. Lenders who typically sell loans are more affected by the short-term sec-ondary market commitment rates.

Both the private conduit and the originator know all the standard risk indicators (credit his-tory, down payment, and payment-to-income ratios) associated with a mortgage or a group of mortgages. Given this information, the private conduit determines a price based on its own assessment of the probability of termination and loss severity. The lower the lender's assess-ment of risk relative to the private conduit's assessassess-ment of risk, the more likely the lender will hold the loan in portfolio. In general, if the internal rate of return is greater than the securitization rate of return (guaranteed payment streams less fees), the lender should hold the mortgage in portfolio (Gilkeson, Jacob, and Smith 1994).

Van Order (2001) has shown that secondary market institutions are likely to enter the mort-gage market in individual risk segments and are attracted to those segments with the least internal variation in risk and the largest density of supply (volume of mortgages originated that can be securitized). This description indicates that the secondary market will not be suc-cessful in the subprime market, because the density of supply is relatively small, and the per-formance of subprime mortgages varies dramatically (Mortgage Information Corporation [MIC] 2000).

Notwithstanding this part of the theory, most subprime loans are sold to private conduits in the secondary market. This is because the cost of holding subprime loans in portfolio is very

(6)

high.4 First, regulatory agencies typically require that depositories hold more capital for sub-prime mortgages than for sub-prime mortgages; and second, the chances of large and unexpected losses are higher. For instance, MIC has estimated that subprime default rates can exceed 20 times the default rate for prime loans.

Although most subprime mortgages are sold into the secondary market rather than retained in portfolio, the subprime market is more likely to suffer from informational asymmetries than the prime market. These asymmetries are driven by the lack of homogeneity of subprime loans and the lack of sophisticated evaluation models being used by originators, making it more likely that information is lost as the mortgage moves from originator to the private con-duit in the secondary market.

Lenders can capitalize on their asymmetric information advantage with respect to borrower credit quality and local economic conditions by trying to sell the higher risk loans and retain the lower risk loans in portfolio. Private conduits can try to control the potential adverse selection problem, or "lemons" problem, resulting from the information asymmetries be-tween the lender and the securitizer by manipulating the lender's guaranteed rate of return or by including a right of recourse against lenders who securitize an excessive number ofloans that default (Passmore and Sparks 1996).

In addition, even if both the originator and the private conduit have the same information set,

there is no guarantee that they will estimate the same profitability for a pool of loans. If

pri-vate conduits underestimate, relative to the originators, the effect oflocal economic factors on termination rates, lenders can try to sell more loans when local conditions are riskier and hold more loans in portfolio when local conditions are less risky.

This article tests for a relationship between the rate at which subprime lenders hold loans in portfolio and local economic conditions. To model the subprime lender's decision to securitize,

let Mi be the proportion of subprime FHA-eligible mortgages in MSA i that are retained in

portfolio. Assume that

(2)

where 8(X) represents the probability of borrower default dependent on local economic risk

characteristics (X) such that a8(x)/ ax > 0, and u is the unobserved cost associated with

secu-ritization. If lenders are effective in s~lling lemons to the secondary market, a higher

propor-tion of loans should be securitized in areas with greater economic risk

(aMJ aX

<

0).

I

However, if the secondary market has effective controls (such as recourse against lenders) that mitigate the lemons problem, securitization activity will not vary, or perhaps will decline,

in areas with higher economic risk

(aMJ aX

~

0).

One other potential explanation for any

I

pattern observed is that originators believe that local risk factors affect profitability

differ-ently than private conduits believe they do.5

4 Van Order (2001) also discusses the importance of the cost of holding a loan in portfolio as another determinant of

secondary market viability.

5 This (an arbitrage position) may not be sustainable in the long run; it is difficult at this point to know the true

(7)

Data

A variety of information sources were used, including extracts from the FHA F-42 loan files and the Home Mortgage Disclosure Act (HMDA) database. To correct for potential underreporting in HMDA (Bunce and Scheessele 1996), FHA loans were identified from the F-42 database.6 Using these sources, the total number of FHA-eligible mortgages originated was calculated for 1995 and 1996 for 306 MSAs that had economic data available from Stand-ard & Poor's DR!. FHA eligible refers to all mortgages with loan amounts under the FHA loan limit as defined by the U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development (HUD) by county. Because the study focuses on FHA, conventional, and subprime lending in metropol-itan areas, it excludes all

u.s.

Department of Veterans Mfairs and Rural Housing Service loam,.

To separate the subprime and prime conventional loans, a list of sub prime lenders that report to HMDA, created in 1998 by HUD's Office of Policy Development and Research, was used. The list has been updated every year, growing from 129 lenders to more than 200 by the year 2000. This list was created from trade publications and therefore may not include all sub-prime lenders who report to HMDA. In addition, not all subsub-prime lenders report to HMDA. The probability of reporting to HMDA is likely to increase with lender size. Further, if bro-kers originate more subprime purchase-money mortgages, and those loans are not reported to HMDA, the sampled loans may be atypical. Measurement error may include some conven-tionalloans categorized as prime that actually may be sub prime and some loans categorized as subprime that may be prime loans.7

These data sources distinguish between prime, FHA, and subprime mortgages to determine the final disposition of the subprime mortgages, either retained in portfolio or sold to a private conduit.s The percentage of FHA-eligible loans insured by FHA was calculated for a

6 See the third quarter 1997 US. Housing Market Conditions published by the Office of Policy Development and

Research, HUD.

7 Although it is difficult to compare shares of loan numbers with dollar-value shares, HMDA estimates of subprime

market share, which are based on the number of loans, are always less than the estimates created by industry ana-lysts at Inside Mortgage Finance (2001), which are based on the dollar value of loans. Inside Mortgage Finance reports shares as 10.2 and 12.3 percent for 1995 and 1996, respectively, whereas HMDA reports 3.3 and 4.2 percent. Although important information (such as prepayment penalties, credit scores, down payments, and contract inter-est rates) is not available to compare data used in this study with other potential data sources, it is clear that the HMDA approach does not include all subprime loans. For instance, for 1995 the Inside Mortgage Finance estimate of subprime market share, using the dollar value of loans, is almost 7 percentage points higher than HMDA estimates for 1995. By 1998 this spread decreased to just over one point. This may indicate changing reporting in HMDA, changing methodology by Inside Mortgage Finance, or the changing market structure of subprime lending. In con-trast to the approach used in this article, it is preferable to use the terms of a mortgage (e.g., interest rate, fees, and prepayment penalties) to identify subprime loans.

8 Mortgages are classified as either held in portfolio or sold to a private conduit based on the types of institutions

orig-inating and (if sold) buying the loan. If the originator is a bank, thrift, or credit union, the loan is classified as held in portfolio if it is not sold or if the loan is sold to a parent that is either a bank, thrift, or credit union. All other sold loans are considered out of portfolio and sold. If the originator is a mortgage bank (reporting to HUD for HMDA data collection) that is not a subsidiary of a bank, thrift, or credit union, all loans sold are considered out of portfolio and sold. In contrast, if the parent of the mortgage bank is a bank, thrift, or credit union, loans sold to the parent are classified as held in portfolio. Note that it is possible that the parent depository could act as an aggregator for the subsidiary, but depositories may try to avoid direct ownership of subprime loans to avoid additional regulatory requirements (higher reserve requirements and increased regulatory scrutiny).

(8)

given MSA as the number of FHA originations divided by the total number of FHA-eligible loans in that MSA. Similarly, the percentage of FHA-eligible mortgages originated as prime or subprime loans was calculated by dividing the number of FHA-eligible prime or subprime originations by the total number of FHA-eligible loans in that MSA. Reflecting the dominance of prime lenders in terms of price and service, the calculations show that, on average, prime originations account for 79 percent of the FHA-eligible market. Table 1 provides a list of the variables used in the analysis as well as the descriptive statistics.

Table 1. Descriptive Statistics for 1995 and 1996

Description Source Variable Mean SD Min Max Obs

Dependent: Sjt' Percent of FHA-Eligible Originations

Percent of loans originated as GSE PUDB, Prime, 79.05 11.21 43.14 99.53 612

prime loans in t HUD/F-42,

HMDA

Percent of loans originated as GSE PUDB, FIL\ 19.83 11.10 0.38 55.64 612

FHA loans in t HUD/F-42,

HMDA

Percent of loans originated as GSE PUDB, Subprime, 1.13 1.39 0.00 20.83 612

subprime loans in t HUD/F-42,

HMDA

Dependent: Mit> Final Disposition of Subprime Loans

Percent of subprime loans sold to HMDA Soldt 93.36 11.75 0.00 100.00 589

private conduit in t

Percent of subprime loans held in HMDA Portfolio, 6.64 11.75 0.00 100.00 589

portfolio in t

Economic Risk

One-year percent change in house Freddie House price 4.33 2.62 -7.11 12.58 612

prices from t-1 to t Mac growtht

One-year change in the DRI Change in -0.20 0.93 -6.00 8.40 612

unemployment rate from t-1 to t unemployment

ratet

SD of percent change in house Freddie Variance of 2.18 1.21 0.28 10.00 612

price for previous 10 years in t Mac house price

growth,

Six-year average of the BLS Unemployment 5.96 2.69 1.78 22.60 612

unemployment rate in t rate,

Demographic

Percent of loans made in GSE PUDB, Underserved'_l 27.17 12.27 0.00 74.24 612

underserved census tracts HUD/F-42,

in t-1 HMDA

Percent of loan applications by GSE PUDB, MinoritY'_l 16.73 14.51 0.79 94.34 612

minorities in t-1 HUD/F-42,

HMDA

(9)

Table 1. Descriptive Statistics for 1995 and 1996 (continued)

Description Source Variable Mean SD Min Max Obs

Location

High-cost location-median house HUD High cost, 0.700 0.460 0 1 612

prices greater than 75 percent of the Freddie Mac/Fannie Mae conforming loan limit

Medium-cost location-median HUD Medium cost, 0.140 0.350 0 1 612

house prices between 75 and 38 percent of the Freddie Mac/ Fannie Mae conforming loan limit

Vermont, Maine, Connecticut, HUD New 0.036 0.186 0 1 612

Massachusetts, Rhode Island, England,

New Hampshire

Alaska, Idaho, Oregon, HUD Northwest, 0.046 0.209 0 1 612

Washington

Utah, Colorado, South Dakota, HUD Mountain, 0.055 0.228 0 1 612

Wyoming, Montana, North Dakota

Illinois, Indiana, Michigan, HUD Midwest, 0.180 0.384 0 1 612

Minnesota, Ohio, Wisconsin

New York, New Jersey HUD New York/ 0.069 0.253 0 1 612

New JerseYt

Nevada, California, Arizona, HUD Pacific, 0.101 0.302 0 1 612

Hawaii

Texas, Oklahoma, Arkansas, HUD Southwestt 0.150 0.358 0 1 612

New Mexico, Louisiana

Missouri, Iowa, Kansas, Nebraska HUD Great Plains, 0.056 0.230 0 1 612

Florida, Georgia, Kentucky, HUD Southeast, 0.212 0.409 0 1 612

Mississippi, Tennessee, South Carolina, Alabama, Puerto Rico, North Carolina

Delaware, West Virginia, District HUD Middle 0.098 0.298 0 1 612

of Columbia, Virginia, Atlantict

Maryland, Pennsylvania

Notes: ABA, American Bankers Association; BLS, Bureau of Labor Statistics; Census, U.S. Bureau of the Census;

DRI, Standard & Poor's DR!; GSE PUDB, government-sponsored enterprise public-use database; Max, maximum;

Min, minimum; MBA, Mortgage Bankers Association of America; Obs, observations; SD, standard deviation.

Within the subset of subprime originations, the share of mortgages lenders held in portfolio was calculated for each MSA by dividing the number of loans held in portfolio in the MSA by the total number of FHA-eligible sub prime originations in that MSA. The percentage of loans in each MSA sold to private conduits was calculated similarly. Given the elevated risks of ter-mination for subprime loans, it is not surprising that 93 percent of the FHA-eligible sub prime mortgages were sold. As indicated by the large standard deviations in table 1, there is sub-stantial variation in loan dispositions by MSA.

(10)

To assess the risk associated with each MSA, measures of economic and demographic charac-teristics are included. Economic characcharac-teristics include the performance of the housing mar-ket and the labor marmar-ket. Demographic characteristics include racial indicators, the presence of under served households (as defined by HUD), and the extent of racial segregation.

Economic Risk

The movement of house prices can have a strong effect on credit risk, default probabilities, loss severity, and the profitability of loans. 9 The yearly percentage change in local house prices and the standard deviation of change in house prices over the past 10 years are included to measure whether house prices moved up or down and whether they were stable or volatile. If

prime lenders are more active in lower risk areas or high-growth areas, the percentage change in house prices should be positively associated with prime market shares and negatively asso-ciated with FHA and subprime shares. The standard deviation in house prices may indicate greater risk to lenders; therefore, FHA and subprime market shares should be higher as volatility increases.

To measure local labor market conditions, changes in local employment, as measured by the yearly change in the local unemployment rate and the average unemployment rate for each MSA over the past six years, are included. Again, it is expected that if unemployment increases or is historically high, it will be more likely that homeowners will have trouble mak-ing timely payments on outstandmak-ing debt and, as a result, will be considered higher risk borrowers.

When considering the disposition of subprime mortgages after their origination, it is useful to group the economic risk proxies into short-run changes and long-run characteristics. For instance, the change in house prices and the change in the unemployment rate represent short-run events, whereas the stability of house prices and the average unemployment rate are determined over a longer historical period. If information asymmetries exist as origina-tors of subprime loans sell loans to private conduits, it may be easier to take advantage of short-run events rather than historical trends. In addition, different participants in the sec-ondary market may value risks associated directly with the housing market differently than risks associated with the labor market. Lastly, originators that sell most of their loans should be more concerned with short-run changes in conditions (warehousing risk) than entities that hold the long-term risk of termination (Benjamin, Heuson, and Sirmans 1997).

Demographics

Demographic factors such as race, spatial segregation, and living in traditionally under-served locations are not measures of risk but have been included in econometric models on the selection of FHA insurance in the mortgage market (for example, Gabriel and Rosenthal

9 See Capozza, Kazarian, and Thomson (1997), Deng and Calhoun (1997), and Ambrose and Capone (1998). Other

(11)

1991, and Pennington-Cross and Nichols 2000). If the racial/ethnic characteristics of home buyers are uncorrelated with missing variables, there should be no relationship between race/ethnicity and mortgage type. Gabriel and Rosenthal (1991) and Ambrose and Pennington-Cross (2000) found that minorities are more likely to use FHA than conven-tional financing. In contrast, Pennington-Cross and Nichols (2000) showed that after in-cluding detailed credit history in addition to other measures of lending standards, Mrican-American households actually were less likely than white households to use FHA financing. Because the analysis in this article does not include credit history, it is expected that results will suggest that minority households are more likely to use FHA-insured financing and subprime lending.

Pennington-Cross and Nichols (2000) and Ambrose and Pennington-Cross (2000) have shown that whether or not credit history is included, home buyers use FHA financing more often in underserved locations, as defined by HUD. If this is one way that lenders adjust behavior to meet Community Reinvestment Act (CRA) requirements, the same results might hold for sub prime lending.

A measure of local segregation is included to determine whether market shares vary depend-ing on the level of racial segregation. Segregation was measured by the spatial distribution of different groups across the local region and was derived using census data from 1990 from the Lorenz curve with values between 0 and 100, with 100 indicating maximum segregation (Massey and Denton 1988). This typically is referred to as the Gini coefficient.

Finally, indicators of whether the MSA is high-, medium-, or low-cost are included. Because of the way FHA sets loan limits, FHA-eligible borrowers in the more expensive areas cover a

smaller fraction of the market.io The borrowers examined in this article represent those in

the cheapest part of the market in high-cost areas. Therefore, in high-cost areas borrowers would tend to have more difficulty amassing a down payment or meeting other financial oblig-ations, and they may use FHA and subprime lending more frequently. In addition, variables to control for regional (HUD-defined regions of the United States) and time (a 1995 indica-tor) effects are included.

When considering the demographic variables and their role in the final disposition of sub-prime loans, the focus of the analysis shifts to the costs and benefits of holding loans in port-folio versus selling them into the secondary market. An institution that needs to increase its CRA-eligible loan count may decide to hold more of these loans in portfolio to get credit

beyond origination. It also may be more difficult to make homogeneous or large enough pools

with loans from underserved locations for aggregation.l l Ambrose and Pennington-Cross

(2000) found that prime loans are more likely to be held in portfolio in areas with more underserved households. If borrowers in underserved census tracts are more likely to be

10 FHA loan limits are capped at the same fixed nominal dollar amount for all high-cost metropolitan areas. In

con-trast, loan limits vary depending on house prices in medium-cost metropolitan areas.

11 eRA-eligible loans are not double counted, however. For instance, loans that are counted because they are

(12)

eRA

eligible, it is likely that depository institutions, or subprime lenders who wish to merge with depository institutions, may hold more loans in portfolio to improve their marketabil-ity. Lastly, the growth of subprime lending is a relatively new phenomenon and its accep-tance (in both the primary and secondary markets) is unlikely to be uniform in different locations or in different segments of the mortgage market.

Results

The market shares were calculated for 306 MSAs for 4,584,3511995 and 1996 loans. Loan dis-position of sub prime lending was calculated for 45,359 loans from 1995 and 1996 in 294 MSAs. The logistic estimation technique weights each observation (market share) by the number of loans in each MSA. For large samples such as the primary market estimates, this technique may lead to artificially low standard error estimates (Greene 1990). Sensitivity analysis using graphical displays and standardized marginal effects were used to identify the economic importance of individual factors.

Primary Market

Table 2 provides the results of the multinomial logit estimation, and table 3 presents the standardized marginal effects evaluated at the mean. The model predicts that the prime market share (evaluated at the data means) is 78 percent, the FHA market share is 21 per-cent, and the sub prime market share is 1 percent. This compares with the actual mean mar-ket shares of 79 percent, 20 percent, and 1 percent for prime, FHA, and subprime lending, respectively. The results show that prime lending is more likely in locations with less eco-nomic risk, and FHA and subprime lending are more active when local risks are higher. No single factor implies that sub prime lending can become a substantial proportion of any local mortgage market.

Economic Risk. If the growth in house price increases one standard deviation from the mean

of 4.3 percent, then prime, FHA, and subprime market shares change from their means by 2, -7, and 2 percent, respectively.12 The market share of subprime lending is most sensitive to changes in the unemployment rate. If the change in the unemployment rate is moved from the mean of -0.2 percent to 0.73 (one standard deviation increase), the subprime market share increases 5 percent. In comparison, the magnitude of the same effect on prime and FHA

market shares is negligible (less than 0.1 percent). In locations where the unemployment rate has been historically high, there tends to be more subprime lending and slightly less FHA-insured lending. In summary, subprime lending is most prevalent in locations with weak labor

market conditions and declining house prices. FHA insurance is most active in locations with very poor housing market conditions-declining and volatile house prices.

12 Note that the percent change is defined as a percent increase, not a percentage point increase. For example, 0.05,

(13)

Table 2. Multinomial Logit Model of Mortgage Choice

FHA Subprime

Variable Parameter t-statistic Parameter t-statistic

Constant -0.75 -57.1 -4.05 -77.6

House price growtht -3.43 -57.8 -1.47 -6.3

Change in unemployment ratet 0.41 2.0 10.98 16.0

Variance of house price growtht 5.18 49.4 -4.43 -9.7

Unemployment ratet -0.71 -9.6 1.63 6.1 U nderservedt_1 -1.65 -81.5 -0.86 -11.0 MinoritYt_1 0.71 45.4 0.38 6.3 Segregationt 0.00 -12.6 0.00 5.3 Medium costt 0.34 41.2 -0.33 -12.6 High costt 0.22 23.0 -0.52 -16.2 Northwestt -0.75 -93.5 0.22 5.7 Midwestt -0.55 -76.6 -0.02 -0.5

New York/New Jersey! -1.04 -124.4 0.18 4.8

Pacifict -0.21 -30.8 0.86 25.3 Southwestt 0.06 8.0 0.86 23.5 Great Plainst -0.29 -33.8 0.04 0.8 Southeastt -0.30 -44.0 0.55 15.6 New Englandt -1.62 -152.5 0.08 1.8 Middle Atlantict -0.04 -5.1 0.00 0.0 1995 -0.11 -37.7 -0.33 -28.1 Log of likelihood -2,557,716

Note: The excluded category is the market share of prime mortgages. Therefore, coefficients are to be interpreted as increasing or decreasing the market share of the column choice relative to prime. Because it is difficult to interpret these coefficients, see the standardized marginal effects in table 3 for an economic interpretation of the results.

Demographic Characteristics. There is some limited evidence that HUD affordable housing

goals may increase the presence of prime lending instead of subprime lending in underserved census tracts. In support of the positions taken by some housing advocates and government agencies (for example, the Woodstock Institute and HUD), the presence of subprime lending is higher in locations that experience more racial isolation. One standard deviation increase in the segregation index leads to a 4 percent increase in the subprime market share but has no effect on prime lending.

As shown in table 3, borrowers located in the least expensive MSAs are more than one-third less likely to use subprime lending than borrowers in medium- and high-cost locations.13 In addition, FHA lending is more likely to be used in medium- and high-cost locations. This is logical, because FHA's insurance program focuses on low down payments, which may be a more important factor in high-cost locations.

13 In table 3, for the reported dummy variables (0,1 indicators, which includes all variables after Segregation),

stand-ardized marginal effects show the percent change in the probability of the outcome if the dummy variable is increased from 0 to 1 and all other variables are evaluated at their means.

(14)

Table 3. Standardized Multinomial Logit Model Marginal Effects

Variable Prime FHA Subprime

House price growtht 0.02 -0.07 -0.02

Change in unemployment ratet 0.00 0.00 0.11

Variance of house price growtht -0.01 0.05 -0.06

Unemployment rate, 0.00 -0.02 0.05 U nderservedt_1 0.04 -0.15 -0.06 MinoritYt_l -0.02 0.08 0.03 Segregationt 0.00 -0.02 0.04 Medium costt -0.06 0.32 -0.33 High costf -0.04 0.19 -0.43 Northwestt 0.12 -0.47 0.39 Midwestf 0.11 -0.36 0.08

New York/New JerseYt 0.16 -0.59 0.40

Pacifict 0.03 -0.17 1.44 Southwestf -0.02 0.04 1.31 Great Plains, 0.05 -0.21 0.09 Southeast! 0.05 -0.22 0.82 New Englandt 0.21 -0.76 0.31 Middle Atlantict 0.01 -0.03 0.01 1995 0.03 -0.08 -0.26

Note: Standardized marginal effects for continuous variables are defined as the percent change in the fraction of loans using prime, FHA, or subprime lending in response to one standard deviation increase in the explanatory vari-able. For dummy variables, which include all variables after Segregation in the table, standardized marginal effects indicate the percent change in the dependent variable as the explanatory variable is increased from 0 to 1. In all cases all other variables are evaluated at their means. The percent change is defined as a percent increase, not a

percent-age point increase. For example, 0.05 indicates that a market share of 30 percent would increase to 31.5 percent =

30 X 1.05.

Looking at variations across regions, prime market share is highest in New England, whereas FHA and subprime market shares are highest in the Southwest. The magnitude of the mar-ginal effects indicates that there is a substantial amount of regional variation not explained by the model, which requires further study.

Subprime Loan Disposition

This section examines the disposition of FHA-eligible subprime mortgages in the secondary market. Loans are either held in portfolio or sold to a private conduit. The results are pre-sented in tables 4 and 5. Table 4 provides the coefficient estimates and t-statistics, and table 5 provides the standardized marginal effects. These marginal effects represent the percent change, not the percentage point change, in the fraction of loans that sub prime lenders hold in portfolio in response to an increase of one standard deviation in the explanatory variable from its mean value. For dummy variables, which include all variables after Minority in the table, the percent change is in response to an increase of the explanatory dummy from 0 to 1, whereas all other variables are evaluated at their means.

(15)

Table 4. Logit Model of Subprime Loan Disposition

Contemporaneous Contemporaneous and Lagged

Information Information

Variable Parameter t-statistic Parameter t-statistic

Constant -3.83 -17.82 -2.40 -10.22

House price growtht 1.77 2.08 8.63 8.39

House price growtht_l -9.00 -14.39

Change in unemployment ratet -0.11 -5.04 0.01 0.48

Change in unemployment ratet_l -0.32 -9.56

Variance of house price growth, 0.12 7.02 0.10 5.84

Unemployment ratet 0.04 4.49 0.03 3.54 U nderservedt_l 3.97 14.25 4.36 14.66 MinoritYt_1 -1.49 -6.00 -1.49 -5.74 Segregation, 0.02 12.10 0.02 12.23 Medium costt -1.30 -17.41 -1.43 -19.07 High cost, -1.44 -13.94 -1.96 -18.03 Northwestt 0.20 1.09 -0.08 -0.41 Midwestt 0.57 3.31 0.01 0.04

New York/New JerseYt -0.64 -3.25 -1.48 -7.15

Pacifict 0.96 5.90 -0.13 -0.74 Southwestt -0.12 -0.66 -1.10 -5.90 Great Plainst 0.41 2.09 -0.44 -2.17 Southeast, 0.15 0.87 -0.68 -3.82 New Englandt 1.60 8.18 1.07 5.22 Middle Atlantic, -0.08 -0.44 -0.91 -4.66 1995 -0.50 -10.20 -1.23 -18.27 Log of likelihood -11,255 -11,085

Note: Coefficient estimates are interpreted as increasing or decreasing the fraction of loans that the lender holds in

portfolio. See table 5 for economic interpretation.

Table 5 shows that for the contemporaneous information results (the first column), all of the economic and demographic variables are significant at the 5 percent level. In general, as local economic risks deteriorate, subprime lenders are contemporaneously more likely to sell loans and less likely to hold loans in portfolio. However, when local economic conditions are histor-ically poor, subprime lenders are more likely to hold loans in portfolio. These potentially con-tradictory results imply either that subprime lenders and private conduits must have different views of the effects of local economic conditions on the profitability of mortgages, or that informational asymmetries are affecting the retain/sell decision.

One potential explanation is that long-term or historical indicators of risk are likely to be known by both local originators and "arm's-length" participants in the secondary market. In contrast, changes in local economic conditions are more likely to be known locally (by the orig-inating institution) first, and only later become known by arm's-length private conduits as the information disseminates. Therefore, the potential for information asymmetries is great-est for changes in risk conditions. The results support this assertion of asymmetric informa-tion and potential adverse selecinforma-tion by finding that subprime originators sell more loans when

(16)

Table 5. Standardized Marginal Effects of Loan Disposition

Variable

House price growth, House price growth'~l

Change in unemployment rate, Change in unemployment rate'~l

Variance of house price growtht Unemployment rate, U nderserved,~ 1 MinoritY'~l Segregation, Medium cost, High cost, Northwest, Midwest,

New York/New Jersey, Pacific, Southwestt Great Plains, Southeastt New England, Middle Atlantic, 1995 Contemporaneous Information, Marginal Effect 0.05 -0.10 0.16 0.12 0.64 -0.20 0.35 -0.73 -0.76 0.22 0.76 -0.47 1.61 -0.11 0.50 0.16 3.96 -0.08 -0040

Contemporaneous and Lagged Information, Marginal Effect

0.25 -0.40 0.01 -0.28 0.13 0.10 0.72 -0.20 0.36 -0.76 -0.86 -0.07 0.01 -0.77 -0.12 -0.67 -0.35 -0.49 1.91 -0.60 -0.71

Note: Standardized marginal effects for continuous variables are defined as the percent change in the fraction of loans held in portfolio in response to one standard deviation increase in the explanatory variable. For dummy vari-ables, which include all variables after Segregation in the table, standardized marginal effects indicate the percent change in the dependent variable as the explanatory variable is increased from 0 to 1. All other variables are evalu-ated at their means. The percent change is defined as a percent increase, not a percentage point increase. For

exam-ple, 0.05 indicates that a retention rate of 30 percent would increase to 31.5 percent = 30 X 1.05.

risks increase and hold onto more loans (whether in pipeline or in portfolio) in locations

his-torically known for high-risk conditions.14

To further test this result, the second columns of tables 4 and 5 report the contemporaneous change in house prices and unemployment rates and the previous year's change in house prices and unemployment rates. The persistence of house prices and unemployment rates requires that this set of results be viewed with caution. The results support the hypothesis that information asymmetries are an important part of the subprime secondary market. For instance, if house prices increase one standard deviation above the mean contemporaneously, sub prime lenders are 25 percent more likely to hold loans in portfolio. In contrast, if this same increase occurred in the previous year, the lender is 40 percent more likely to sell loans to pri-vate conduits.

14 To test for the sensitivity of the results to any potential outliers, all observations with shares ofloans held in

port-folio over 0.50 were excluded, and the regressions rerun. The results were found to be consistent with the reported results. Detailed results are available from the author upon request.

(17)

The results for changes in unemployment rates are not as consistent and may indicate that the attention paid by subprime lenders and private conduits to labor market conditions may differ. Although contemporaneous changes in the unemployment rate are insignificant (almost zero), an increase in the previous year's change in unemployment by one standard deviation leads to a 28 percent decrease in loans held in portfolio. Assuming that informa-tion this old must be known by both parties, this result cannot be driven by asymmetries. However, a long-run increase in unemployment rates does lead to higher rates of loan reten-tion in portfolio.

Theoretical work (Benjamin, Heuson, and Sirmans 1997) has shown that firms that sell their loans into the secondary market are more concerned with short-term changes than long-run cost and benefits. Because most subprime loans are sold, the results also are consistent with this hypothesis.

Focusing on the contemporaneous results, subprime lenders sell their loans 93.36 percent of the time. The model predicts that 5.44 percent of subprime loans are held in portfolio, and 94.56 percent are sold.

To highlight some of the most dramatic results, figures 1 and 2 provide a graphical represen-tation of the sensitivity analysis. As shown in figure 1, an increase in change in the unem-ployment rate from the mean of -0.2 percent to the maximum of 8.4 percent decreases the share of loans held in portfolio from a mean of 5.4 to 2.1 percent. Consistent with previous findings (Ambrose and Pennington-Cross 2000), figure 2 shows that as the underserved frac-tion increases from a mean of27.3 percent to the maximum of 74.2 percent, the share of loans held in portfolio increases from 5.4 to 35.8 percent. This may be explained partly by the pos-sibility that subprime lenders were positioning themselves for acquisition by depositories dur-ing this time, or that it is more difficult to bundle under served loans for sale into the secondary market. Although equating subprime lending with CRA eligibility is not accurate, the ability of subprime lenders to deliver high volumes of CRA-eligible loans likely has played a role in acquisition strategies of depositories since the mid-1990s.

Table 5 shows the standardized marginal estimates for all the variables, and it reinforces the finding that most of the indicators are economically important in addition to being statisti-cally significant. The magnitude of the location and demographic marginal effects indicates that there is substantial variation left unexplained by economic effects. Although the causes ofthese effects are beyond the scope ofthis article, further research is needed to identify why there are such large regional differences in loan retention rates.

Conclusion

This article provides an exploratory look at the role of subprime lending in the primary and secondary markets by examining the spatial distribution of FHA-eligible subprime loans. A list of subprime lenders published by HUD was used, loans were aggregated to the MSA level, and geographic differences in market shares were modeled as a function oflending standards and local economic risk factors.

(18)

.,

§

.3

... 0

...

J:: Q) f:! Q) Il..

Figure 1. Contemporaneous Change in the Unemployment Rate and Loans Held in Portfolio

12 -~---- --~~---~---. 10 2

o

-hTTTTTTn--T r I I I I I I I Tl '"n'lTTTTT I I I I I I I I i I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I i I I I I \ I I i i i I I I i I I I I I I 40 35 30 25 20 15 10 5

o

~6.0 ~5.0 ~4.0 ~3.0 ~2.0 ~1.0 0.0 1.0 2.0 3.0 4.0 5.0 6.0 7.0 8.0

Percent Change in Unemployment Rate

Figure 2. Underserved Borrowers and Loans Held in Portfolio

T I T T T T T T T T T - r T T i T T T T i T T - ' -J I I I I I I I I I I I , r 1'-1- i I I I j I i i i I i i i i i i I I i i i i i i I i I I I i i i i i i i

o

4 8 12 16 20 24 28 32 36 40 44 48 52 56 60 64 68 72

(19)

The empirical results clearly indicate that subprime and FHA market shares are higher in cities with higher economic risk characteristics. Subprime lending is most active in locations with weak labor markets (high and increasing unemployment rates) and declining house prices, whereas FHA lending is most prevalent in locations with poor housing market condi-tions (declining and volatile house prices). In contrast, prime lenders concentrate their origi-nation activity in markets with lower economic risk.

Subprime lenders sell most of their loans to private conduits. They tend to hold more loans in portfolio when local economic risks are improving and in locations that have high long-term risk profiles. In essence, subprime lenders are more willing to accept more risk in loca-tions that are improving than in those that are deteriorating. Two potential explanaloca-tions for this result are that (1) information asymmetries make it easier to sell higher risk loans in changing economic conditions, and (2) primary and secondary market participants estimate the effect of local conditions on the profitability of loans at different rates. In addition, although the vast majority of subprime loans are sold, the presence of underserved borrowers makes it more likely that the loans will be held in portfolio.

These results represent the first step in understanding the role of sub prime lending in the mortgage market. Future research must identify more precisely how households decide to use subprime lending to purchase a home. This requires knowing borrower reserves, credit his-tory, income, and assets, as well as the extent that this information is verifiable. It is also important that researchers and market participants gain a better understanding of how sub-prime loans perform relative to sub-prime mortgages. The private information company MIC has shown that subprime loans are seriously delinquent (90 days or more delinquent or in fore-closure) at least 10 times more often than prime mortgages, and they are prepaid at least twice as fast as prime mortgages (MIC 2000), but very little is known about how these mort-gages will perform in changing economic environments. For subprime lending and the secu-ritization of subprime loans to become part of the mainstream mortgage market, it is vital that the details of how subprime loans perform be better understood.

References

Ambrose, Brent, and Charles Capone. 1998. Modeling the Conditional Probability of Foreclosure in the Context of Single-Family Mortgage Default Resolutions. Real Estate Economics 26(3):391-429.

Ambrose, Brent, and Anthony Pennington-Cross. 2000. Local Economic Risk Factors and the Primary and Secondary Mortgage Market. Regional Science and Urban Economics 30(6):683-702.

Benjamin, John, Andrea Heuson, and Clemon F Sirmans. 1997. Pricing Effects of the Decision To Sell or Hold Adjustable Rate Mortgage Loans in a Portfolio. Financial Review 32(1):1-20.

Brueckner, Jan, and James Follain. 1988. The Rise and Fall of the ARM: An Econometric Analysis of Mortgage Choice. Review of Economics and Statistics 70(1):93-102.

Bunce, Harold, and Randall Scheessele. 1996. The GSEs Funding of Affordable Loans. Housing Finance Working Paper, Series No. HF-OOl. U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development, Office of Pol-icy Development and Research.

(20)

Canner, Glenn, and Stuart Gabriel. 1992. Market Segmentation and Lender Specialization in the Pri-mary and Secondary Mortgage Markets. Housing Policy Debate 3(2):241-332.

Capone, Charles, and Donald Cunningham. 1992. Estimating the Marginal Contribution of Adjustable-Rate Mortgage Selection to Termination Probabilities in a Nested Model. Journal of Real Estate Finance

and Economics 5(4):333-56.

Capozza, Dennis, Dick Kazarian, and Thomas Thomson. 1997. Mortgage Default in Local Markets. Real

Estate Economics 25(4):631-56.

Deng, Young Heng, and Charles Calhoun. 1997. A Dynamic Analysis of Adjustable- and Fixed-Rate Mortgage Termination. Presented at the Allied Social Science Association (American Real Estate and Urban Economics Association) annual meeting, New Orleans, LA. January.

Dhillon, Upinder, James Shilling, and Clemon F Sirmans. 1990. The Mortgage Maturity Decision: The Choice between 15-Year and 30-Year FRMs. Southern Economic Journal 56(4):1103-16.

Gabriel, Stuart, and Stuart Rosenthal. 1991. Credit Rationing, Race, and the Mortgage Market.

Jour-nal of Urban Economics 29(3):371-79.

Gilkeson, James H., Paul Jacob, and Stephen D. Smith. 1994. Buy, Sell, or Hold? Valuing Cash Flows from Mortgage Lending. Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Economic Review 79(6):1-16.

Goodman, John, and Joseph Nichols. 1997. Does FHA Increase Home Ownership or Just Accelerate It?

Journal of Housing Economics 6(2):184-202.

Greene, William. 1990. Econometric Analysis. 2nd ed. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.

Hendershott, Patric, William LaFayette, and Donald Haurin. 1997. Debt Usage and Mortgage Choice: The FHA-Conventional Decision. Journal of Urban Economics 41(2):202-17.

Hendershott, Patric, and Kevin Villani. 1980. Secondary Mortgage Markets and the Cost of Mortgage Funds. Journal of the American Real Estate and Urban Economics Association 8(1):50-76.

Inside Mortgage Finance. 2001. Mortgage Market Statistical Annual. Vol. II. Bethesda, MD.

Joint Center for Housing Studies of Harvard University. 2000. The State of the Nation's Housing 2000. Graduate School of Design and John F Kennedy School of Government.

Kogler, Bernadette. 1997. MorServ Survey 1997. Washington, DC: KPMG.

Linneman, Peter, and Susan Wachter. 1989. The Impacts of Borrowing Constraints on Homeownership.

Journal of the American Real Estate and Urban Economics Association 17(4):389-402.

Massey, Douglas, and Nancy Denton. 1988. The Dimensions of Residential Segregation. Social Forces 67:281-315.

Mortgage Information Corporation. 2000. Subprime Mortgage Delinquencies. Market Pulse (summer/fall):6-7.

Passmore, Wayne, and Roger Sparks. 1996. Putting the Squeeze on the Market for Lemons: Government-Sponsored Mortgage Securitization. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 13(1):27-44.

Pennington-Cross, Anthony, and Joseph Nichols. 2000. Credit History and the FHA-Conventional Choice. Real Estate Economics 28(2):307-36.

(21)

Phillips, Richard, and James VanderHoff. 1994. Alternative Mortgage Instruments, Qualification Con-straints and the Demand for Housing: An Empirical Analysis. Journal of the American Real Estate and

Urban Economics Association 22(3):95-104.

Sa-Aadu, Jarjisu, and Clemon F. Sirmans. 1995. Differentiated Contracts, Heterogeneous Borrowers, and the Mortgage Choice Decision. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 27(2):498-510.

Steinbach, Gorden. 1998. Making Risk-Based Pricing Work. Mortgage Banking (September): 11-20. Tucker, Michael. 1989. Adjustable-Rate and Fixed-Rate Mortgage Choice: A Logit Analysis. Journal of

Real Estate Research 4(2):81-91.

Van Order, Robert. 2001. The Structure of the Mortgage Market in the United States: A Model of Duel-ing Charters. Journal of HousDuel-ing Research 11(2):233-55.

Weicher, John C. 1997. The Home Equity Lending Industry: Refinancing Mortgages for Borrowers with

References

Related documents

To protect regional interests vno-ncw has regional branches: vno- ncw North (Drenthe, Friesland and Groningen provinces), vno-ncw Central (Flevoland, Gelderland, Overijssel

The course saw a close relationship with ATTIK during the 48 duration of the programme where students had the opportunity to get first hand experience of working in

Oz, H. &#34;Morphological Awareness and Some Implications for English Language Teaching&#34;. &#34;Morphological awareness dynamic assessment task in third grade children: a

DARIAH-AAI was established within the ESFRI Digital Research Infrastructure for the Arts and Humanities and consists of web-based services that are protected by SAML

(13) The influence of biological surface agent in the bio-extraction of copper from sulphide minerals Débora de Oliveira, biologist; Luis dos Santos Sobral, researcher and

a Fourth Amendment right to a neutral detached magistrate to review deten- tion for probable cause in the immigration context. 1977) (finding warrantless arrest legal pursuant

The multi-resolution real-time system presents a com- plex composition of three imaging modalities: depth cam- era, 3D scanner and thermal measurement camera. Each component

section, the proportion of the employee' s vacation interrupted shall be deemed to be bereavement leave and the employee shall be entitled to reschedule the vacation credits at