• No results found

Price determination in Ireland effects of changes in exchange rates and exchange rate regimes

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2020

Share "Price determination in Ireland effects of changes in exchange rates and exchange rate regimes"

Copied!
24
0
0

Loading.... (view fulltext now)

Full text

(1)

The Economic and Social Review, Vol. 20, No. 2, January 1989, pp. 165-188

Price Determination in Ireland: Effects of Changes

in Exchange Rates and Exchange Rate Regimes*

T I M C A L L A N and J O H N F I T Z G E R A L D

The Economic and Social Research Institute, Dublin

Abstract: This paper finds that the wholesale price of Irish manufacturing o u t p u t is closely tied t o

foreign prices i n the long r u n ; domestic wage costs generally do not exert a significant influence. I n the short run changes i n foreign currency prices affect Irish prices more rapidly than do changes i n exchange rates. There is evidence of a change i n pricing behaviour on Ireland's entry i n t o the EMS. German out­ put prices are now as i m p o r t a n t as U K prices i n determining Irish prices.

I I N T R O D U C T I O N

I

t is w e l l established b y n o w that short-run purchasing p o w e r p a r i t y does n o t h o l d between major countries (see, for example, Frenkel, 1981 or Isard, 1977). This means that one cannot define an empirical counterpart t o the single w o r l d price o f simple small open economy (SOE) models. Several approaches can be adopted t o dealing w i t h this p r o b l e m o f m o d e l l i n g the i n f l u ­ ence o f foreign prices o n the domestic prices o f a small c o u n t r y . When Ireland's exchange rate was f i x e d at p a r i t y w i t h sterling the d o m i n a n t approach adopted i n empirical w o r k was the use o f prices i n the U K , Ireland's largest trade partner, t o p r o x y w o r l d prices. The alternative, o f using a trade-weighted basket o f the prices o f Ireland's major trade partners, has also been given con­ siderable a t t e n t i o n .

I n this paper we reassess these results, a l l o w i n g for differences i n the short-r u n short-response t o exchange short-rates and foshort-reign pshort-rices, and foshort-r possible changes

(2)

i n the relative i m p o r t a n c e o f U K and German prices associated w i t h Ireland's membership o f the European M o n e t a r y System (EMS). We use quarterly data on the wholesale prices o f the o u t p u t o f m a n u f a c t u r i n g i n d u s t r y . Wholesale prices do n o t include V A T or retail d i s t r i b u t i o n costs, so they p r o v i d e more direct evidence o n the influence o f foreign prices than consumer prices, w h i c h also include a m u c h larger non-traded c o m p o n e n t . We allow for the possibility o f differential response t o foreign currency price changes and exchange rate changes. We investigate possible changes i n the relative importance o f dif­ ferent countries, or other changes i n the influence o f foreign prices arising f r o m or associated w i t h Ireland's EMS membership. Specifically, we examine econometric tests o f the f o l l o w i n g questions:

(1) A r e Irish prices p r o p o r t i o n a l t o foreign prices i n Irish currency i n the l o n g run?

(2) D o domestic u n i t wage costs exert at least a short-run influence o n prices, as a mark-up m o d e l o f p r i c i n g w o u l d suggest?

(3) D o Irish prices react similarly i n the short r u n t o changes i n foreign currency prices and t o exchange rate changes, or is there a differential response?

(4) Is there evidence o f an asymmetric response o f Irish prices t o increases and decreases i n foreign prices?

(5) W h i c h specification o f foreign price variables performs best: U K prices alone, a trade-weighted index, or the prices o f several major com­ petitors?

(6) Has e n t r y t o the EMS l e d t o a change i n the relative influence o f dif­ ferent countries, or t o any other changes i n the relationship between foreign and domestic prices?

The remainder o f the paper is stuctured as follows. A brief review o f pre­ vious w o r k o n price d e t e r m i n a t i o n i n I r e l a n d is given i n Section I I . Section I I I describes the basic m o d e l and Section I V gives results on the six m a i n ques­ tions o u t l i n e d above, based o n analysis o f wholesale price indices for manu­ facturing i n d u s t r y treated as an aggregate. Section V deals briefly w i t h the results o f a p p l y i n g the basic m o d e l t o the data o n the o u t p u t prices o f i n d i ­ vidual i n d u s t r i a l sectors. Section V I draws together the m a i n conclusions.

I I R E V I E W O F P R E V I O U S W O R K

(3)

The conclusions f r o m this w o r k , as summarised b y H o n o h a n and F l y n n ( 1 9 8 6 ) , were t h a t " I r i s h price i n f l a t i o n was determined b y , and more or less equal t o , U K i n f l a t i o n . " (p. 175).

This evidence l e d t o a widespread expectation t h a t EMS membership w o u l d r a p i d l y result i n the Irish rate o f i n f l a t i o n being determined i n a similar fashion by German i n f l a t i o n . The experience o f EMS membership has been rather different. Whereas, i n the sterling l i n k p e r i o d , there was n o u n c e r t a i n t y con­ cerning the future value o f the sterling exchange rate, the relationship between the I r i s h p o u n d and the Deutschmark has n o t remained f i x e d over t i m e and firms have been faced w i t h u n c e r t a i n t y about future rates o f exchange between the Irish p o u n d and other EMS currencies. The u n c e r t a i n t y concerning the rate o f exchange between the Irish p o u n d and sterling, w h i c h has remained outside the EMS, has been even greater. The p a t t e r n o f I r i s h i n f l a t i o n since j o i n i n g the EMS cannot be explained b y the simple SOE m o d e l o f price deter­ m i n a t i o n : i t is no longer closely t i e d t o the U K rates, and i t has n o t m i r r o r e d German rates. A t first sight, this suggested a change i n the foreign influence on I r i s h prices. However, H o n o h a n and F l y n n ' s analysis o f the 1972-1984 p e r i o d showed that a more flexible dynamic specification o f the influence of foreign prices, using a trade-weighted index rather than s i m p l y U K prices, c o u l d y i e l d an adequate m o d e l for b o t h the sterling l i n k and EMS sub-periods.

Neither H o n o h a n and F l y n n ' s trade-weighted approach, nor the earlier w o r k based o n U K prices, examined the question o f whether the relative i m p o r t a n c e o f different countries' prices i n determining Irish prices has changed over t i m e , i n particular i n response t o Ireland's membership o f the European M o n e t a r y System (EMS). The use o f trade weights, w h i l e valuable for m a n y purposes, implies that the relative i m p o r t a n c e changes i f and o n l y i f trade patterns change, thus s i m p l y imposing an answer t o the question. The use o f U K prices does n o t even allow this l i m i t e d a m o u n t o f f l e x i b i l i t y .

F i t z G e r a l d (1983) e x p l o r e d the issue using data disaggregating foreign price influence b y c o u n t r y . However, that analysis was l i m i t e d b y the small number o f post-EMS observations. The approach adopted there, and e x p l o r e d i n more detail here, was t o regress Irish o u t p u t prices against the prices o f Ireland's major c o m p e t i t o r s , n o t a b l y the U K , Germany and the U S A , a l l o w i n g the relative importance o f different countries t o be more d i r e c t l y determined f r o m the data. A priori one w o u l d expect considerable difference i n behaviour between domestic Irish firms and foreign-owned firms, and also between dif­ ferent sectors. I n order t o examine this p o s s i b i l i t y , we repeat the analysis for selected sectors o f m a n u f a c t u r i n g i n d u s t r y (as d i d F i t z G e r a l d ) , some o f w h i c h are d o m i n a t e d b y m u l t i n a t i o n a l s , and others b y domestic f i r m s .1

(4)

FitzGerald also f o u n d a stronger response t o sterling price changes i n the p e r i o d 1979-81 than t o sterling exchange rate changes, although attempts t o disaggregate the exchange rate and foreign currency price changes for other countries gave less satisfactory results. This analysis strongly suggested further investigation o f differential effects o f exchange rate and foreign currency price changes, a topic neglected i n other analyses o f Irish price d e t e r m i n a t i o n .

Leddin's ( 1 9 8 8 ) more recent analysis has investigated some o f the issues addressed here, also using wholesale price index data for manufacturing i n d u s t r y . However, Leddin's specification imposed some crucial r e s t r i c t i o n s2

w h i c h our tests indicate are rejected by the data. His conclusion, that short-r u n pushort-rchasing poweshort-r p a short-r i t y does n o t h o l d , is supposhort-rted by oushort-r moshort-re extensive tests, b u t our results show t h a t a long-run version o f purchasing power p a r i t y ( n o t tested b y L e d d i n ) may h o l d .

I l l B A S I C M O D E L A N D T H E D A T A

We begin w i t h t w o alternative general models w h i c h express the long-run d e t e r m i n a t i o n o f the level o f prices i n I r e l a n d ; these t w o models represent the polar cases o f the pure SOE m o d e l and the closed economy alternative where prices are determined as a mark-up o n i n p u t costs.

pi * R = fi (piIV >i = 1>n) W

PI*R= f2( Wj; j = l , m ) (2)

where

P*R = the long-run desired wholesale price for Irish manufacturing o u t p u t

P. = the wholesale price for manufacturing o f c o u n t r y i R. = the rate o f exchange between Ireland and c o u n t r y i Wj = the price index for i n p u t factor j .3

I f prices are p u r e l y externally determined, as i n E q u a t i o n ( 1 ) , then, assum­ ing that purchasing power p a r i t y holds i n the long r u n , Irish prices w i l l be some weighted average o f the prices o f a possible range o f other countries, all expressed i n Irish p o u n d terms. I f , o n the other hand, they are purely deter­ m i n e d as a mark-up o n domestic costs, then E q u a t i o n (2) is appropriate. I n examining the behaviour o f o u t p u t prices we test for whether either of these t w o long-run models o f price d e t e r m i n a t i o n o n their o w n or, alternatively,

2. These include, for example, the imposition of identical coefficients o n foreign currency prices and exchange rates.

(5)

some m i x t u r e o f the t w o is appropriate. This is done b y c o m b i n i n g Equations (1) and (2) i n t o the composite E q u a t i o n ( 3 ) .

P*R = f3( P . Ri >W . ; i = l , n a n d j = l , m ) (3)

T a k i n g E q u a t i o n (3) as the u n d e r l y i n g long-term relationship determining Irish o u t p u t prices, we a l l o w for differential short-run effects f r o m the prices and exchange rates o f the U K , Germany (GR) and the US, and f r o m the price of domestic factor i n p u t s . This is i m p l e m e n t e d using an error-correction type t e r m w h i c h allows a long-run influence f r o m prices i n each o f these countries and, possibly, f r o m domestic costs; the o n l y r e s t r i c t i o n imposed at this stage was that o f long-run homogeneity, tested later. The structure o f the m o d e l is, therefore, similar t o that estimated on trade-weighted data b y H o n o h a n and F l y n n ( 1 9 8 6 ) . The m o d e l can be w r i t t e n as follows where L stands for the lag operator, PJ R for the Irish price, for the price o f c o u n t r y j , R. for

the bilateral exchange rate w i t h respect t o c o u n t r y j , W for u n i t wage costs, and a, |3;J, y.^, e.^ r?j and X are all parameters t o be estimated:

A l o g ( PI R) = \ £ PijL1 { A l o g ( P ) } + I I y L M A l o ^ R ) }

i= 0 j = l J J 1= 0 j = l J J

The /3.j, 7 j j , and e; terms give the short-run responses t o changes i n foreign

currency prices and exchange rates i n the three countries and t o domestic u n i t wage costs, w h i l e the last t e r m is an error-correction mechanism ( E C M ) b y w h i c h Irish prices are b r o u g h t i n t o a long-run e q u i l i b r i u m r a t i o w i t h a weighted average4 o f the Irish currency prices o f the three countries and

labour costs. The constant i n the E C M t e r m allows for this e q u i l i b r i u m r a t i o t o be some constant otner than u n i t y ; i n the estimated equations we r e p o r t the coefficient for a. This m o d e l allows for deviations f r o m purchas­ ing p o w e r p a r i t y i n the short r u n . H o m o g e n e i t y i n the l o n g r u n is tested i n a later section b y adding an unrestricted t e r m i n L4 ( l o g ( PI R) ) . A p p r o p r i a t e

seasonal dummies were i n c l u d e d i n all the equations.

(6)

The data o n the wholesale price o f the different categories o f m a n u f a c t u r i n g i n d u s t r y o u t p u t , i n c l u d i n g t o t a l o u t p u t , are taken f r o m the CSO databank E O L A S . The data o n u n i t wage costs for each sector are derived f r o m a similar source. The data o n exchange rates are p a r t l y taken f r o m the E O L A S data­ bank and p a r t l y f r o m the D e p a r t m e n t o f Finance databank o f series f r o m the O E C D Main Economic Indicators p u b l i c a t i o n . The o u t p u t prices for each o f the industrial sectors i n the other countries are taken f r o m D e p a r t m e n t o f Finance databank o f series f r o m the O E C D Quarterly Indicators of Industrial Activity p u b l i c a t i o n . The exchange rate data for the three m a i n countries (the U S A , the U K , and West Germany) are p e r i o d averages whereas the exchange rate data for certain other countries t r i e d i n the disaggregated equations are averages o f end m o n t h l y values.5 The availability o f the wholesale price indices

basically determined the data p e r i o d as the first quarter o f 1975 t o the t h i r d quarter o f 1987. The estimation p e r i o d , unless otherwise indicated, is the first quarter o f 1976 t o the t h i r d quarter o f 1987.

I V R E S U L T S F O R T O T A L M A N U F A C T U R I N G I N D U S T R Y 4.1 Preliminary Tests of Co-integration

Before estimating the m o d e l ( E q u a t i o n (4)) we check that the t i m e series properties o f the data satisfy the constraints w h i c h Engle and Granger (1987) have shown are i m p l i e d b y the m o d e l . The basic procedure suggested is i n t w o steps. The first step is t o test that the i n d i v i d u a l series share a c o m m o n order o f i n t e g r a t i o n (i.e., are each stationary after differencing the same number o f t i m e s ) ; the second step is t o test that the series move together i n the l o n g r u n (i.e., are " c o - i n t e g r a t e d "6) .

Since the models u l t i m a t e l y used i n this section involve j u s t U K and German prices as explanatory variables, they i m p l y a constant long-run relationship between I r i s h prices and a weighted average o f U K and German prices, o n a c o m m o n currency basis. Therefore, we examine first o f all the order o f i n t e g r a t i o n for I r i s h , U K and German prices, all i n Irish p o u n d terms. We test the hypothesis that the series is a r a n d o m w a l k , using the test statistics derived by D i c k e y and Fuller ( 1 9 7 9 ) . The hypothesis that the series is a r a n d o m w a l k w i t h o u t d r i f t (so that the series is "integrated o f order 1") is tested b y $2,

w h i l e 4>3 tests the hypothesis that the first differenced series is a r a n d o m w a l k

w i t h d r i f t .

The test statistics for the f u l l p e r i o d , and for the post-EMS p e r i o d are shown i n Table 1.

5. The data available in the databank.

(7)

T a b l e 1: Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test Statistics for Hypothesis that Irish Pound Price

Series are Integrated of Order 1

Full Period EMS Period

(45 obs.) (33 obs.)

* 2 * 3 1 2 * 3

L ° g ( PT R) 2.45 2.55 1.40 1.34

L° g (PU K X RU K )

2 . 7 8 2 . 5 8 4 . 4 7 5 . 5 5

L o g ( PG R X RGR) 3 . 7 2 0 . 9 2 3 . 9 8 3 . 1 6

C r i t i c a l values f r o m D i c k e y a n d F u l l e r ( 1 9 8 1 ) :

50 obs. 25 obs.

5% 5 . 1 3 6.73 5 . 6 8 7 . 2 4

10% 4.31 5.61 4 . 6 7 5.91

These test statistics do n o t reject the hypotheses t h a t each o f the Irish p o u n d price series is integrated o f order 1, even at the 10 per cent level. H o w ­ ever, the results m a y be sensitive t o the p e r i o d i c i t y o f the data, or perhaps t o the exact sub-period chosen, as the results o f T h o r n elsewhere i n this Review m i g h t suggest. The statistics also appear t o be q u i t e sensitive t o certain choices w h i c h m u s t be made w i t h i n the test procedure, an issue t o w h i c h we n o w t u r n . The augmented D i c k e y - F u l l e r regression f r o m w h i c h these statistics are derived involve, for the l o g ( PI R) series, lagged terms i n A l o g ( PI R) . Granger

(1986) indicates that the order o f the autoregressive terms should be large enough t h a t the residuals f r o m the augmented Dickey-Fuller regression are empirical w h i t e noise. The best procedure for establishing the order o f this autoregression has y e t to be established. The procedure adopted here was t o start w i t h four lags, because the quarterly price data are k n o w n t o involve seasonal factors, and add further lags i f the F-form o f the Lagrange M u l t i p l i e r test indicates a u t o c o r r e l a t i o n o f the residuals at the 5 per cent level. I n all cases where a d d i t i o n a l lags were i n t r o d u c e d , they had h i g h l y significant t-statistics, and the F-testno longer i n d i c a t e d the presence o f a u t o c o r r e l a t i o n . I f the order of the autoregression was instead set and m a i n t a i n e d at four, the hypothesis that the Irish p o u n d price o f German goods is integrated o f order 1 w o u l d be rejected for the full p e r i o d , t h o u g h n o t for the post-EMS p e r i o d .

(8)

bivariate relationships, using a simple "co-integrating regression" w h i c h regresses one variable o n the other plus a constant t e r m . Some test statistics for higher order cases have been p r o d u c e d b y Engle and Y o o ( 1 9 8 7 ) , using a multivariate co-integrating regression.

We examine first of all whether I r i s h prices share a c o m m o n t r e n d or long-r u n e q u i l i b long-r i u m long-relationship w i t h eithelong-r U K olong-r Gelong-rman plong-rices ( i n Ilong-rish p o u n d terms), and then whether there is a c o m m o n long-run e q u i l i b r i u m relationship between Irish prices and some weighted average o f U K and German prices. The test statistic is based o n a regression o f the first differences o f the residuals f r o m the co-integrating regression on autoregressive terms, together w i t h the lagged value of the levels of these residuals (again, see T h o r n , this Review, or Engle and Granger, 1987, for details). The choice o f the number o f auto­ regressive terms t o be i n c l u d e d i n this regression raises issues parallel t o those discussed above, and the sensitivity o f the results is similar. The hypothesis of co-integration is rejected i f the calculated t-statistic for the lagged level o f the residuals does n o t exceed the critical values. The d i s t r i b u t i o n o f this A u g m e n t e d Dickey-Fuller ( A D F ) test statistic is n o t i n fact given b y the t - d i s t r i b u t i o n , b u t critical values are tabulated b y Engle and Y o o ( 1 9 8 7 ) . Table 2 gives the results for the f u l l p e r i o d , and the post-EMS p e r i o d .

T a b l e 2: Tests of Co-integration between log(Pffj), log(Pnf, X RUK), and log(PGR X RGR)

Full Period EMS Period

(44 obs.) (27 obs.)

ADF ADF

PIRa n d PUKX R UK 1.82 1.29

PIRa n d PGRX RGR 1.47 3 . 1 6

Critical values^ 50 obs. 25 obs.

5% 3 . 2 9 N A

10% 2.90 N A

PI R 'PU K X RU K 'a n d PG R X RG R 3.42

3 . 5 0

Critical values 50 obs. 2 5 obs.

5% 3.75 N A

10% 3 . 3 6 N A

(9)

The results for the f u l l p e r i o d illustrate the possibility that Irish prices m a y n o t be co-integrated w i t h either U K prices or German prices, b u t c o u l d be co-integrated w i t h a weighted average o f the t w o : the o n l y statistic w h i c h is significantly different f r o m zero (thereby i n d i c a t i n g co-integration) is that based o n the hypothesis o f a long-run e q u i l i b r i u m relationship between I r i s h prices and both U K and German prices. While critical values are n o t y e t avail­ able for the n u m b e r o f observations corresponding t o the post-EMS p e r i o d , the results suggest a stronger role for German prices, b u t w o u l d still a l l o w for a long-run l i n k t o some weighted average o f U K and German prices.

Given t h a t there is support f r o m this co-integration analysis for the existence of a l o n g - r u n e q u i l i b r i u m relationship between Irish prices and a weighted aver­ age o f U K and German prices, we proceed t o the estimation o f E q u a t i o n ( 4 ) .8

4.2 Basic Model: Dynamic Specification and Stability Tests

E q u a t i o n (4) was applied t o the price o f o u t p u t o f t o t a l m a n u f a c t u r i n g . The u n i t wage cost variable p r o v e d insignificant. This suggests that the long-r u n long-relationship d e t e long-r m i n i n g Ilong-rish plong-rices is closelong-r t o the pulong-re SOE m o d e l , described b y E q u a t i o n ( 1 ) , than t o the m i x e d m o d e l u n d e r l y i n g E q u a t i o n ( 3 ) .9

Data for prices and exchange rates o f three different countries, the U K , Germany and the U S A , were t r i e d i n the equation. However, i n estimating E q u a t i o n ( 4 ) , i t was apparent that neither US prices n o r the dollar exchange rate p l a y e d any significant role i n the d e t e r m i n a t i o n o f wholesale prices at an aggregate level. This is somewhat surprising, given the fact that price-setting i n dollars has become increasingly i m p o r t a n t , especially i n the office machines and data processing equipment and pharmaceuticals sectors, w h i c h have g r o w n r a p i d l y over the p e r i o d t o f o r m a significant part o f m a n u f a c t u r i n g i n d u s t r y . However, there are inherent difficulties i n measuring the prices o f these sectors. I n particular, the problems posed b y r a p i d q u a l i t y change i n the c o m p u t i n g i n d u s t r y have l e d t o the exclusion o f its prices f r o m the whole­ sale price index i n I r e l a n d , so that the lack o f US influence m a y reflect the exclusion f r o m the index o f the sector where prices are most obviously set i n US dollars.

Three lags o n the change i n German and U K prices and exchange rates were i n i t i a l l y i n c l u d e d , together w i t h an error c o r r e c t i o n t e r m lagged four periods and seasonal dummies Sf c. These i n i t i a l estimates are r e p o r t e d as E q u a t i o n ( 5 ) .1 0

8. We do not perform similar co-integration analysis of the other variables i n that equation (US prices, wages) since the simpler tests used i n the next section indicate that they should be discarded.

9. As Baker (1985) has pointed out, the rapid g r o w t h of high technology sectors o f the economy in the 1980s poses problems for the use o f an aggregate wage cost variable covering all o f manufacturing industry. As discussed i n the next section, when examined on a disaggregated basis, wage costs proved to be a significant factor determining prices i n the long r u n in t w o sectors, i.e., electrical engineering and paper and paper products.

(10)

A 1° g (PlR) = . ViGRLi^log (PG R ) >+ . V ^ L ^ A l o g l R ^ ) }

1= 0 1= u

+ . 1 PI U KLi{ A l o g ( Pl K) } + _i yiVKV{Mog(RVK)}

+ a+

I

fjS. (5)

i = 0

The f i t o f the relationship is very good, and most coefficients have significant values o f the expected (i.e., positive) sign; the three coefficients w i t h negative signs are n o t significantly different f r o m zero. The long-run coefficients are p a r t i c u l a r l y well-defined.

Equation 5 Results11

Coefficient: i=0 i = l i=2 i=3

a 1.379

( 4 . 7 )

0 i G R 0 . 5 7 5 0 . 0 9 2 - 0 . 2 8 2 0 . 1 2 2

0 i G R

(2.1) (0.3) ( - 0 . 8 ) (0.4)

T i G R 0 . 1 6 5 0.171 0 . 0 9 6 0 . 0 8 4

T i G R

(4.6) (4-0) (2.3) (1.8)

0 i U K 0 . 1 6 9 - 0 . 1 1 7 0 . 1 9 3 - 0 . 0 6 3

0 i U K

(1.1) ( - 0 . 7 ) (1.1) ( - 0 . 5 )

I ' i U K 0 . 0 4 8 0.131 0 . 0 7 9 0 . 0 8 9

I ' i U K

( 1 . 2 ) (3.4) (2.1) (2.6)

0G R

0 . 1 3 5

( 4 . 3 )

^ U K 0 . 0 9 6

(4.0)

0 . 0 1 8

(5-3)

0 . 0 1 2

(2.8)

0 . 0 0 4 (1.1)

R2 = . 9 4 0 S E R = . 0 0 5 3 4 R2 = .887

M e a n = . 0 2 2 9 S . D . = .0 1 7 1 C h o w F [ 1 2 , 3 5 ] = 1 . 2

A R F [ 4 , 2 0 ] = . 9 0 6 D F F I T S = 2 . 9 2 Het F [ l , 4 4 ] = .6 8 4

(11)

The diagnostic statistics are generally satisfactory. The F-versions o f the Lagrange M u l t i p l i e r tests do n o t indicate that the errors are autocorrelated or heteroscedastic. The relationship is relatively robust t o the d r o p p i n g o f the last 12 observations, as i n d i c a t e d b y the C h o w test: m o r e detailed analysis o f possible structural breaks related t o the EMS regime is taken up later i n this section. The D F F I T S statistic is above the critical level suggested b y Krasker, K u h and Welsch (1983) i n d i c a t i n g t h a t at least one observation is exerting significant leverage o n the results. However, w h e n estimated using b o u n d e d influence regression, the results were l i t t l e changed (Krasker, K u h and Welsch,

1983).

The strength o f the influence f r o m Germany, and the weakness o f the U K influence are interesting. The coefficients o n the E C M terms indicate that the long-run weight o n German prices i n Irish p o u n d terms is 0.6 while that on the U K is 0.4. O n the basis o f trade shares one m i g h t have expected the U K influence t o be g r e a t e r .1 2 The difference between the estimated

short-r u n and long-short-run effects i n this and otheshort-r equations accounts foshort-r the auto­ c o r r e l a t i o n f o u n d b y L e d d i n (1988) i n a specification w h i c h d i d n o t a l l o w for these differential dynamics.

We w a n t t o investigate b o t h the dynamic specification o f this relationship, and its s t a b i l i t y across the change o f exchange rate regime. T o make our results independent o f the order i n w h i c h we u n d e r t o o k these tasks, we have p e r f o r m e d F-tests for a series o f nested models. T h e y involve simplifications of the dynamic structure and alternative changes associated w i t h EMS e n t r y . I n Figure 1 the dynamic structure o f E q u a t i o n ( 5 ) , w i t h three lags o n all short-run coefficients, is labelled A ; the s i m p l i f i c a t i o n (suggested b y the t-statistics) w h i c h drops the three lags o n the price terms is labelled B ; a corresponding s i m p l i f i c a t i o n , d r o p p i n g the lags o n the exchange rate terms is labelled Z ; w h i l e the final s i m p l i f i c a t i o n , d r o p p i n g the t h i r d lag on the German exchange rate, is labelled C. A specificiation w h i c h allows b o t h long- and short-run relationships t o change after EMS e n t r y is labelled 1 ;1 3 a specifica­

t i o n w h i c h allows o n l y the long-run relationship t o change, as shown i n E q u a t i o n (6) below, is labelled 2; and the specification w h i c h imposes the same relationship over the f u l l p e r i o d (as i n E q u a t i o n (5)) is labelled 3. Thus we have a 4 X 3 m a t r i x o f possible specifications, w i t h E q u a t i o n (5) repre­ sented b y A 3 . Figure 1 b e l o w indicates the specifications preferred b y the F-test at the 5 per cent level: the calculated statistics are given i n A p p e n d i x 1.

12. This issue is discussed later i n Section 4.6.

(12)

F i g u r e 1: Summary of Results of Nested Tests

(Significance level: 5%)

(1) (2) (3)

Short- & Long- Long-run Short- & Long-run Relationships Relationship run Relationships

Changed by EMS Changed by EMS Unchanged by EMS

Z . D r o p lags o n R Z l => Z 2 «= Z 3

A . 3 lags o n P a n d R A l A 2 <= A 3

*

B . D r o p lags o n P B l B 2 => B 3

C . D r o p 3 r d lag

»

1t

o n R G R C I C 2 C 3

These F-tests c o n t a i n several features o f interest. The d r o p p i n g o f the lags on the price terms is never rejected; corresponding tests o n d r o p p i n g the lags on the exchange rate terms are always strongly rejected. This is strong evidence for an a s y m m e t r y between the effects o f foreign price changes and exchange rate changes o n Irish wholesale prices: the exchange rate effects are more spread o u t over t i m e , w h i l e the price effects are concentrated i n the current p e r i o d . F u r t h e r testing o n this issue is carried o u t i n Section 4.4 b e l o w .

Tests for a s t r u c t u r a l break after e n t r y t o the EMS are accepted for all b u t one specification at the 5 per cent level, and for all at the 10 per cent level. The hypothesis that this structural break is concentrated on the long-run coefficients cannot be rejected at the 5 per cent level for any o f the specifi­ cations considered. This strongly suggests that there was a change i n the d e t e r m i n a t i o n o f Irish wholesale prices subsequent t o EMS e n t r y . The fact that the short-run coefficients do n o t change significantly may reflect the d i f f i c u l t y i n i d e n t i f y i n g the exact short-run relationships, whereas the longer-r u n longer-relationships diffelonger-r molonger-re clealonger-rly.

N o m a t t e r w h a t the starting p o i n t i n the m a t r i x o f specifications o f Figure 1, f o l l o w i n g the results o f the nested tests leads t o either specification C2 or B3. This a m b i g u i t y can be resolved b y m o v i n g t o a 10 per cent significance level for the tests. The o n l y change i n terms o f Figure 1 is that the arrow f r o m B2 t o B3 is reversed. This means that n o matter w h a t the starting p o i n t ,1 4

the arrows n o w p o i n t eventually t o specification C2, w h i c h is r e p o r t e d b e l o w as E q u a t i o n ( 6 ) .

(13)

I n the preferred specification, E q u a t i o n ( 6 ) , the long-run relationship is a l l o w e d t o change o n j o i n i n g the E M S . This is i m p l e m e n t e d b y m u l t i p l y i n g a d u m m y1 5 b y the error c o r r e c t i o n terms for the U K and Germany.

A l o g ( PI R) = i =l Pi G RLi{ A l o g ( PG R) } + T i G RLi{ A l o g ( RG R) }

+ .}Q 0 i U KL i{A 1° g (PU K ) }+ j * , 7 i U KLi{Alog ( RUK) }

^ C R ^ o g Q^*) + 9 O T L * l o g ( ^ « )

/ + g C R L 4 l o g ( P G R ^ R G R ) x D E M S

+ 6U KL4l o g (?UK p RUK) X D m s + a + I f . S; (6)

While the t-statistic o n the coefficients o f the t w o " s t r u c t u r a l b r e a k " vari­ ables are i n d i v i d u a l l y significant o n l y at the 10 per cent level, the F-test o f the j o i n t hypothesis t h a t b o t h are equal t o zero yields a value o f 5.59, w h i c h is significant at the 1 per cent level. As shown i n Table 3, these results i m p l y t h a t the long-run weights o n German and U K prices changed o n j o i n i n g the EMS as the importance o f U K o u t p u t prices i n d e t e r m i n i n g I r i s h o u t p u t prices was greatly reduced and there was a corresponding increase i n the importance o f German o u t p u t prices.

A break i n this estimated relationship, i n v o l v i n g f i x e d weights o n each c o u n t r y ' s price indices has t w o possible explanations. I f the u n d e r l y i n g w o r l d price d e t e r m i n i n g Irish o u t p u t prices were, a trade-weighted average o f prices i n our m a i n t r a d i n g partners the significance o f the dummies c o u l d merely reflect a change i n trade weights, i.e., the higher weight o n German prices i n the later p e r i o d c o u l d be due solely t o its increasing i m p o r t a n c e i n I r i s h trade. This e x p l a n a t i o n can, however, be discounted, because o f the evidence f r o m the trade-weighted regressions below.

The alternative e x p l a n a t i o n , supported b y these results, is t h a t there was a change i n price setting behaviour after Irish e n t r y i n t o the EMS. This suggests that the relative i m p o r t a n c e o f German prices as against U K prices i n Irish f i r m s ' p r i c i n g decisions may have been altered f o r more i n s t i t u t i o n a l reasons, perhaps associated w i t h a reversal i n the relative s t a b i l i t y o f the Deutschmark and Sterling n o m i n a l exchange rates under the n e w regime.

(14)

Equation 6 Results

Coefficient: i=0 i = l i=2 i=3

a 1.050

( 3 . 7 )

0 . 5 0 0 ( 2 . 8 )

^ i G R 0 . 1 1 8

( 3 . 6 )

0 . 1 1 4

( 3 . 0 )

0 . 0 6 1

( 1 . 8 )

0 i U K 0 . 2 7 0

( 2 . 5 )

I ' i U K 0 . 0 6 7

( 2 . 5 )

0 . 1 3 5

( 5 . 1 )

0 . 0 8 1 0.081 ( 3 . 0 ) ( 3 . 3 )

9G R

0 . 0 2 4

( 0 . 6 )

9U K

0 . 1 6 7

( 2 . 9 )

5G R

0 . 0 6 1 ( 1 . 5 )

5U K

- 0 . 0 7

( - 1 . 4 )

? i 0 . 0 1 6 0.011 0 . 0 0 3

( 5 . 8 ) ( 4 . 1 ) ( 1 . 3 )

R2 = . 9 4 2 S E R = . 0 0 4 9 0 R2 = . 9 1 0

A R F [ 4 , 2 5 ] = 1.36 D F F I T S = 1.99 H e t F [ l , 4 4 ] = 1.12

T a b l e 3 : Weights on German and UK Prices

Germany UK

P r e - E M S 0.13 0.87

P o s t - E M S 0.47 0 . 5 3

(15)

4.3 Tests of Long-run Homogeneity

The tests o f co-integration i n Section 4 . 1 have i n d i c a t e d support for a long-r u n e q u i l i b long-r i u m long-relationship between Ilong-rish plong-rices and a weighted avelong-rage o f the Irish p o u n d prices o f German and U K manufactures. This is a necessary, b u t insufficient, c o n d i t i o n for long-run homogeneity t o h o l d . The r e s t r i c t i o n o f long-run homogeneity, or relative purchasing p o w e r parity, has been imposed i n the models o f the previous section: the long-run s o l u t i o n o f these models involves a constant r a t i o between Irish prices and a (geometric) weighted average o f U K and German prices i n Irish p o u n d terms. Given the nature o f price indices i t is n o t possible t o draw any conclusions concerning absolute purchasing p o w e r p a r i t y f r o m these results.

A stronger test o f the homogeneity r e s t r i c t i o n can be derived b y i n c l u d i n g as an a d d i t i o n a l variable the f o u r t h lag o f the level o f Irish prices: this allows the long-run relationship t o be a non-constant r a t i o . I f the r e s t r i c t i o n is rejected by this test i t w o u l d suggest the omission o f some i m p o r t a n t explanatory variable. While the coefficient o n this a d d i t i o n a l variable is significantly dif­ ferent f r o m zero i n the regressions covering the f u l l p e r i o d , i t is n o t signi­ f i c a n t l y different f r o m zero i n 3 o f the 4 regressions for the post-EMS sub-p e r i o d .

Thus, the evidence o n long-run homogeneity is somewhat m i x e d . I t should be remembered that the price series used are for t o t a l m a n u f a c t u r i n g i n d u s t r y . Differences i n the weights attached t o different components w i l l lead t o divergences f r o m relative PPP i f the price trends for these different com­ ponents diverge.

4.4 Tests of Short-term PPP

We have already seen one set o f F-tests w h i c h indicates that the response to exchange rate changes is slower than that t o prices. Further tests c o n f i r m this as a strong result. F o r m u l a t i o n s w h i c h impose an identical response i n each quarter b y Irish prices t o changes i n foreign currency prices and exchange rates are rejected against those w h i c h a l l o w differential effects. This result holds very generally across countries, sectors and sub-periods. For example, the F-test for imposing an i d e n t i c a l response r e s t r i c t i o n o n E q u a t i o n (5) yields a value o f 3.65 as against a 1 per cent critical value F ( 8 , 2 ) o f 3 . 4 1 . These tests c o n f i r m the result o f L e d d i n (1988) t h a t purchasing p o w e r p a r i t y , expressed o n a p e r i o d b y p e r i o d basis, can be rejected: they also indicate, however, t h a t Leddin's i m p o s i t i o n o f i d e n t i c a l coefficients o n the foreign price and exchange rate terms is rejected b y the data.

(16)

this r e s t r i c t i o n on E q u a t i o n (5) yields a value o f 1.28 as against a critical value F ( 2 , 2 3 ) o f 3.42.

The response t o German price changes i n D M terms tends t o be larger (and better defined) than the response to exchange rate changes. I n the case o f the U K the opposite is the case w i t h the exchange rate terms being generally better defined than the price terms. The short-term response t o exchange rate changes tends t o be somewhat slower than t o foreign currency prices.

4.5 Tests of Asymmetric Response to Changes in Foreign Prices

Baker et al. (1986) suggested that domestic prices w o u l d respond faster t o a rise i n the price o f foreign currency than t o a fall. The possibility o f a stronger response t o exchange rate induced increases i n c o m p e t i t o r s ' prices (in Irish p o u n d terms) than t o decreases was tested as follows. First, a d u m m y variable was constructed t a k i n g the value 1 for an increase i n the U K exchange rate and zero otherwise. A n a d d i t i o n a l variable was f o r m e d by m u l t i p l y i n g the short-term exchange rate changes by this d u m m y variable, thus giving a variable equal t o the exchange rate change i f this was positive, b u t zero o t h e r w i s e .1 7

A positive significant coefficient o n this variable w o u l d indicate a more r a p i d response t o positive exchange rate changes. The results show that the coef­ ficients o n the d u m m y variables, while all bearing the expected positive sign, i m p l y i n g a faster response t o a depreciation o f the Irish p o u n d , are j o i n t l y n o t significant f r o m zero. However, due t o the small number o f observations for an appreciation o f the Irish p o u n d against Sterling, this test is n o t conclusive.

4.6 Non-nested Tests against Trade-weighted Foreign Price Variables Trade weights for the U K , Germany and the US move fairly steadily f r o m 0.75, 0.13, 0.12, respectively, t o 0.55, 0.20, 0.25 over the p e r i o d 1975 t o 1987. We have already seen that the i m p l i e d weight on German prices i n the aggregate level regressions is m u c h greater than even this end-period weight, and the i m p l i e d weight on the U K is correspondingly lower. However, the fact that the trade weights move over the p e r i o d to reflect Germany's increas­ i n g trade share c o u l d give a trade-weighted approach some advantages over the f i x e d weights o f the regression approach. Simple trade weights were used t o create w e i g h t e d averages o f U K , German and US prices and exchange rates: the results r e p o r t e d b e l o w do n o t suggest that more sophisticated weighting sys­ tems w o u l d lead t o different conclusions. Non-nested tests provide the appro­ priate f r a m e w o r k for choosing between the trade-weighted and regression-w e i g h t e d approaches.

(17)

The results indicate t h a t the regression-weighted approach encompasses the results o f the trade-weighted approach. The trade-weighted regressions are rejected against a j o i n t m o d e l i n c o r p o r a t i n g separate i n f o r m a t i o n o n the U K and Germany (the test statistic o f 4.72 exceeding the critical F ( 1 8 , 1 5 ) at the 1 per cent level o f 3.43), w h i l e the regression-weighted approach is n o t rejected against a j o i n t m o d e l i n c l u d i n g trade-weighted i n f o r m a t i o n (the test statistic o f 1.31 being b e l o w the 5 per cent c r i t i c a l F ( 9 , 1 5 ) o f 2.59). The r e p o r t e d statistics are based o n the inclusion o f three lags o f each price and exchange rate variable, as i n E q u a t i o n ( 5 ) , b u t similar results were o b t a i n e d w i t h m o r e restricted specifications.

Specifications w h i c h use U K data alone t o p r o x y foreign prices are also strongly rejected against specifications i n c l u d i n g German price data. Further­ m o r e , the specifications i n v o l v i n g the U K alone y i e l d unstable and counter­ i n t u i t i v e results, i n c l u d i n g rejection o f long-run homogeneity, and a sign o n the error c o r r e c t i o n t e r m w h i c h w o u l d lead t o Irish prices diverging f r o m those i n the U K .

There w o u l d seem t o be t w o m a i n reasons w h y the influence o f German prices exceeds their trade weight. The first is t h a t German prices m a y t o some extent p r o x y prices for France, the Netherlands and other European countries n o t i n c l u d e d i n the analysis. I t is d o u b t f u l , however, i f this is the w h o l e story. A n alternative, m e n t i o n e d earlier, is that German prices exert an influence o u t o f p r o p o r t i o n t o their trade w e i g h t , possibly because German firms are regarded as price leaders; further investigation w o u l d be needed t o establish whether or n o t this is the case.

V R E V I E W O F D I S A G G R E G A T E D R E S U L T S

We also applied the m o d e l described above i n E q u a t i o n (4) t o the price data for the o u t p u t o f a range o f n o n - f o o d sectors o f m a n u f a c t u r i n g i n d u s t r y .1 8

I n each case data for prices and exchange rates i n the U K , Germany and the US, were t r i e d together w i t h wage rates. I n the case o f certain sectors price and exchange rate data for some other possibly relevant countries were t r i e d . The results o f these regressions are summarised i n Table 4 .1 9 The same dynamic

specification was used i n each case w i t h no lags on the price change variables and 3 lags o n the exchange rate changes. I n all b u t one case a specification i n c l u d i n g 3 lags o n the change i n prices was rejected at the 5 per cent level i n favour o f this m o r e restricted specification used here.

18. See Callan and FitzGerald (1988) for full details of these results.

(18)

While the R2 statistics r e p o r t e d for these disaggregated equations are t y p i ­

cally l o w e r t h a n t h a t for the aggregate equation, they are all highly significant, and compare favourably w i t h other t i m e series analyses o f dependent variables differenced i n logarithms. A t such a disaggregated level the increasing i m p o r ­ tance o f special factors, n o t captured b y the regressors, m a y account for the somewhat l o w e r R2 statistics r e p o r t e d .

The 11 equations for the different sectors o f m a n u f a c t u r i n g cover the b u l k of the n o n - f o o d o u t p u t o f t h a t sector (over 60 per cent o f net o u t p u t ) . One major omission is the electronics sector w h i c h is also o m i t t e d f r o m the index covering t o t a l m a n u f a c t u r i n g . As can be seen f r o m the table the results are reasonably consistent w i t h the results obtained f r o m the aggregate equation.

I n eight sectors at least one o f the 6 coefficients are significant i n d i c a t i n g a significant long-term relationship between Irish prices and the explanatory variables. Domestic costs, p r o x i e d b y wage costs, are o f o n l y l i m i t e d i m p o r ­

tance i n d e t e r m i n i n g prices; they are o n l y significant i n t w o sectors i n the l o n g r u n .2 0 Thus, for m o s t sectors the SOE m o d e l is appropriate. As w i t h the

results presented i n Section 4 , German prices generally have a higher weight i n determining Irish prices than do U K prices. The results c o n f i r m the slower speed o f adjustment o f I r i s h prices t o changes i n exchange rates than t o changes i n foreign currency prices. F i n a l l y , these results c o n f o r m e d t o the results i n Section 4 i n ascribing l i t t l e or n o weight t o other countries' p r i c e s2 1

i n explaining Irish prices.

(19)

T a b l e 4 : Results for Individual Industrial Sectors

Sector 1 2 3 4 5 6 72 2

5 9 10 11

a 0.788 1.510 1.139 1.101 1.171 2.003 0.567 0.404 - 0 . 0 5 6 0.665 0.493 (3.6) (3.6) (1.4) (4.8) (4.0) (3.4) (1.9) (2.3) (0.3) (3.4) (1.4)

^OGR 0.261 0.117 0.014 1.005 - 0 . 0 0 7 0.176 0.270 0.744 (0.7) (0.1) (0.0) (3.9) (0.0) (0.9) (1.8) (5.4)

70 G R 0.223 -0.010 0.074

0.107 0.371 - 0 . 0 0 4 - 0 . 0 3 8 0.031

70 G R

(3.4) (0.1) (1.5) (2.1) (2.2) (0.2) (0.3) (0.3) 0.069 0.140 0.171 0.233 0.511 - 0 . 0 2 0 0.281 0.415 (1.0) (1.9) (3.2) (4.1) (2.9) (0.0) (2.1) (3.9)

^2GR 0.002 0.037 0.160 0.081 0.173 0.077 - 0 . 3 0 8 0.216 (0.0) (0.4) (2.9) (1.5) (1.0) (2.1) (2.4) (2.0)

^ G R 0.134 - 0 . 1 0 7 0.015 0.162 0.200 0.032 0.188 0.081 ^ G R

(2.3) (1.3) (0.3) (3.1) (1.2) (1.0) (1.4) (0.8)

0.436 0.616 0.339 0.293 - 0 . 0 8 8 0.183 -0.010 0.853 0.463 (2.8) (2.7) (2.1) (1.4) (0.4) (0.3) (0.0) (3.9) (3.8)

7O U K 0.018 0.081 0.076 - 0 . 0 6 3 0.109 0.106 0.090 0.155 0.019 7O U K

(0.2) (1.7) (1.6) (1.6) (2.8) (0.8) (2.4) (3.1) (0.4)

^ l U K 0.232 0.146 0.099 0.054 - 0 . 0 4 3 0.026 0.026 0.190 0.105 ^ l U K

(3.1) (3.2) (2.5) (1.3) (1.0) (0.2) (0.7) (3.8) (2.1)

72 U K 0.086

0.079 0.012 0.023 0.033 0.124 0.075 - 0 . 0 2 0 0.096

72 U K

(1.0) (1.7) (0.2) (0.5) (0.8) (0.9) (2.0) (0.3) (1.8)

T3UK. 0.072 0.111 - 0 . 0 2 2 0.168 0.040 0.026 0.062 0.026 0.091 (0.9) (2.4) (0.5) (4.3) (1.0) (0.2) (1.6) (0.5) (1.9)

eo

0.037 0.015 - 0 . 0 8 6 0.072

(1.3) (0.7) (2.1) (2.7)

0.012 - 0 . 0 0 2 - 0 . 0 6 8 0.112

(0.4) (0.1) (1.3) (3.6)

e2

0.024 0.041 0.124 0.087

(0.7) (1.5) (2.0) (2.4)

e3 0.076 0.040 0.021 - 0 . 0 6 7

(2.2) (1.5) (0.4) (1.4)

^GR 0.131 0.126 0.114 0.099 0.126 0.346 0.055 0.097 0.076 (2.6) (3.1) (1.5) (3.7) (4.2) (3.1) (1.8) (3.3) (1.4)

0.133 0.050 0.084 0.068 - 0 . 0 4 9 0.000 0.086 - 0 . 0 6 7 (3.3) (0.7) (3.8) (2.4) (1.0) (0.0) (1.6) (1.4)

ew 0.042 0.051 - 0 . 0 1 4 0.079

(1.4) (2.4) (0.3) (2.5)

R2 0.647 0.664 0.706 0.685 0.756 0.393 0.453 0.694 0.785 0.292 0.472

Sectors: 1. Chemicals 2. Metal Products 3. Electrical Engineering 4. M o t o r Vehicles and Parts

5. Textiles

6. Leather and Footwear 7. Clothing

8. Timber and Furniture

9. Paper and Paper Products 10. Rubber and Rubber Products 11. Processing o f Plastics

(20)

V I C O N C L U S I O N S

The results presented i n this paper show t h a t the SOE m o d e l o f price d e t e r m i n a t i o n is appropriate t o Irish manufacturing o u t p u t . Domestic wage costs play o n l y a m i n o r role i n price d e t e r m i n a t i o n , while foreign price i n f l u ­ ences are d o m i n a n t . I n this respect, the results c o n f i r m the consensus o f earlier research o n this t o p i c ; b u t the results on the nature and t i m i n g o f the foreign influence are a good deal more novel.

Short-run h o m o g e n e i t y is rejected b y the data. While long-run homogeneity is generally rejected for the f u l l data sample, i t is accepted for the post-EMS p e r i o d .

Generally the effects o f changes i n exchange rates on prices are m u c h slower to materialise than are the effects o f changes i n foreign currency prices. This difference i n behaviour can be explained b y the fact that firms are reluctant to change their o u t p u t prices very frequently. As a result, they have t o set future prices based o n their expectations o f the Irish p o u n d price o f foreign c o m p e t i t o r s . When foreign c o m p e t i t o r s raise their prices i n foreign currency terms there is l i t t l e l i k e l i h o o d t h a t they w i l l subsequently reduce t h e m , so domestic producers w i l l be quick t o f o l l o w suit. However, i f foreign prices i n Irish p o u n d terms change because o f exchange rate changes, past experience suggests, especially i n the case o f the Sterling-Irish p o u n d exchange rate, that there is quite a p o s s i b i l i t y that the change may be reversed i n the immediate future. As a result, firms are l i k e l y t o be slower t o change their expectations about future values o f the exchange rate as a result o f a single quarter's f i g u r e s .2 3

There is no evidence o f an asymmetric response to appreciation and depreci­ a t i o n vis-a-vis Sterling. However, the number o f observations available for the post-EMS p e r i o d are s t i l l t o o few to p r o p e r l y test this hypothesis. I n any event, this hypothesis may be more appropriately applied t o a m o d e l o f the f o r m a t i o n o f domestic consumer prices, as suggested by Baker et al., 1986.

Germany has a stronger influence i n determining Irish prices than the trade weights suggest. I n the post-EMS p e r i o d its role i n o u t p u t price d e t e r m i n a t i o n is r o u g h l y equal t o that o f the U K . The p a t t e r n o f response o f Irish prices t o foreign prices was significantly different f r o m that suggested b y an approach based o n trade weights.

Because o f a l i m i t e d number o f consistent observations for the pre-EMS p e r i o d i t is d i f f i c u l t t o test for a change i n p a t t e r n o f behaviour f o l l o w i n g the break i n the l i n k w i t h sterling consequent on EMS membership. However, the evidence f r o m the aggregate price series does indicate a change i n p r i c i n g

(21)

behaviour i n 1979 w i t h an increase i n the i m p o r t a n c e o f German prices and a fall i n the i m p o r t a n c e o f U K p r i c e s .2 4 I t is d i f f i c u l t t o i d e n t i f y a change i n

short-run p r i c i n g behaviour. The differential response t o exchange rate changes and foreign currency price changes has also taken o n added importance n o w that the Sterling-Irish p o u n d rate is flexible.

These results have a n u m b e r o f i m p l i c a t i o n s for p u b l i c p o l i c y . I n so far as the p r i c i n g behaviour o f Irish firms reflects their views as t o w h o their com­ petitors are, these results suggest a change i n the t r a d i t i o n a l trade-weighted approach t o measuring competitiveness. O n the basis o f these results, EMS countries, p r o x i e d b y Germany, should have a m u c h bigger weight i n c o m ­ petitiveness measures t h a n w o u l d be suggested b y t r a d i t i o n a l trade weights.

The slower response o f domestic prices t o changes i n the exchange rate than t o changes i n foreign currency prices has i m p l i c a t i o n s for the Irish eco­ n o m y o n the c o m p l e t i o n o f the EC m a r k e t i n 1992. I f the U K remains o u t of the EMS u n c e r t a i n t y about the bilateral Sterling-Irish p o u n d exchange rate w i l l pose problems i n price d e t e r m i n a t i o n . W i t h o u t any customs or fiscal barriers the slow adjustment o f prices t o exchange rate changes c o u l d give rise to large t e m p o r a r y trade flows. The alternative is that either prices i n I r e l a n d change m o r e r a p i d l y i n the face o f changes i n the Sterling-Irish p o u n d exchange rate or else the v a r i a b i l i t y o f U K prices i n Sterling terms increases.

(22)

REFERENCES

B A K E R , T . , 1 9 8 5 . " T r e n d s i n M a n u f a c t u r i n g O u t p u t a n d Wage C o s t s 1 9 8 0 - 1 9 8 4 " , A p p e n ­

d i x to Quarterly Economic Commentary, A p r i l , p p . 2 6 - 3 5 .

B A K E R , T . , S . S C O T T , a n d T . Q U I N N , 1 9 8 6 . Quarterly Economic Commentary, A p r i l .

B R A D L E Y , J . , 1 9 7 7 . " L a g s i n the T r a n s m i s s i o n of I n f l a t i o n " , The Economic and Social

Review, Vol. 8 , p p . 1 4 9 - 1 5 4 .

C E N T R A L S T A T I S T I C S O F F I C E , 1 9 8 8 . Census of Industrial Production, 1 9 8 5 , D u b l i n :

cso.

C A L L A N , T . , a n d J . F I T Z G E R A L D , 1 9 8 8 . "Price D e t e r m i n a t i o n i n I r e l a n d : E f f e c t s of changes i n exchange rates a n d exchange rate regimes", D u b l i n : E S R I M e m o r a n d u m

Series N o . 1 7 9 .

D I C K E Y , D . A . , a n d W . A . F U L L E R , 1 9 7 9 . " D i s t r i b u t i o n of the E s t i m a t e s for A u t o -regressive T i m e Series w i t h a U n i t R o o t " , Journal of the American Statistical Associ­

ation, V o l . 7 9 , p p . 4 2 7 - 4 3 1 .

D I C K E Y , D . A . , a n d W . A . F U L L E R , 1 9 8 1 . " T h e L i k e l i h o o d R a t i o Statistics for A u t o

-regressive T i m e Series w i t h a U n i t R o o t " , Econometrica, V o l . 4 9 , p p . 1 0 5 7 - 1 0 7 2 .

E N G L E , R . F . , a n d C . W . G R A N G E R , 1 9 8 7 . " C o - I n t e g r a t i o n a n d E r r o r C o r r e c t i o n :

R e p r e s e n t a t i o n , E s t i m a t i o n a n d T e s t i n g " , Econometrica, V o l . 5 5 , N o . 2, p p . 2 5 1 - 2 7 6 . E N G L E , R . F . , a n d B . S . Y O O , 1 9 8 7 . " F o r e c a s t i n g a n d T e s t i n g in C o - I n t e g r a t e d S y s t e m s " ,

Journal of Econometrics, V o l . 3 5 , N o . 1, p p . 1 4 3 - 1 5 9 .

F I S H E R , F . M . , 1 9 7 0 . "Tests o f E q u a l i t y b e t w e e n Sets of Coefficients i n T w o L i n e a r

Regressions: A n E x p o s i t o r y N o t e " , Econometrica, V o l . 3 8 , p p . 3 6 1 - 3 6 6 .

F I T Z G E R A L D , J . , 1 9 8 3 . " A S t u d y of the D e t e r m i n a n t s of I r i s h I n d u s t r i a l O u t p u t P r i c e s " , E S R I seminar paper.

F R E N K E L , J . A . , 1 9 8 1 . " T h e C o l l a p s e of P u r c h a s i n g P o w e r Parities during the 1 9 7 0 s " ,

European Economic Review, V o l . 16, p p . 1 4 5 - 1 6 5 .

G E A R Y , P . T . , 1 9 7 6 a . " L a g s i n the T r a n s m i s s i o n of I n f l a t i o n : S o m e P r e l i m i n a r y E s t i ­

m a t e s " , The Economic and Social Review, V o l . 7, p p . 3 8 3 - 3 8 9 .

G E A R Y , P . T . , 1 9 7 6 b . " W o r l d Prices a n d the I n f l a t i o n a r y Process in a S m a l l O p e n E c o ­ n o m y — T h e C a s e of I r e l a n d " , The Economic and Social Review, V o l . 7, p p . 3 9 1 - 4 0 0 .

G E A R Y , P . T . , a n d C . M c C A R T H Y , 1 9 7 6 . "Wage a n d P r i c e D e t e r m i n a t i o n i n a L a b o u r E x p o r t i n g E c o n o m y : T h e Case o f I r e l a n d " , European Economic Review, V o l . 8, N o . 3,

p p . 2 1 9 - 2 3 4 .

G O L D S T E I N , M . , 1 9 7 4 . " T h e E f f e c t s of E x c h a n g e R a t e Changes o n Prices a n d Wages i n

the U K : an E m p i r i c a l S t u d y " , IMF Staff Papers, V o l . 2 3 , N o . 4.

G R A N G E R , C . W . , 1 9 8 6 . " D e v e l o p m e n t s i n the S t u d y of C o i n t e g r a t e d E c o n o m i c V a r i ­ ables", Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, V o l . 4 8 , N o . 3, p p . 2 1 3 - 2 2 8 .

H E N D R Y , D . F . , 1 9 8 3 . " E c o n o m e t r i c Modelling — the C o n s u m p t i o n F u n c t i o n i n R e t r o ­

s p e c t " , Scottish Journal of Political Economy, V o l . 3 0 , N o . 3, p p . 1 9 3 - 2 0 0 .

H O N O H A N , P . , a n d J . F L Y N N , 1 9 8 6 . " I r i s h I n f l a t i o n i n E M S " , The Economic and

Social Review, V o l . 17, p p . 1 7 5 - 1 9 1 .

I S A R D , P . , 1 9 7 7 . " H o w F a r C a n We P u s h the L a w of O n e P r i c e ? " , American Economic

Review, V o l . 6 7 , p p . 9 4 2 - 9 4 8 .

K R A S K E R , W . S . , E . K U H , a n d R . E . W E L S C H , 1 9 8 3 . " E s t i m a t i o n for D i r t y D a t a a n d F l a w e d M o d e l s " , i n Z . G r i l i c h e s a n d M . D . Intriligator (eds.), Handbook of Econo­

(23)

L E D D I N , A . , 1 9 8 8 . "Interest a n d Price P a r i t y a n d F o r e i g n E x c h a n g e M a r k e t E f f i c i e n c y : T h e I r i s h E x p e r i e n c e i n the E u r o p e a n M o n e t a r y S y s t e m " , The Economic and Social

Review, V o l . 19, p p . 2 1 5 - 2 3 1 .

R E S T R I C T I V E P R A C T I C E S C O M M I S S I O N , 1 9 8 8 . Report of the Restrictive Practices

Commission, D u b l i n : S t a t i o n e r y O f f i c e .

T H O M , R . , 1 9 8 9 . " R e a l E x c h a n g e R a t e s , Co-integration a n d P u r c h a s i n g P o w e r P a r i t y :

(24)

A p p e n d i x 1 : Calculated Values of the Test Statistics Underlying Figure 1.

Specifications 1, 2 and 3 and dynamics A , B , C and Z are as described i n Figure 1 and the related t e x t .

Z l F ( l l , 1 7 ) = 1.05 Z 2 F ( 2 , 2 8 ) = 8 . 0 4 * * Z 3

F ( 6 , l l ) = 7 . 2 9 * * F ( 6 , 2 2 ) = 8 . 0 5 * * F ( 6 , 2 4 ) = 8 . 1 2 * *

A l F ( 1 1 , H ) = 1.61 A 2 F ( 2 , 2 2 ) = 7 . 2 7 * * A 3

F ( 6 , l l ) = 2 . 2 6 F ( 6 , 2 2 ) = 1 . 8 7 F ( 6 . 2 4 ) = 0 . 5 0

B l F ( l l , 1 7 ) = 1.18 B 2 F ( 2 , 2 8 ) = 3 . 3 1 + B 3

F ( l , 1 7 ) = 0 . 5 0 F ( l , 2 8 ) = 1 . 6 5 F ( l , 3 0 ) = 5 . 6 0 *

C I F ( l l , 1 8 ) = =1.33 C 2 F ( 2 , 2 9 ) = 5 . 5 9 * * C 3

A test statistic w h i c h is significant at 1 per c e n t ( * * ) , 5 per cent(*) and 10 per cent(+) indicates that the less general specification (i.e., the one w i t h more restrictions and, hence, fewer estimated parameters) is rejected against the more general specification. For example, since Z is less general than A , the test statistic F ( 6 , l l ) = 7 . 2 9 indicates that Z l is rejected against A l . Specifica­ t i o n A is m o r e general than B w h i c h is m o r e general than C while dynamics 1 are m o r e general than 2 w h i c h are more general than 3.

T y p e s e t by W e n d y A . C o m m i n s , T h e C u r r a g h ; M a k e - u p by Paul B r a y S t u d i o .

References

Related documents

On the other hand, exchange rates shifts (under fixed exchange rate regime) associated with volatility of main reference currency serving as the nominal anchor are usually

Capital flight encourages an increase in the demand for foreign currency in developing countries, for example Nigeria, which tends to increase the exchange rate between the Naira

Figure 28: Response in percent of exchange rates, import prices and consumer prices for goods of foreign origin, and response in percentage points of consumer price inflation for

This study measures long run relationships and short run relationships between crude oil price, foreign exchange rates and interest rates by using monthly data of Brent crude

Even with these difficulties, we would like to investigate the relationship between the nominal exchange rates and economic fundamentals focusing on the different behavior of

Our results confirm the existence of an asymme- try in central bank foreign exchange intervention responses to currency appreciations versus depreciations in many develop- ing

On the other hand, exchange rates shifts (under fixed exchange rate regime) associated with volatility of main reference currency serving as the nominal anchor are usually

Empirical Review on Foreign Exchange Rates Fluctuation and Performance of Securities Market The study by Golaka and Samanta [9] on relationship between exchange rate and stock