Faculdade de Economia da Universidade de Coimbra
Grupo de Estudos Monetários e Financeiros (GEMF)
Av. Dias da Silva, 165 – 3004-512 COIMBRA, PORTUGAL
gemf@fe.uc.pt http://www.uc.pt/feuc/gemf
NUNO CARVALHO FIGUEIREDO, PATRÍCIA PEREIRA DA SILVA & PEDRO CERQUEIRA
The Renewables Influence on Market Splitting: the Iberian Spot
Electricity Market
ESTUDOS DO GEMF
N.º 14 2014
Este trabalho é financiado por Fundos Nacionais através da
a EFS Initiative, University of Coimbra, Sustainable Energy Systems – MIT‐P, Coimbra, Portugal
b INESCC, Coimbra, Portugal
c Faculty of Economics, University of Coimbra, Coimbra, Portugal
d GEMF, Grupo de Estudos Monetários e Financeiros,Coimbra, Portugal
The Renewables Influence on Market Splitting: the Iberian Spot Electricity Market
Nuno Carvalho Figueiredo a,b, Patrícia Pereira da Silva b,c, Pedro Cerqueira c,d
This paper aims to assess the influence of wind power generation on the market splitting behaviour of the Iberian electricity spot markets.
We use logit models to express the probability response for market splitting of day‐
ahead spot electricity prices together with explanatory variables like, wind speed, available transmission capacity and electricity demand.
The results show that the probability of market splitting increases with the increase of wind power generation. The European interconnection capacity target of 10% of the peak demand of the smallest interconnected market has to be reconsidered, in order to keep electricity market integration a reality.
As demonstrated, investment in interconnection capacity has to follow the investment and deployment of further wind power capacity, so coordination policies governing both interconnection development and renewable incentives should be designed.
Keywords ‐ Electricity Market Integration, Market Splitting, Renewable Energy
JEL: C10, C35, D47
1. INTRODUCTION
In Iberia, both the Portuguese and the Spanish wind power sectors were developed with extreme success (Batlle 2011; Moreno and Martínez‐Val 2011; Gelabert et al. 2011;
Ruiz Romero et al. 2012), following the European targets for the promotion of Renewable Energy Source electricity (RES‐E), aiming to reduce dependency on imported fossil fuels and allowing for the reduction in Green House Gas emissions (European Union 2001;
European Union 2009a). Comparing the hourly demand profile with the wind power installed capacity evolution in Iberia (Figure 1) we can observe that currently with the adequate climate conditions, wind power can supply a big share of electricity to the system.
The large deployment of RES‐E generation and in particular of wind power in Europe was achieved by strong financial support mechanisms, like feed‐in tariffs, fiscal incentives, tax exemptions and other (Meyer 2003; Jager et al. 2011; Amorim et al. 2013). This poses new challenges, both in the technical sense and in the market design. Electricity systems
have to be restructured to accommodate RES‐E intermittency (Lynch et al. 2012) and policy design has to reflect required market integration of these technologies (Batlle et al. 2012;
Benatia et al. 2013).
Figure 1 ‐ Hourly demand and wind power installed capacity in Iberia
The impact of high penetration of RES‐E on electricity as been discussed throughout a number of scientific papers and reports. In particular some of the issues discussed related with the high level growth of wind power installed capacity reported are: the importance of adequate interconnections and transmission capacities to transport excess production, electrical system fault endurance, available and flexible standby generating capacity to accommodate load variability and effective control or curtailment of wind power production (Söder et al. 2007; Franco and Salza 2011; Benatia et al. 2013). Also wind forecasting is fundamental to allow wind power load management and electrical system balancing (Milligan et al. 2009).
Due to the almost inexistent marginal costs of RES‐E generation, they will come first in the merit order of power plant dispatch. Therefore, by displacing higher marginal cost electricity generation, one could expect some level of decrease on the electricity spot market prices. This fact is reported by several authors (Moreno and López; Sensfuß et al.
2008; Sáenz de Miera et al. 2008; Klessmann et al. 2008; Mauritzen 2010; Jónsson et al.
2010; Amorim et al. 2010; Cruz et al. 2011; Cutler et al. 2011; Gelabert et al. 2011; Mulder and Scholtens 2013).
Several authors have studied electricity market integration, as it is one of the main objectives in Europe. Studies were made concerning different geographic areas: De Vany &
Walls (1999), Park, Mjelde, & Bessler (2006) in the US regional markets; Worthington, Kay‐
Spratley & Higgs (2005) and Higgs (2009) in Australia; Bower (2002), Boisseleau (2004), Armstrong and Galli (2005), Zachmann (2008), Bosco et al. (2010), Bunn and Gianfreda (2010), Pellini (2012) and Figueiredo and Silva (2012 and 2013) in Europe. Nonetheless, literature lacks on the assessment of the impacts that the high penetration of RES‐E generation have on interconnected market behaviour. The market coupling/splitting mechanism and its behaviour considering the influence of high wind power penetration is therefore herein offered.
In the following section a summary of the electricity market reform and an overview of the market coupling/splitting mechanisms, in place in the Iberian spot electricity markets, is given. The interconnections available in Iberia are described in Section 3 and the data used in this study is presented in Section 4. The estimated models are described in Section 5, followed by the analysis and discussion of results in Section 6. Conclusions can be found in Section 7.
2. REGIONAL ELECTRICITY MARKETS
Successive European Directives (European Union 1997; European Union 2003a;
European Union 2009b) where issued with the objective to established common rules for the various electricity markets in Europe, based on the liberalisation of the sector, without prejudice of the public service required and the access by the generators and consumers to the transmission and distribution grids (Jamasb and Pollitt 2005). These requirements are guaranteed by regulating authorities established in each country (Silva 2007). Member‐
States would take necessary measures to facilitate transit of electricity between transmission grids in accordance with the conditions laid down (European Union 2003b;
European Union 2009c) in order to achieve an adequate integration of national electricity transmission grids and associated increase of electricity cross‐border transfers, ensuring the optimization of the production infrastructure (Jacottet 2012). However, with this set up, back in 2006 market integration in Europe was still far from being achieved (Coppens and Vivet 2006), which led to the creation of Regional Electricity Markets, to provide an intermediate step for the consolidated European Electricity Market (ERGEG 2006).
The interaction between electricity markets within a region can occur through high voltage interconnections with limited capacity. This limited interconnection capacity might have additional constraints due to the electricity physical behavior, originating unidentified flows not necessarily related with cross‐border trading or contracts. A consumer that contracted with one generator across the border will probably receive electricity from a different generator causing the so called Loop Flow Problem (Coppens and Vivet 2006).
One of the preferred methods and currently used to link interconnected spot markets is through a market coupling mechanism, where markets with lower prices export electricity to markets with higher prices through interconnections (Meeus et al. 2009). If the interconnection capacity is large enough to accommodate the exported electricity flows
(without congestion) then the price is the same in both markets, otherwise market splitting occurs and two regional market prices are cleared (EPEX et al. 2010). The basis of this mechanism is the calculation of the Available Transfer Capacity (ATC), which is made by the Transmission System Operators (TSO) taking into account the safety and reliability of the electrical system, together with an allowable safety margin. Therefore import and export ATC can have different values depending on loop flows and technical constraints (Luna and Martínez 2011).
Figure 2 – Market coupling without congestion (EPEX
et al. 2010)
Figure 3 – Market coupling with congestion – market splitting (EPEX et al. 2010)
3. THE IBERIAN INTERCONNECTIONS
The Portugal‐Spain electrical interconnection currently consists of eight HV lines. A new interconnection line between Tavira and P. Guzman is being constructed (to be concluded by REE on the Spanish side) and another new line is forecasted to be in service by 2015 between V. Fria and O Covelo, which with several other internal line reinforcements will allow the completion of the interconnection capacity between Portugal and Spain of 3000 MW, essential for the joint Iberian electricity market MIBEL (REN 2013).
Cross‐border interconnections offer numerous advantages under normal operating conditions, such as optimal power station daily production, increasing opportunities for operation with renewable energies, the promotion of competition and enhancement of supply security (Figueiredo and Silva 2012). However, interconnectors are limited and have constraints due to the physical behaviour of electricity, which flows through the easiest path. Therefore, high voltage grids interconnected through many interconnectors placed in different geographic positions originate unidentified flows not necessarily related with cross‐border contracts causing congestion of transmission lines and interconnectors, the so called Loop Flow Problem (Coppens and Vivet 2006).
It is the TSO responsibility to manage the above mentioned constraints (Turvey 2006) and to deal specifically with cross‐border exchanges in electricity, which in turn have to comply with European Community Regulation 1228/2003/EC of 26 June 2003 and also later with European Community Regulation 714/2009 of 13 July 2009. These regulations establish a set of rules for cross‐border exchanges in electricity, in order to enhance competition, establish a compensation mechanism for cross‐border flows of electricity, setting principles on cross‐border transmission charges and allocating available capacities of interconnections (European Union 2003c; European Union 2009c). With the third legislative package the creation of the European Network of Transmission System
Operators (ENTSO) was established, aiming to prepare network codes to guarantee an efficient transmission network management, together with allowing trade and supply of electricity across borders. The Agency for the Cooperation of Energy Regulators (ACER) requested ENTSO to draft the so called network codes, laying down common rules applicable to the energy sector (ENTSO‐E 2014a). As part of these, the Network Code on Capacity Allocation and Congestion Management (CACM) will establish the interconnection capacity allocation methods to be applied in the European markets. ACER has recommended the adoption of this code by the European Commission on the 26th of May 2014 (ACER 2014).
4. DATA
Hourly price data and ATC were extracted from the OMIE data download web page (OMIE 2013) for the day‐ahead spot electricity prices in €/MWh, for Portugal and Spain.
Demand data was extracted from the European Network of Transmission System Operators for Electricity data portal (ENTSO‐E 2014b). Additionally, wind power installed capacities in both Iberian countries were obtained from Eurostat statistics bulk data download web page (Eurostat 2013) and wind speed data extracted from Weather Underground web page (Weather Wunderground 2013). Wind speed data was then validated and averaged over each hour and geographically, considering the areas with higher concentration of wind parks installed in each country (The Wind Power 2013).
In Figure 4 the spot electricity prices for the both Iberian countries are plotted, together with the corresponding differences. Market integration in Iberia was demonstrated in other studies (Figueiredo and Silva 2013a; Figueiredo and Silva 2013b), however we can still observe many market splitting occurrences.
Concerning the ATC (Figure 5), the increase in interconnection capacity between the two Iberian countries is visible in the plot, with the last improvement being observed in mid 2012. It is also to note that ATC limitations are more often observed in the direction Spain to Portugal.
Figure 4 – Spot electricity prices and corresponding differences in Iberia
In Figure 6 the average wind speed in both Iberian countries is plotted and the reader can observe the big variability created in wind generation. However, we cannot see a clear seasonality in the wind speed pattern, which means that wind generation might be present throughout all seasons of the year.
Summary statistics for the time series are presented in Table 1. Skewness and kurtosis values indicate that all price time‐series have non‐normal distribution, which is confirmed by Jarque‐Bera statistic rejection of the null for normal distribution testing.
Figure 5 – Available Transfer Capacities in Iberia
Figure 6 – Wind speed in Iberia
Table 1
Time series summary statistics
MIBEL
Portugal
MIBEL Spain
Price difference
PT‐ES
ATC ES‐PT
ATC PT‐ES
Demand Spain
Demand Portugal
Wind Speed Spain
Wind Speed Portugal
[€/MWh] [€/MWh] [€/MWh] [MW] [MW] [MW] [MW] [km/h] [km/h]
Mean 46.71161 45.60964 1.101976 1548.897 1566.429 29143.02 5752.907 5.663591 6.519888
Median 46.5 46 0 1500 1500 29279 5729 5.003364 5.823533
Maximum 180.3 145 136.3 2400 2400 44258 9397 26.35932 28.37574
Minimum 0 0 ‐47.46 50 150 1067 3310 0.892408 0.605483
Std. Dev. 15.58027 15.21566 4.233299 439.352 514.4117 5286.531 1084.979 2.863928 3.569009 Skewness 0.003219 ‐0.14001 4.166229 ‐0.178521 0.095002 0.050637 0.263738 0.863859 0.915203 Kurtosis 4.111249 4.009405 70.77425 2.624141 2.029153 2.432735 2.289435 3.620756 3.818572
Jarque‐Bera 1984.458 1763.332 7492891 431.868 1572.642 533.5838 1258.464 5416.005 6460.184
Probability 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
Observations 38567 38567 38567 38567 38567 38567 38567 38567 38564
5. MODEL ESTIMATION
The estimated models aim to provide indications about the behaviour of the market splitting mechanism in the Iberian spot electricity markets, considering the wind power penetration in these same markets. We have modelled the probability of market splitting as a function of relevant explanatory variables related with wind power generation and market splitting mechanism. To model the split probability we can describe it in terms of a non‐observable latent variable (Split*) such that:
1| ∗ , 1 ∗ 0 (1)
,where Split is the binary variable of occurring market splitting conditional to X explanatory variables and e is the error term.
In order to overcome some limitations of the linear probability models, namely the fact that we can obtain probabilities below zero or above one (Davidson and Mackinnon 2004), through a transformation function we have used models of the form:
1| , ∗ , 1 ∗ 0 (2)
,where G is a cumulative distribution function (cdf), which in the case of the probit model is the normal distribution cdf, where e has a standard normal distribution, and in the case of the logit is the logistic distribution cdf, where e has a standard logistic distribution.
We have opted to use the logit model as our binary response model, due to the fact that the probit model latent error does not follow a normal distribution (Wooldridge 2003).
Therefore:
1| ∗ 0| 0| (3)
,where X is a matrix of explanatory variables and e is the error term that is an independently distributed variable following the standard logistic distribution, from which we can obtain,
| 1 Λ Λ , where Λ (4)
In this study the wind speed is the main explanatory variable used in our models, expressing the amount of electricity generated from wind energy sources. The two other explanatory variables used are related with demand of each country and the ATC between both spot electricity markets. The former expresses the ability of the country to consume the electricity produced by wind energy sources and the latter expresses the ability to export the electricity generated at lower marginal costs.
Wind power curves are well described by a third order polynomial in the wind speed (Joensen et al. 1999; Stathopoulos et al. 2013). Therefore we modelled the probability of market splitting as a function of the ratio of the third order polynomial in wind speed and the demand in each spot electricity market, following the concept of wind power penetration level (Jónsson et al. 2010). Another concept introduced in the model is the ratio of ATC to demand expressing the size of interconnection capacity compared with the demand of each market.
The estimated model associated to the latent variable is:
∗ ∙ ∙ ∙ ∙ ∙
∙ ∙ ∙
,where Split is the binary variable of occurring market splitting, WSPT and WSES are the average wind speeds in Portugal and Spain respectively, ATCPT‐ES and ATCES‐PT the available transmission capacity for both directions of the interconnections and DPT and DES the demand in Portugal and Spain respectively.
In the estimated models (Table 2) all coefficients are significant to 0.1%, having a value for Percent Correctly Predicted of 79.69%, in spite of the rather low McFadden pseudo R‐
square. The “Neglected Heterogeneity” specification issue might have an influence on the coefficient estimates causing an underestimation of the effects, however relative effects of the explanatory variables can be extracted (Mood 2009; Wooldridge 2010).
Table 2
OMIE market splitting model 1 – No Heteroskedasticity correction
Dependent variable: Split
Coefficients:
Estimate Std. Error z value Pr(>|z|)
0 ‐1.3617 0.0686 ‐19.85 <2e‐16 ***
1 2178.3855 147.5561 14.76 <2e‐16 ***
2 ‐261.8331 17.2916 ‐15.14 <2e‐16 ***
3 7.9904 0.5881 13.59 <2e‐16 ***
4 20604.4118 903.0495 22.82 <2e‐16 ***
5 ‐2611.7491 135.4113 ‐19.29 <2e‐16 ***
6 98.4730 6.0111 16.38 <2e‐16 ***
7 ‐2.1370 0.1515 ‐14.10 <2e‐16 ***
8 ‐35.0798 0.9519 ‐36.85 <2e‐16 ***
Signif. codes: 0 ‘***’ 0.001 ‘**’ 0.01 ‘*’ 0.05 ‘.’ 0.1 ‘ ’ 1
Log‐likelihood: ‐1.784e+04 on 9 Df
Studentized Breusch‐Pagan test
data: ms.logit
BP = 4199.087, df = 8, p‐value < 2.2e‐16
Percent correctly predicted: 79.69%
McFadden pseudo R‐squared:
'log Lik.' 0.07897156 (df=9)
Another present specification issue is the heteroskedasticity of the error term, which is observed in the estimated model. In order to overcome this, an additional model was estimated attempting to correct this issue,
1| Λ , ∗ , ~Λ 0, exp 2 (5)
1| Λ , ∗ , ~Λ 0, exp 2 (6)
,where X’ is a matrix of explanatory variables belonging to the original information set and a vector of parameters to be estimated (Davidson and Mackinnon 2004). The market splitting probability is then not only dependent on the original regression function, but also on the skedastic function. The correction attempted was done by considering the ratio
average wind speed over demand, both in Portugal and Spain. These variables were initially chosen due to to high variability expected in the wind speed, thus in the wind power generated. The inclusion of further variables in the correction term made the model not to converge and are not herein presented.
Table 3
OMIE market splitting model 2 – WS/D Heteroskedasticity correction
Dependent variable: Split
Coefficients (binomial model with logit link):
Estimate Std. Error z value Pr(>|z|)
0 ‐2.290e+00 1.883e‐01 ‐12.161 <2e‐16 ***
1 4.118e+03 4.004e+02 10.283 <2e‐16 ***
2 ‐5.364e+02 5.432e+01 ‐9.874 <2e‐16 ***
3 1.752e+01 1.974e+00 8.873 <2e‐16 ***
4 1.041e+05 5.361e+03 19.416 <2e‐16 ***
5 ‐2.102e+04 1.104e+03 ‐19.047 <2e‐16 ***
6 1.003e+03 5.428e+01 18.473 <2e‐16 ***
7 ‐7.024e+00 4.773e‐01 ‐14.716 <2e‐16 ***
8 ‐9.421e+01 4.399e+00 ‐21.414 <2e‐16 ***
Latent scale model coefficients (with log link):
Estimate Std. Error z value Pr(>|z|)
1 11.90 29.45 0.404 0.686
2 5577.54 227.25 24.543 <2e‐16 ***
‐‐‐
Signif. codes: 0 '***' 0.001 '**' 0.01 '*' 0.05 '.' 0.1 ' ' 1
Log‐likelihood: ‐1.758e+04 on 11 Df
LR test for homoskedasticity: 524.5 on 2 Df, p‐value: < 2.2e‐16 Dispersion: 1
Number of iterations in nlminb optimization: 26
Percent correctly predicted: 79.41%
McFadden pseudo R‐squared:
'log Lik.' 0.09251255 (df=11)
The logit model coefficients cannot be interpreted directly so predicted probabilities were calculated for some created data sets as shown and analysed in the next section.
6. ANALYSIS AND DISCUSSION OF RESULTS
Prediction results from the models express that market splitting probability increases when the wind speed is higher, consequently with higher wind power generation (Figure 7). This can be explained by having low marginal cost electricity available to flow across the
border. It is to note the steep inflexion of the surface around a certain average wind speed (10 km/h for Spain in model 2 and 20 km/h for Portugal in both models), meaning that market splitting probability as a dramatic increase above a determined wind speed. Also to note is the loss of symetry when introducing the heroskedasticity correction, which may actually make sense due to the different sizes of the Portuguese and the Spanish electricity markets. With low average wind speeds in Spain the market splitting probability responds quite drastically to an increase in the Portuguese wind speed, whilst this effect looses its influence when the average wind speed increases in Spain. Model 2 in this respect has a more consistent behaviour than model 1 as the different sizes of the electrical systems play a role in the asymmetric behaviour of the market splitting probability.
Further predictions were then made at different average wind speeds to evaluate probability response to ATC and demand.
Figure 7 –OMIE – Predicted probability response to average wind speed
Market splitting probability decreases with increasing ATC (allowing higher flows of electricity between markets), as one could expect by the concept definition of market splitting (Figure 8). Considering the mean of the average wind speed and the existing interconnection capacity between both spot electricity markets we can conclude that the existing interconnection level is adequate, bearing in mind that it is actually higher than the European Union recommendation of 10% of the peak demand of the smaller interconnected market (Amorim et al. 2014). The same tendency of decreasing probability response to increasing ATC can be seen in both models estimated, however different shapes for the probability response surfaces can be observed with increasing average wind speed (Figure 10 and Figure 11 of Appendix A). Moreover, in order to have a reasonable market splitting probability level and maintain both spot electricity markets integrated, the
requirements for interconnection capacity should increase with increasing available wind power.
Notwidstanding the specification issues of the estimated models and considering the double of the wind power generation level available in the system (corresponding to an average wind speed level of 10 km/h), we estimate that in order to maintain the current market splitting occurrence probability (around 5% with an ATC of 2500 MW and at mean average wind speed), the interconnection capacity should be increased to 3700 MW (Table 4).
Table 4 – OMIE market splitting probability estimates
WS/D heteroskedasticity correction
ATC level [MW] Mean of the average wind speed
Average wind speed of 10 km/h
2500 5% 11%
2700 4% 10%
2900 3% 9%
3100 2% 8%
3300 2% 7%
3500 1% 6%
3700 1% 5%
Considering an average wind speed of 20 km/h, as observed in Figure 11, the market splitting probability response to ATC does not decrease significantly, demonstrating that there is a limit for wind power generation from where investment in increasing interconnection capacity is not capable of improving electricity spot market integration.
Figure 8 –OMIE – Predicted probability response to ATC at mean average wind speed
Figure 9 –OMIE – Predicted probability response to demand at mean average wind speed
The probability response predictions to demand for the mean average wind speed in the estimated models are plotted in Figure 9. Here we can observe a different behaviour between the two models and an asymmetry between the Portuguese and Spanish
probability response behaviour to demand. By increasing demand in only one of the markets, generation with higher marginal costs in this market would set the clearing price, causing lower marginal cost electricity to be imported through the interconnection and leading eventually to a high probability of market splitting occurrence. This behaviour could explain model 1 at mean average wind speed for the Spanish demand response, but not the Portuguese demand response, maybe due to their relative sizes. This, of course, would only happen if there is enough lower marginal cost electricity in the other market, in this case in Portugal, otherwise an increasing demand would cause a decrease of the market splitting probability, as the available low marginal cost electricity would be consumed internally. This behaviour is actually consistent with the observed in model 2 at mean average wind speed. Also when the wind speed increases, having more low marginal cost electricity available in the system, the market splitting probability increases even with the increasing demand due to the available excess of low marginal cost electricity and inverting the normal behaviour of the system (Figure 13).
7. CONCLUSIONS
One of the benefits of the integration of spot electricity markets is the optimization of RES‐E generation. The influence of high penetration of wind energy source electricity generation and its integration, together with the requirement to achieve an Iberian integrated electricity spot market is herein studied. Market splitting behaviour was modelled through logit models estimating the probabilities of its occurrence.
It is shown that when the wind speed is higher, consequently having higher wind power generation available, market splitting probability increases. To maintain the same market splitting probability level with increasing wind speed, consequently with increasing available low marginal cost electricity in the system, the requirements for interconnection capacity have to increase.
As demonstrated, investment in interconnection capacity has to follow the investment and deployment of further wind power capacity, so coordination policies governing both interconnection development and renewable incentives should be designed. Also as an indicative requirement, additional interconnection capacity to reach 3700 MW is required if Iberia doubles its available wind power generation, or any other low marginal cost generation, in the system.
In order to accomplish the aimed future decarbonisation of the European Union’s power sector, renewables expansion and in particular wind power generation will have to increase. Moreover, the reality of electricity market integration at a European level can only be aimed if the interconnection capacity target of 10% of the peak demand of the smallest interconnected market is re‐evaluated and increased. Availability of large amounts of wind power generation will have to be managed in order to optimize infrastructure.
Regulation should be adjusted and coordinated to allow different mechanisms for optimization, deployment of effective energy storage facilities, wind power production curtailment and transmission system expansion.
Future work is required to explore other type of models, in order to overcome the limitations and specification issues of the logit models described in this paper.
8. ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
This Work has been framed under the Energy for Sustainability Initiative of the University of Coimbra, supported by the R&D Project EMSURE, Energy and Mobility for Sustainable Regions (CENTRO 07 0224 FEDER 002004) and also partially supported by the Portuguese Foundation for Science and Technology under project grant[s] PEst‐OE/
EEI/UI308/2014.
This paper was written while the third author was a visiting scholar at the Economics Department of the University of Massachussets, Amherst with support of the FCT grant
#SFRH/BSAB/1340/2013.
We would also like to recognise the kind assistance provided by the Portuguese TSO REN for making data available.
REFERENCES
ACER (2014) ACER recommends the adoption of the Network Code on Forward Capacity Allocation.
http://www.acer.europa.eu/Media/News/Pages/ACER‐recommends‐the‐adoption‐of‐the‐Network‐
Code‐on‐Forward‐Capacity‐Allocation.aspx. Accessed 3 Jun 2014
Amorim F, Martins MVM, Pereira da Silva P (2010) A new perspective to account for renewables impacts in Portugal. 2010 7th Int. Conf. Eur. Energy Mark. IEEE, pp 1–6
Amorim F, Pina A, Gerbelová H, et al. (2014) Electricity decarbonisation pathways for 2050 in Portugal: A TIMES (The Integrated MARKAL‐EFOM System) based approach in closed versus open systems modelling. Energy in press. doi: 10.1016/j.energy.2014.01.052
Amorim F, Vasconcelos J, Abreu IC, et al. (2013) How much room for a competitive electricity generation market in Portugal? Renew Sustain Energy Rev 18:103–118. doi: 10.1016/j.rser.2012.10.010
Armstrong M, Galli A (2005) Are day‐ahead prices for electricity converging in continental Europe? An exploratory data aproach. Cern Work Pap 33:1–18.
Batlle C (2011) A method for allocating renewable energy source subsidies among final energy consumers.
Energy Policy 39:2586–2595. doi: 10.1016/j.enpol.2011.02.027
Batlle C, Pérez‐Arriaga IJ, Zambrano‐Barragán P (2012) Regulatory design for RES‐E support mechanisms:
Learning curves, market structure, and burden‐sharing. Energy Policy 41:212–220. doi:
10.1016/j.enpol.2011.10.039
Benatia D, Johnstone N, Haščič I (2013) Effectiveness of Policies and Strategies to Increase the Capacity Utilisation of Intermittent Renewable Power Plants. OECD Environ Work Pap OECD Publ 1–49. doi:
10.1787/5k46j0trlrnn‐en
Boisseleau F (2004) The role of power exchanges for the creation of a single European electricity market:
market design and market regulation. 405.
Bosco B, Parisio L, Pelagatti M, Baldi F (2010) Long‐run relations in European electricity prices. J Appl Econom 25:805–832. doi: 10.1002/jae.1095
Bower J (2002) Seeking the Single European Electricity Market ‐ Evidence from an Emprirical Analysis of Wholesale Market Prices. Report, Oxford Inst Energy Stud 1–42.
Bunn DW, Gianfreda A (2010) Integration and shock transmissions across European electricity forward markets. Energy Econ 32:278–291. doi: 10.1016/j.eneco.2009.09.005
Coppens F, Vivet D (2006) The single European electricity market : A long road to convergence. Natl Bank Belgium, Work Pap 1–53.
Cruz A, Muñoz A, Zamora JL, Espínola R (2011) The effect of wind generation and weekday on Spanish electricity spot price forecasting. Electr Power Syst Res 81:1924–1935. doi: 10.1016/j.epsr.2011.06.002 Cutler NJ, Boerema ND, MacGill IF, Outhred HR (2011) High penetration wind generation impacts on spot
prices in the Australian national electricity market. Energy Policy 39:5939–5949. doi:
10.1016/j.enpol.2011.06.053
Davidson R, Mackinnon JG (2004) Econometric Theory and Methods, illustrate. Oxford University Press ENTSO‐E (2014a) Network Code Overview. https://www.entsoe.eu/major‐projects/network‐code‐
development/. Accessed 3 Jun 2014
ENTSO‐E (2014b) Country Data Packages. https://www.entsoe.eu/data/data‐portal/country‐packages/.
Accessed 6 Mar 2014
EPEX, apx‐endex, BelPEX (2010) CWE MARKET COUPLING ALGORITHM. 1–19.
ERGEG (2006) The Electricity Regional Initiative: Making Progress Towards a Single European Market. Electr Reg Initiat ‐ Fact Sheet 1–5.
European Union (2001) Directive 2001/77/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 27 September 2001 on the promotion of electricity produced from renewable energy sources in the internal electricity market. Off J Eur Communities L283:33–40.
European Union (2009a) Directive 2009/28/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 23 April 2009 on the promotion of the use of energy from renewable sources and amending and subsequently repealing Directives 2001/77/EC and 2003/30/EC. Off J Eur Union L140:16–62.
European Union (1997) Directive 96/92/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 19 December 1996 concerning common rules for the internal market in electricity. Off J Eur Union L 027:0020 – 0029.
European Union (2003a) Directive 2003/54/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 26 June 2003 concerning common rules for the internal market in electricity and repealing Directive 96/92/EC. Off J Eur Union L 176:37–56.
European Union (2009b) Directive 2009/72/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 13 July 2009 concerning common rules for the internal market in electricity and repealing Directive 2003/54/EC. Off J Eur Union L 211:55–93.
European Union (2003b) Regulation (EC) No 1228/2003 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 26 June 2003 on conditions for access to the network for cross‐border exchanges in electricity. Off J Eur Union L176:1–10.
European Union (2009c) Regulation (EC) No 714/2009 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 13 July 2009 on conditions for access to the network for cross‐border exchanges in electricity and repealing Regulation (EC) No 1228/2003. Off J Eur Union L 211:15–35.
European Union (2003c) European Community Regulation 1228/2003/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 26 June 2003 on conditions for access to the network for cross‐border exchanges in electricity. Off J Eur Union L 176:1–10.
Eurostat (2013) Eurostat Statistics ‐ Bulk download.
http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/portal/page/portal/statistics/bulk_download. Accessed 28 Dec 2013 Figueiredo N, Silva PP da (2012) Integration of South‐West Spot Electricity Markets: An Update. Conf.
Proceedings, 12th IAEE ‐ Eur. Energy Conf. pp 1–14
Figueiredo N, Silva PP da (2013a) Explanatory Variables on South‐West Spot Electricity Markets Integration.
Conf. Proceedings, ICEE ‐ Energy Environ. bringing together Econ. Eng. pp 1–13
Figueiredo NC, Silva PP da (2013b) Integration of Central West Europe spot electricity markets: An update.
2013 10th Int Conf Eur Energy Mark 1–7. doi: 10.1109/EEM.2013.6607299
Franco A, Salza P (2011) Strategies for optimal penetration of intermittent renewables in complex energy systems based on techno‐operational objectives. Renew Energy 36:743–753. doi:
10.1016/j.renene.2010.07.022
Gelabert L, Labandeira X, Linares P (2011) An ex‐post analysis of the effect of renewables and cogeneration on Spanish electricity prices. Energy Econ 33:S59–S65. doi: 10.1016/j.eneco.2011.07.027
Higgs H (2009) Modelling price and volatility inter‐relationships in the Australian wholesale spot electricity markets. Energy Econ 31:748–756. doi: 10.1016/j.eneco.2009.05.003
Jacottet A (2012) Cross‐border electricity interconnections for a well‐functioning EU Internal Electricity Market. 1–17.
Jager D de, Klessmann C, Stricker E, et al. (2011) Financing Renewable Energy in the European Energy Market.
Report, Ecofys 1–264.
Jamasb T, Pollitt M (2005) Electricity Market Reform in the European Union : Review of Progress toward Liberalization & Integration. Energy J 26:11–41.
Joensen AK, Giebel G, Landberg L, et al. (1999) Model output statistics applied to wind power prediction.
Wind Energy Next Millenn. Nice ‐ France, pp 1177–1180
Jónsson T, Pinson P, Madsen H (2010) On the market impact of wind energy forecasts. Energy Econ 32:313–
320. doi: 10.1016/j.eneco.2009.10.018
Klessmann C, Nabe C, Burges K (2008) Pros and cons of exposing renewables to electricity market risks—A comparison of the market integration approaches in Germany, Spain, and the UK. Energy Policy 36:3646–3661. doi: 10.1016/j.enpol.2008.06.022
Luna L, Martínez J (2011) IMPACT OF WIND POWER GENERATION ON THE ATC VALUE.
Lynch MÁ, Tol RSJ, O’Malley MJ (2012) Optimal interconnection and renewable targets for north‐west Europe. Energy Policy 51:605–617. doi: 10.1016/j.enpol.2012.09.002
Mauritzen J (2010) What happens when it’s windy in denmark? an empirical analysis of wind power on price volatility in the nordic electricity market. 1–29.
Meeus L, Vandezande L, Cole S, Belmans R (2009) Market coupling and the importance of price coordination between power exchanges. Energy 34:228–234. doi: 10.1016/j.energy.2008.04.013
Meyer NI (2003) European schemes for promoting renewables in liberalised markets. Energy Policy 31:665–
676. doi: 10.1016/S0301‐4215(02)00151‐9
Milligan M, Lew D, Corbus D, et al. (2009) Large‐Scale Wind Integration Studies in the United States : Preliminary Results. Report, 8th Int Work Large Scale Integr Wind Power Transm Networks Offshore Wind Farms 1–5.
Mood C (2009) Logistic Regression: Why We Cannot Do What We Think We Can Do, and What We Can Do About It. Eur Sociol Rev 26:67–82. doi: 10.1093/esr/jcp006
Moreno B, López AJ The electricity prices in European Union . The role of renewable energies and regulatory electric market reforms. 6th Dubrovnik Conf. Sustain. Dev. energy water Environ. Syst. pp 1–13
Moreno F, Martínez‐Val JM (2011) Collateral effects of renewable energies deployment in Spain: Impact on thermal power plants performance and management. Energy Policy 39:6561–6574. doi:
10.1016/j.enpol.2011.07.061
Mulder M, Scholtens B (2013) The impact of renewable energy on electricity prices in the Netherlands. Renew Energy 57:94–100. doi: 10.1016/j.renene.2013.01.025
OMIE (2013) http://www.omie.es/inicio. http://www.omie.es/inicio. Accessed 6 Aug 2013
Park H, Mjelde JW, Bessler D a. (2006) Price dynamics among U.S. electricity spot markets. Energy Econ 28:81–101. doi: 10.1016/j.eneco.2005.09.009
Pellini E (2012) Wholesale Spot Markets : Still a Way To Go. Proc. 12th IAEE ‐ Eur. Energy Conf. pp 1–16 REN (2013) Caracterização das interligações em 31 de Dezembro de 2012. 1–64.
Ruiz Romero S, Colmenar Santos A, Castro Gil MA (2012) EU plans for renewable energy. An application to the Spanish case. Renew Energy 43:322–330. doi: 10.1016/j.renene.2011.11.033
Sáenz de Miera G, del Río González P, Vizcaíno I (2008) Analysing the impact of renewable electricity support schemes on power prices: The case of wind electricity in Spain. Energy Policy 36:3345–3359. doi:
10.1016/j.enpol.2008.04.022
Sensfuß F, Ragwitz M, Genoese M (2008) The merit‐order effect: A detailed analysis of the price effect of renewable electricity generation on spot market prices in Germany. Energy Policy 36:3086–3094. doi:
10.1016/j.enpol.2008.03.035
Silva PP da (2007) O sector da energia eléctrica na União Europeia: Evolução e Perspectivas. Coimbra University Press
Söder L, Hofmann L, Orths A, et al. (2007) Experience From Wind Integration in Some High Penetration Areas.
IEEE Trans Energy Convers 22:4–12. doi: 10.1109/TEC.2006.889604
Stathopoulos C, Kaperoni A, Galanis G, Kallos G (2013) Wind power prediction based on numerical and statistical models. J Wind Eng Ind Aerodyn 112:25–38. doi: 10.1016/j.jweia.2012.09.004
The Wind Power (2013) The Wind Power. http://www.thewindpower.net/. Accessed 1 Oct 2013
Turvey R (2006) Interconnector economics. Energy Policy 34:1457–1472. doi: 10.1016/j.enpol.2004.11.009 De Vany AS, Walls WD (1999) Cointegration analysis of spot electricity prices: insights on transmission
efficiency in the western US. Energy Econ 21:435–448. doi: 10.1016/S0140‐9883(99)00019‐5 Weather Wunderground (2013) Weather Underground. www.wunderground.com. Accessed 1 Dec 2013 Wooldridge J (2010) Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data, 2nd ed. 752.
Wooldridge JM (2003) Introductory Econometrics ‐ A modern approach, 2nd ed. Econ Anal 824.
Worthington A, Kay‐Spratley A, Higgs H (2005) Transmission of prices and price volatility in Australian electricity spot markets: a multivariate GARCH analysis. Energy Econ 27:337–350. doi:
10.1016/j.eneco.2003.11.002
Zachmann G (2008) Electricity wholesale market prices in Europe: Convergence? Energy Econ 30:1659–1671.
doi: 10.1016/j.eneco.2007.07.002
APPENDIX A
Figure 10 – OMIE – No correction for heteroskedasticity ‐ ATC predicted probability response with 10, 15, 20 and 25 km/h average wind speed
Figure 11 – OMIE – WS/D correction for heteroskedasticity ‐ ATC predicted probability response with 10, 15,
20, and 25 km/h average wind speed
APPENDIX B
Figure 12 – OMIE – No correction for heteroskedasticity ‐ Demand predicted probability response with 10, 15, 20, and 25 km/h average wind speed
Figure 13 – OMIE – WS/D correction for heteroskedasticity ‐ Demand predicted probability response with 10, 15, 20, and 25 km/h average wind speed
E
STUDOS DOG.E.M.F.
(Available on-line at http://www.uc.pt/feuc/gemf )
2014-14 The Renewables Influence on Market Splitting: the Iberian Spot Electricity Market - Nuno Carvalho Figueiredo, Patrícia Pereira da Silva & Pedro Cerqueira
2014-13 Drivers for Household Electricity Prices in the EU: A System-GMM Panel Data Approach - Patrícia Pereira da Silva & Pedro Cerqueira
2014-12 Effectiveness of Intellectual Property Regimes: 2006-2011 - Noemí Pulido Pavón & Luis Palma Martos
2014-11 Dealing with Technological Risk in a Regulatory Context: The Case of Smart Grids - Paulo Moisés Costa, Nuno Bento & Vítor Marques
2014-10 Stochastic Volatility Estimation with GPU Computing - António Alberto Santos & João Andrade
2014-09 The Impact of Expectations, Match Importance and Results in the Stock Prices of European Football Teams
- Pedro Godinho & Pedro Cerqueira
2014-08 Is the Slovak Economy Doing Well? A Twin Deficit Growth Approach - Elias Soukiazis, Eva Muchova & Pedro A. Cerqueira
2014-07 The Role of Gender in Promotion and Pay over a Career - John T. Addison, Orgul D. Ozturk & Si Wang
2014-06 Output-gaps in the PIIGS Economies: An Ingredient of a Greek Tragedy - João Sousa Andrade & António Portugal Duarte
2014-05 Software Piracy: A Critical Survey of the Theoretical and Empirical Literature - Nicolas Dias Gomes, Pedro André Cerqueira & Luís Alçada Almeida
2014-04 Agriculture in Portugal: Linkages with Industry and Services - João Gaspar, Gilson Pina & Marta C. N. Simões
2014-03 Effects of Taxation on Software Piracy Across the European Union - Nicolas Dias Gomes, Pedro André Cerqueira & Luís Alçada Almeida
2014-02 A Crise Portuguesa é Anterior à Crise Internacional - João Sousa Andrade
2014-01 Collective Bargaining and Innovation in Germany: Cooperative Industrial Relations?
- John T. Addison, Paulino Teixeira, Katalin Evers & Lutz Bellmann
2013-27 Market Efficiency, Roughness and Long Memory in the PSI20 Index Returns: Wavelet and Entropy Analysis
- Rui Pascoal & Ana Margarida Monteiro
2013-26 Do Size, Age and Dividend Policy Provide Useful Measures of Financing Constraints? New Evidence from a Panel of Portuguese Firms
- Carlos Carreira & Filipe Silva
2013-25 A Política Orçamental em Portugal entre Duas Intervenções do FMI: 1986-2010 - Carlos Fonseca Marinheiro
2013-24 Distortions in the Neoclassical Growth Model: A Cross-Country Analysis - Pedro Brinca
2013-23 Learning, Exporting and Firm Productivity: Evidence from Portuguese Manufacturing and Services Firms
- Carlos Carreira
2013-22 Equity Premia Predictability in the EuroZone - Nuno Silva
2013-21 Human Capital and Growth in a Services Economy: the Case of Portugal - Marta Simões & Adelaide Duarte
2013-20 Does Voter Turnout Affect the Votes for the Incumbent Government?
Estudos do GEMF
2013-18 Despesa Pública em Educação e Saúde e Crescimento Económico: Um Contributo para o Debate sobre as Funções Sociais do Estado
- João Sousa Andrade, Marta Simões & Adelaide P. S. Duarte
2013-17 Duration dependence and change-points in the likelihood of credit booms ending - Vitor Castro & Megumi Kubota
2013-16 Job Promotion in Mid-Career: Gender, Recession and ‘Crowding’
- John T. Addison, Orgul D. Ozturk & Si Wang
2013-15 Mathematical Modeling of Consumer's Preferences Using Partial Differential Equations - Jorge Marques
2013-14 The Effects of Internal and External Imbalances on Italy´s Economic Growth. A Balance of Payments Approach with Relative Prices No Neutral.
- Elias Soukiazis, Pedro André Cerqueira & Micaela Antunes
2013-13 A Regional Perspective on Inequality and Growth in Portugal Using Panel Cointegration Analysis
- Marta Simões, João Sousa Andrade & Adelaide Duarte
2013-12 Macroeconomic Determinants of the Credit Risk in the Banking System: The Case of the GIPSI
- Vítor Castro
2013-11 Majority Vote on Educational Standards - Robert Schwager
2013-10 Productivity Growth and Convergence: Portugal in the EU 1986-2009 - Adelaide Duarte, Marta Simões & João Sousa Andrade
2013-09 What Determines the Duration of a Fiscal Consolidation Program?
- Luca Agnello, Vítor Castro & Ricardo M. Sousa
2013-08 Minimum Wage Increases in a Recessionary Environment - John T. Addison, McKinley L. Blackburn & Chad D. Cotti
2013-07 The International Monetary System in Flux: Overview and Prospects - Pedro Bação, António Portugal Duarte & Mariana Simões
2013-06 Are There Change-Points in the Likelihood of a Fiscal Consolidation Ending?
- Luca Agnello, Vitor Castro & Ricardo M. Sousa
2013-05 The Dutch Disease in the Portuguese Economy - João Sousa Andrade & António Portugal Duarte
2013-04 Is There Duration Dependence in Portuguese Local Governments’ Tenure?
- Vítor Castro & Rodrigo Martins
2013-03 Testing for Nonlinear Adjustment in the Portuguese Target Zone: Is there a Honeymoon Effect?
- António Portugal Duarte, João Soares da Fonseca & Adelaide Duarte
2013-02 Portugal Before and After the European Union - Fernando Alexandre & Pedro Bação
2013-01 The International Integration of the Eastern Europe and two Middle East Stock Markets - José Soares da Fonseca
2012-21 Are Small Firms More Dependent on the Local Environment than Larger Firms? Evidence from Portuguese Manufacturing Firms
- Carlos Carreira & Luís Lopes
2012-20 Macroeconomic Factors of Household Default. Is There Myopic Behaviour?
- Rui Pascoal
2012-19 Can German Unions Still Cut It?
- John Addison, Paulino Teixeira, Jens Stephani & Lutz Bellmann
2012-18 Financial Constraints: Do They Matter to R&D Subsidy Attribution?
- Filipe Silva & Carlos Carreira
2012-17 Worker Productivity and Wages: Evidence from Linked Employer-Employee Data
Estudos do GEMF
2012-16 Slovak Economic Growth and the Consistency of the Balance-of-Payments Constraint Approach
- Elias Soukiazis & Eva Muchova
2012-15 The Importance of a Good Indicator for Global Excess Demand - João Sousa Andrade & António Portugal Duarte
2012-14 Measuring Firms' Financial Constraints: A Rough Guide - Filipe Silva & Carlos Carreira
2012-13 Convergence and Growth: Portugal in the EU 1986-2010 - Marta Simões, João Sousa Andrade & Adelaide Duarte
2012-12 Where Are the Fragilities? The Relationship Between Firms’ Financial Constraints, Size and Age
- Carlos Carreira & Filipe Silva
2012-11 An European Distribution of Income Perspective on Portugal-EU Convergence - João Sousa Andrade, Adelaide Duarte & Marta Simões
2012-10 Financial Crisis and Domino Effect
- Pedro Bação, João Maia Domingues & António Portugal Duarte
2012-09 Non-market Recreational Value of a National Forest: Survey Design and Results - Paula Simões, Luís Cruz & Eduardo Barata
2012-08 Growth rates constrained by internal and external imbalances and the role of relative prices: Empirical evidence from Portugal
- Elias Soukiazis, Pedro André Cerqueira & Micaela Antunes
2012-07 Is the Erosion Thesis Overblown? Evidence from the Orientation of Uncovered Employers - John Addison, Paulino Teixeira, Katalin Evers & Lutz Bellmann
2012-06 Explaining the interrelations between health, education and standards of living in Portugal.
A simultaneous equation approach - Ana Poças & Elias Soukiazis
2012-05 Turnout and the Modeling of Economic Conditions: Evidence from Portuguese Elections - Rodrigo Martins & Francisco José Veiga
2012-04 The Relative Contemporaneous Information Response. A New Cointegration-Based Measure of Price Discovery
- Helder Sebastião
2012-03 Causes of the Decline of Economic Growth in Italy and the Responsibility of EURO.
A Balance-of-Payments Approach.
- Elias Soukiazis, Pedro Cerqueira & Micaela Antunes
2012-02 As Ações Portuguesas Seguem um Random Walk? Implicações para a Eficiência de Mercado e para a Definição de Estratégias de Transação
- Ana Rita Gonzaga & Helder Sebastião
2012-01 Consuming durable goods when stock markets jump: a strategic asset allocation approach - João Amaro de Matos & Nuno Silva
2011-21 The Portuguese Public Finances and the Spanish Horse - João Sousa Andrade & António Portugal Duarte
2011-20 Fitting Broadband Diffusion by Cable Modem in Portugal - Rui Pascoal & Jorge Marques
2011-19 A Poupança em Portugal
- Fernando Alexandre, Luís Aguiar-Conraria, Pedro Bação & Miguel Portela
2011-18 How Does Fiscal Policy React to Wealth Composition and Asset Prices?
- Luca Agnello, Vitor Castro & Ricardo M. Sousa
2011-17 The Portuguese Stock Market Cycle: Chronology and Duration Dependence -Vitor Castro
2011-16 The Fundamentals of the Portuguese Crisis - João Sousa Andrade & Adelaide Duarte
2011-15 The Structure of Collective Bargaining and Worker Representation: Change and Persistence