• No results found

The Inefficiency of the Stock Market Equilibrium under Moral Hazard

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "The Inefficiency of the Stock Market Equilibrium under Moral Hazard"

Copied!
11
0
0

Loading.... (view fulltext now)

Full text

(1)

No. 2003ā€“107

THE INEFFICIENCY OF THE STOCK

MARKET EQUILIBRIUM UNDER MORAL HAZARD By R. Calcagno, W. Wagner

November 2003

(2)

Ine

ļ¬ƒ

ciency of the Stock Market Equilibrium with

Moral Hazard

āˆ—

Riccardo Calcagno

Tilburg University

Wolf Wagner

Cambridge University

Abstract

This paper studies the eļ¬ƒciency of a stock market equilibrium. We extend a standard general equilibrium framework with moral hazard (Magill and Quinzii1999, 2002) to allow for a more general initial ownership distribution offirms. We show that the market allocation is constrained-eļ¬ƒcient only when in eachfirm the entrepreneur who generates payoļ¬€s through unobservable eļ¬€ort has the full initial property rights to his firm.

Keywords: stock market equilibrium, moral hazard, general equilibrium, constrained optimality

JEL Classification: D51, D52, D62, D82, G14

āˆ—We would like to thank Michael Magill, Heraklis Polemarchakis and Martine Quinzii for their valuable

(3)

1

Introduction

Can stock markets perform their role of allocating resources eļ¬ƒciently in the presence of moral hazard? Obviously, when production depends on entrepreneurial eļ¬€ort (which is neither verifiable nor contractible), one cannot expect thefirst best to be achieved. This is because risk-sharing and financing motives require that an entrepreneur sells parts of his

firm but in doing this he reduces his incentives to exert eļ¬€ort in thefirm, thus creating an ineļ¬ƒciency (Jensen and Meckling, 1976). A more appropriate question is therefore to ask whether a stock market operates eļ¬ƒciently relative to the moral hazard problem (this is the concept of constrained-eļ¬ƒciency dating back to Diamond, 1967), i.e., whether a social planner who cannot create new assets and who cannot observe individual eļ¬€orts is unable to improve the market allocation.

Several authors have addressed this issue (e.g. Kihlstrom and Mathews, 1990, Kocher-lakota, 1998, Lisboa, 2001, Magill and Quinzii, 1999, 2002), showing that a stock market can be indeed (constrained)-eļ¬ƒcient. The intuition of this result is that investors are aware of the entrepreneurā€™s moral hazard problem and lower their valuation of the firm in an-ticipation of a lower eļ¬€ort choice when an entrepreneur sells a stake in his firm. Thus, the ineļ¬ƒciencies stemming from a lower eļ¬€ort choice are internalized by the entrepreneur through the lower price he obtains from selling the firm.

In particular, Magill and Quinzii (1999, 2002) prove the (constrained)-eļ¬ƒciency of the stock market in a standard general equilibrium framework with moral hazard under the assumption that investors correctly infer an entrepreneurā€™s eļ¬€ort from his (observable)

financing decisions and that an entrepreneur cannot influence equilibrium state prices (i.e., price perceptions arerational andcompetitive).

In their analysis, entrepreneurs are all full owners of their firm before trading. In this paper we show that full initial ownership is in fact a necessary condition to obtain constrained eļ¬ƒciency. Intuitively, the reason for this result is a simple externality: an

(4)

entrepreneur does not internalize the ineļ¬ƒciencies imposed on other initial owners when selling hisfirm.

The condition of full initial ownership before trade may not be fulfilled in practice for several reasons. First, venture capitalists typically own a stake in the venture at the time this goes public. Furthermore, stock markets oļ¬€er several opportunities for an entrepreneur to sell shares of his firm: besides at the IPO, an entrepreneur can sell through secondary market trading or with seasoned oļ¬€erings. Hence, even though he may be the full owner of thefirm at the time of going public, he may not be so at each time he trades. Moreover, there may be several owners with a stake in the firm to begin with (e.g., several entrepre-neurs or managers) that trade their stakes in the firm independently. Thus, under quite plausible circumstances, our results imply that a stockmarket will not operate eļ¬ƒciently.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. In the next section we define a stock market equilibrium in a general equilibrium model under moral hazard by extending the framework of Magill and Quinzii (1999) and (2002, Example1) (for brevity, MQ from now on) for a generalized initial ownership in firms. Subsequently, we show that the market equilibrium is (constrained)-ineļ¬ƒcient whenever there is not full initial inside ownership.

2

Stock Market Equilibrium with Moral Hazard

A one-good production economy runs for two periods.1 There are two types of agents in the

economy: entrepreneurs and investors. The set of entrepreneurs and investors is denoted by I1 andI2, respectively. Both sets are assumed to be non-empty and finite. I =I1 āˆŖ I2

is the set of all agents. Each agent i āˆˆI has an initial wealth Ļ‰i0 >0 at t = 0. If agent i is an entrepreneur, then he can obtain an (uncertain) income stream att = 1 by investing

1The exposition in this section is condensed. For a more detailled discussion of the framework and the

(5)

an amount of capital zi āˆˆR+ and exercising eļ¬€ort ei āˆˆR+. The income stream is

Fsi(zi, ei) =fi(zi, ei)Ī·is

where s = 1, ..., S denotes the state of nature andĪ·i = (Ī·1i, ..., Ī·iS)āˆˆ RS+ characterizes the risk structure of the firm. When agent i is an investor we set Ī·i = 0. Each agent has a separable utility function

Ui(xi, ei) = ui0(xi0) +ui1(xi1, ..., xiS)āˆ’ci(ei)

where xi = (xi0, xis, ..., xiS) is the vector of consumption att = 0and in all states at t= 1. For an investor iāˆˆI2, we setei =zi = 0 sinceFsi = 0.

The economy satisfies the following additional assumptions: ui0andui1are diļ¬€erentiable, strictly concave and increasing; ci is diļ¬€erentiable, convex and increasing, with ci(0) = 0. These functions satisfy the boundary conditions

ui00(xi0)āˆ’ā†’ āˆžif xi0 āˆ’ā†’0; for all s= 1, ..., S: āˆ‚ui1/āˆ‚xis āˆ’ā†’ āˆžif xis āˆ’ā†’0; and ci0(0) = 0

i.e., consumption is essential in all states and eļ¬€ort is essentially costless for small levels of eļ¬€ort. fi(zi, ei) is assumed to be diļ¬€erentiable and increasing in(zi, ei) and concave in

zi, with fi(0, ei) =fi(zi,0) = 0 (both inputs are essential).

Entrepreneurs can sell claims to their firms on a stock market (but their eļ¬€ort is still required for production). There is further a single bond traded, which is riskless because we assume that the penalty for bankruptcy is infinite. We deviate from MQ by allowing for a more general initial ownership structure that does not require that an entrepreneur has full ownership in his firm. More formally, we denote an entrepreneurā€™s i initial ownership in his own firm by Īøi0,i (0 < Īøi0,i ā‰¤ 1) and agent j0s, j 6= i, ownership in the firm by Īøj0,i

(Īøj0,i ā‰„0). Feasibility requires that

P

kāˆˆIĪøk0,i = 1 for all iāˆˆI.

The agentsā€™ choices and their timing are as follows. At t= 0, an agentidecides on the amount of capital to invest in his firm zi, the amount to borrow bi, the share of his own

(6)

firm to sell (Īøi0,iāˆ’Īøii), and shares in other firms k 6= i to buy (Īøik āˆ’Īøi0,k). It is assumed

that firmsā€™ income streams Ī·i āˆˆRS+ are linearly independent to ensure that entrepreneurs cannot replicate the income stream of their firm by trading other firms.2 Denote with q0

the price of the bond and with Qi the price of firm i (the price for full ownership of firm

i). The accountability of agent irequires the following budget equations to be satisfied

xi0 = Ļ‰i0+q0bi āˆ’ X k6=i (Īøikāˆ’Īøi0,k)Qk+ (Īø0i,iāˆ’Īøii)Qiāˆ’zi (1) xis = āˆ’bi+ X k6=i Īøikfk(zk, ek)Ī·ks+Īøiifi(zi, ei)Ī·is, s= 1, ..., S (2)

After the financial decisions have been made, the agent chooses his optimal eļ¬€ort if he is an entrepreneur. Since eļ¬€ort is unobservable, the eļ¬€ort choice has only an impact on the agentā€™s income att= 1(through a change in the output of hisfirm). Hence, optimal eļ¬€ort solves

max eiā‰„0{u

i

1(xi1, ..., xiS)āˆ’ci(ei)} (E)

Under some regularity conditions the optimal eļ¬€ort choice is unique and diļ¬€erentiable, and exercising eļ¬€ort is always worthwhile (see assumption MCMP and Proposition1 in Magill and Quinzii, 1999). Because of the uniqueness result we refer to the solution to (E) by

e

e=ee(bi, zi,Īøi).

Allfinancial decisions are assumed to be mutually observable and agentsā€™ preferences are common knowledge. Hence, although eļ¬€ort is not observable, investors can infer from entre-preneurā€™sifinancing decisions(bi, zi,Īøi)the (unique) eļ¬€ort that he will exerciseeei(bi, zi,Īøi). Furthermore, we denote with qi the price of firmiā€™s unit income streamĪ·i. Competitive-ness of agents implies that they take qi as given.3 Thus, for a given financial portfolio

2In MQ, this is ensured by ruling out short sales. This is not suļ¬ƒcient here since entrepreneurs can

have positive endowments in otherfirms.

3Competitive behavior is consistent with our model assumptions: because of the multiplicative structure

of the production technology (Fi = fi(zi, ei)Ī·i), the unit income stream generated byfirm i cannot be changed by varying the production plan(zi, ei).

(7)

(bi, zi,Īøi), rational investors will price firm i at

Qi =qif(zi,eei(bi, zi,Īøi)) (3)

which is in turn the price an entrepreneuriexpects to receive if he chooses(bi, zi,Īøi)(price perceptions are both competitive and rational). This leads to the following definition of a stock market equilibrium.

Definition 1 A stock market equilibrium in an economy with generalized ownership Īø0

consists of actions (x,e,z,b,Īø) and prices q0 and qi (iāˆˆI1) such that

(i) for each agent, (xi, ei) maximizes Ui(xi, ei) subject to (1), (2), with Qi in (1) given by Qi =qif(zi,eei(bi, zi,Īøi)),

(ii) PiāˆˆIbi = 0, (iii) for allk = 1, ..., I : PiāˆˆIĪøik= 1.

3

Ine

ļ¬ƒ

ciency of the Stock Market Equilibrium

An allocation is constrained Pareto optimal (CPO) if a social planner that has to respect the limited availability of assets (bonds and stocks) and the unobservability of eļ¬€ort cannot improve the allocation. Or, in other words, there are no prices and feasible reallocation of

financial assets that lead to a pareto-improvement in the economy. MQ have shown that in an economy where entrepreneurs have full ownership in their firms before trading at the stockmarket, rational and competitive price perceptions induce the entrepreneur to choose an optimal capital structure, and thus guarantee the CPO of the market equilibrium. The following proposition shows that CPO breaks down exactly when there is at least one entrepreneur that has not full initial ownership in his firm (alternatively, we can interpret Proposition 1 as saying that the market equilibrium is CPO only if entrepreneurs are allowed to trade once at the stock market, namely at the first stage of the economy when they have full ownership).

(8)

Proposition 2 The stock market equilibrium is (constrained)-eļ¬ƒcient if and only if there is full initial inside ownership (Īøi0,i = 1 for all iāˆˆI1).

Proof. ā€ifā€ part: Īøi0,i = 1for all iāˆˆI1. This is exactly the case of MQ. For the proof

we refer to them.

ā€only ifā€: Let (x,e,z,b,Īø) with q0 and qi (i āˆˆ I1) be an arbitrary stock market

equilibrium. We show that there exists a feasible reallocation of assets that is pareto-improving if there exists at least one entrepreneur i āˆˆ I1 with Īøi0,i < 1. This proves the

necessity of full initial inside ownership for CPO.

Let Īøi0,i < 1 for one i āˆˆ I1. Consider the following redistribution of shares of firm i:

entrepreneur i0s stake in his ownfirm is increased by an (infinitesimal) small amount dĪøi i,

each entrepreneurā€™sj 6=i stake infirmi is changed by

dĪøji =āˆ’Īøjiāˆ‚f i(zi, ei) āˆ‚ei āˆ‚eei(bi, zi,Īøi) āˆ‚Īøii 1 fi(zi, ei)dĪø i i (4)

and an arbitrary investork0sstake is changed bydĪøk

i =āˆ’dĪøiiāˆ’Pj6=idĪøji. All otherfinancial

decisions(z,b,Īø6=i)and prices q0 andqi, iāˆˆI1, are not changed. For brevity, we suppress

the functionsā€™ arguments from now on whenever the function is evaluated at the original market equilibrium value.

Since dĪøii +PjāˆˆI1\{i}dĪøji + dĪøki = 0, the reallocation is feasible. Furthermore, the

reallocation does not change the eļ¬€ort choice of an entrepreneur j 6= i. We show this by demonstrating that if all eļ¬€ort choicesek,k 6=i, j do not change, the f.o.c.ā€™s for eļ¬€ortej is still fulfilled. From the uniqueness of the eļ¬€ort choice follows then that dej = 0 for j 6=i. The f.o.c. for the eļ¬€ort choiceej (from 2 and E) is

Īøjj X sāˆˆS āˆ‚uj1(xjs) āˆ‚xjs āˆ‚fj(zj, ej) āˆ‚ej Ī· j sāˆ’cj0(ej) = 0 (5)

Thus, if the reallocation does not aļ¬€ect income xjs at t = 1 for all s = 1, ...S , (5) is still

(9)

do not change that dxjs(ej) = Īøjiāˆ‚f i āˆ‚ei āˆ‚eei āˆ‚ĪøiiĪ· i sdĪøii+fiĪ·isdĪøji = Īøjiāˆ‚f i āˆ‚ei āˆ‚eei āˆ‚ĪøiidĪø i iĪ·isāˆ’fiĪ·isĪøjiāˆ‚f i āˆ‚ei āˆ‚eei āˆ‚Īøii 1 fidĪø i i = 0 (6)

i.e., the impact of higher eļ¬€ort byi onj0s income at t= 1(first term) is exactly oļ¬€set by

a reduction in j0s stake infirmi (second term). Hence, for allj 6=i, the f.o.c. for eļ¬€ort is

fulfilled and thus dej = 0 for all j 6=i.

Next we show that the reallocation is pareto-improving. We know that the f.o.c. for the choice of the optimal amount of shares in firm i for entrepreneur i and an investor m

must be fulfilled at the market equilibrium. From (1), (2) and (3) these are

Īøiiāˆ— : u0(xi0)[āˆ’qifi+ (Īø0i,iāˆ’Īøii)qiāˆ‚fāˆ‚eiiāˆ‚ee i āˆ‚Īøi i]+ P sāˆˆS āˆ‚ui1(xi s) āˆ‚xi s [f iĪ·i s] + Āµ P sāˆˆS āˆ‚ui1(xi s) āˆ‚xi s Īø i iāˆ‚f i āˆ‚eiĪ·isāˆ’ci0(ei) Ā¶ āˆ‚eei āˆ‚Īøi i = 0 (7) Īømi āˆ— : u0(xm0 )[āˆ’qifi] + P sāˆˆS āˆ‚um 1 (xms) āˆ‚xms [fiĪ·is] = 0 (8)

Now we can compute the utility change for an entrepreneur j 6= i. Since dxjs = 0 and

dek = 0for k 6=i, we have dUj = u0(xj0)[āˆ’(Īøji āˆ’Īøj0,i)qiāˆ‚f i āˆ‚ei āˆ‚eei āˆ‚ĪøiidĪø i iāˆ’qifidĪøji] (9) = u0(xj0)Īøj0,iqi āˆ‚fi āˆ‚ei āˆ‚eei āˆ‚ĪøiidĪø i i ā‰„0

where the last line is obtained by using (4) to substitutedĪøji. For an investorkwe get with (8) dUk = u0(xk0)[(Īøk0,iāˆ’Īøki)qiāˆ‚f i āˆ‚ei āˆ‚eei āˆ‚ĪøiidĪø i i āˆ’dĪøkiqifi] + X sāˆˆS āˆ‚uk1 Ā” xksĀ¢ āˆ‚xks [Īøkiāˆ‚f i āˆ‚ei āˆ‚eei āˆ‚ĪøiidĪø i iĪ·is+dĪøkifiĪ·is] = u0(xk0)Īøk0,iqiāˆ‚f i āˆ‚ei āˆ‚eei āˆ‚ĪøiidĪø i i ā‰„0 (10)

and for any investor l 6=k we have

dUl = u0(xl0)[(Īøl0,iāˆ’Īøli)qiāˆ‚f i āˆ‚ei āˆ‚eei āˆ‚ĪøiidĪø i i] + X sāˆˆS āˆ‚ul1 Ā” xlsĀ¢ āˆ‚xls [Īøliāˆ‚f i āˆ‚ei āˆ‚eei āˆ‚ĪøiidĪø i iĪ·is] = u0(xl0)Īøl0,iqiāˆ‚f i āˆ‚ei āˆ‚eei āˆ‚ĪøiidĪø i i ā‰„0 (11)

(10)

Finally, for entrepreneur i we have dUi =u0(xi0)[(Īøi0,iāˆ’Īøii)qiāˆ‚f i āˆ‚ei āˆ‚eei āˆ‚ĪøiidĪø i iāˆ’qifidĪøii]+ X sāˆˆS āˆ‚ui1 Ā” xisĀ¢ āˆ‚xis [Īø i iāˆ‚f i āˆ‚ei āˆ‚eei āˆ‚ĪøiidĪø i iĪ·is+fiĪ·isdĪøiiāˆ’ci 0 (ei)āˆ‚ee i āˆ‚Īøii = 0

because of (7). Hence, no agent is worse oļ¬€ and because of Īøi0,i < 1 there exists at least

one agent m6=iwith Īøm0,i >0, who is strictly better oļ¬€ by (9), (10) or (11). 4

The intuition for the existence of a Pareto-improving reallocation if there is initial outside ownership is straightforward. Since the entrepreneur does not internalize the

inef-ficiency losses on initial outside owners when selling hisfirm, an increase in his stake in the

firm reduces this externality and makes all initial outside owners better oļ¬€ while having only a second order impact on all other agents.

4

Conclusions

In this paper we show that the contrained-eļ¬ƒciency of decentralized stock markets breaks down when entrepreneurs do not have full ownership in their firms before market trading. Hence, a stock market generally does not fulfill its function of allocating resources opti-mally across agents. The question arises of how eļ¬ƒciency can be ensured. Government intervention, through appropriate taxes, may help to restore eļ¬ƒciency (see, for example, Geanakoplos and Polemarchakis, 2003). Alternatively, retaining the decentralization of the economy, other organizational forms, like the competitive pools of Dubey and Geanakoplos (2002) can possibly overcome the externalities posed by entrepreneurs on initial owners. One specific way to eliminate the externality shown in this paper would be to use contracts that limit the possibilities for entrepreneurs to divest their stake in the firm through the stock market without the previous agreement of the initial owners (as analyzed in Wagner, 2002).

(11)

References

[1] Diamond, P. A. (1967) "The Role of a Stock Market in a General Equilibrium Model with Technological Uncertainty". American Economic Review 57: pp. 759-773. [2] Dubey, P. and J. D. Geneakoplos (2002) "Competitive Pooling: Rothschild-Stiglitz

Reconsidered". The Quarterly Journal of Economics 117: pp. 1529-1570.

[3] Geanakoplos, J. D. and H. M. Polemarchakis (2003) "Pareto improving taxes".Mimeo, Yale University.

[4] Kocherlakota, N.R. (1998) "The eļ¬€ects of moral hazard on asset prices whenfinancial markets are complete". Journal of Monetary Economics 41: pp. 39-56.

[5] Lisboa, M. B. (2001) "Moral Hazard and General Equilibrium in Large Economies".

Economic Theory 18: pp. 555-575.

[6] Jensen, M. and W. H. Meckling (1976) "Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and Ownership Structure". Journal of Financial Economics 3: pp. 305-360.

[7] Kihlstrom, R.E. and S. A. Matthews (1990) "Managerial incentives in an entrepre-neurial stock market model".Journal of Financial Intermediation 1: pp. 57-79. [8] Magill, M. and M. Quinzii (1999) "Incentives and Risk-Sharing in a Stock Market

Equilibrium" in Current Trends in Economics: Theory and Applications, A. Alkan, D.D.Aliprantis, N.C. Yannelis eds., Springer Verlag.

[9] Magill, M. and M. Quinzii (2002) "Capital Market Equilibrium with Moral Hazard".

Journal of Mathematical Economics 38, pp. 149-190.

[10] Wagner, W. (2002) "Divestment, Entrepreneurial Incentives, and the Decision to Go Public", CentER Discussion Paper no. 2002-47.

References

Related documents

Taking all three lemmas above, we can conclude that for &lt; o , there is only a separating equilibrium that is essentially the same as the full information equilibrium. Here, the

taking account of the objectives, financial situation or needs of any particular individual.. It

With group drives, the 24 V safety inputs of several MOVIDRIVE Ā® MDX60B/61B units can be made available via a single safety relay. The maximum number of axis modules results from

A importance for my job Competency Areas (1-10) B importance for my professional growth (MO) C current knowledge skill level (MO) D work priority measure (A-C) E professional

Procurement All stages of the alternative contracting process for acquiring project management, design, and construction services for a design-build contract.. Project Manager (PM)

This research proposal effort aims at analyzing the physical properties of Papercrete such as density, water absorption capacity, compressive strength,

Po přesnĆ©m provedenĆ­ pilotnĆ­ho vrtu je konec soutyčƭ opět osazen speciĆ”lnĆ­ rozÅ”iřovacĆ­ hlavou (Obr. Za touto hlavou nĆ”sleduje kolona ocelovĆ½ch chrĆ”niček,

general SUrgICal InStrUmentS neeDle HOlDerS anD SUtUre