• No results found

An Empirical Multi Output Production Decision Model for the Profit Maximizing Multiproduct Firm

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2020

Share "An Empirical Multi Output Production Decision Model for the Profit Maximizing Multiproduct Firm"

Copied!
6
0
0

Loading.... (view fulltext now)

Full text

(1)

http://dx.doi.org/10.4236/tel.2015.54065

An Empirical Multi-Output Production

Decision Model for the Profit Maximizing

Multiproduct Firm

Ekaterina Vorotnikova1, Serhat Asci2

1Agricultural Economics and Rural Sociology Department, University of Idaho, Moscow, ID, USA 2Department of Agricultural Business, California State University, Fresno, CA, USA

Email: evorotnikova@uidaho.edu, sasci@csufresno.edu

Received 30 July 2015; accepted 17 August 2015; published 20 August 2015

Copyright © 2015 by authors and Scientific Research Publishing Inc.

This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution International License (CC BY). http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/

Abstract

Empirical estimation of a theoretical multi-output production model that uses multiple inputs is difficult because of the complexities of its functional form. By using proper parameterization to linearize theoretical model’s functional form, this paper develops an empirical estimation for multi-output production decision using multiple inputs in the profit maximizing firm, namely, multi-output production decision model. The model aligns with the dual approach of cost minimi-zation and revenue maximiminimi-zation for the profit maximizing multi-product firm while keeping jointness in production structurally intact.

Keywords

Multiproduct Firm, Multi-Output Production Decision, Differential Production Component

1. Introduction

[1] developed a theory of multiproduct firm and used a differential approach to model a multi-output production using multiple inputs. They theoretically derived input demand and output supply equations for multiproduct firm. The authors also extended these derivations to the input allocation decision for the cost minimizing, the revenue maximizing firms, as well as multi-output production decision for the profit maximizing firms. Howev-er, the complexities of the equations presented some barriers to empirical estimation of such models. This paper developed an empirical estimation model for multi-output production decision using multiple inputs in the profit maximizing firm, namely, multi-output production decision model.

(2)

systems. However, he recommended imposing input-output separability restriction to simplify the input alloca-tion and multi-output producalloca-tion decision models for estimaalloca-tion. This restricalloca-tion resulted in input allocaalloca-tion de-cision independent of the changes in output prices and multi-output production dede-cision independent of the changes in the input prices, which was counterproductive to the multiproduct firm theory.

Recently, [3] and [4] developed empirical models to estimate input allocation in the revenue maximizing and the cost minimizing firms, respectively. These empirical models linearized functional forms of the input alloca-tion models without having to impose the input-output separability and input independence restricalloca-tions. Addi-tionally, the authors suggested a statistical test, which checked whether imposing these restrictions was neces-sary. By using this linearization technique, we developed an empirical model for the multi-output production decision for the profit maximizing firm that combined both cost minimization and revenue maximization for a particular firm. We also proved homogeneity property for the individual input price parameter for each output.

[5] and [6] estimated output-supply model. However, no one to date had empirically estimated multi-output production decision model due to the complexities associated with the input price terms. This paper reformu-lated multi-output production decision model for the profit maximizing firm by using proper parameterization to linearize theoretical model’s functional form. This advancement allowed us develop multi-output production de-cision model that could easily be estimated empirically.

The empirical model suggested that multi-output production decision was a function of the Divisia output vo-lume index and the relative changes in the individual input and output prices. The model was derived in such a way that the theoretical adding-up conditions held for all parameters. The restrictions like homogeneity, symme-try, input-output separability and output independence cpuld be imposed and tested statistically.

The paper was organized in the following way: Section 2 developed the multi-output production decision model for profit maximizing firm. Section 3 linearized and reformulated the model empirically, and Section 4 concluded the paper.

2. Multi-Output Production Decision Model for Profit Maximizing Firm

Profit maximizing multiproduct firm implies the following multi-output production decision equation for the rth product [1] [2]

(

)

*

(

)

* *

ln ln ln

s s

r r r s rs

p W

g d z d Z d

P W

θ ψ θ  ′ 

= −  ′′

 

(1)

where gr= p zr r

rp zr r is the rth output’s share in revenue; zr is the quantity of the rth output; pr is the price of the rth output

(

r s, =1, 2,,m

)

; d

(

lnZ

)

=

rg dr

(

lnzr

)

is a Divisia output volume index;

(

)

*

(

)

ln r r ln r

d P′ =

θ d p is a Frisch output price index where pr is the price of the rth output;

(

ln s

)

s

(

ln

)

i i

i

d W′ =

θ d w and

(

ln

)

*

(

ln s

)

s

s

d W′′ =

θ d W′ are Frisch input price indexes where wi is the price of the ith input

(

i=1, 2,,n

)

. The coefficient θrs* is normalized output price coefficient and represents a pure substitution effect between the rth and sth products. Therefore, we define * *

rs θ  

Θ =   is an m × m symme-tric positive definite matrix,

∑ ∑

r sθrs* =

rθr*=1. In addition,

* i

r i i r

θ =

θ θ , θri = ∂

(

p zr r

) (

w qi i

)

is de- scribed as the rth product marginal revenue for the ith input. θis= ∂

(

w qi i

) (

p zs s

)

expresses the additional cost of the ith input used in the production relative to the additional dollar’s value of the sth output as a neces-sary condition for profit maximization. θi =

rθ θr* ir is such that

∑ ∑

i jθij =

iθi =1, where θij are normalized coefficients and r 1

i iθ =

[2].

Finally, the revenue-cost ratio is γ =R C where R=

rp zr r is the firm’s revenue, and C=

iw qi i is

the cost. The ψ* is the price elasticity of the supply and defined by

( )

1R p

(

2C

(

∂ ∂z z

)

)

−1p>0

. It also sa-tisfies ψ*≥ψ γ ψ

(

)

>0, where ψ is a measure of the curvature of the logarithmic cost function and can be found using

( )

2

(

2

(

)

)

1+ 1γ

∑ ∑

r s ∂ lnC ∂lnzr∂lnzs for output homogeneous production function [2]. By

(3)

Note that when the firm is input-output separable, the multi-output production decision model becomes inde-pendent of the input price changes. This restriction implies that the individual input price indexes are the same for each output. Hence, the Frisch input price indexes are equal to each other, d

(

lnWs

)

=d

(

lnW′′

)

=d

(

lnW

)

.

Therefore, the input prices disappear in the Equation (1). Further output independence restriction yields θrs* =0 for r s and θrs* =θr*>0 for r = s[2].

3. Multi-Output Production Decision Model

3.1. Linear Model

This section simplifies Equation (1) to a linear form. We can show Equation (1) as the three-term summation:

(

)

*

(

)

* * * *

ln ln ln s ln

r r r s rs s rs s

p W

g d z d Z d d

P W

θ ψ θ   ψ θ  ′′

= −

 

(2)

When we decompose output price terms into two terms using the above definition, −ψ*

sθrs*d

(

lnp Ps

)

can be written as

(

)

(

)

* * * * *

ln ln

rs s r s s

s d p s d p

ψ θ ψ θ θ

+

(3)

Collecting under output price term, the two terms can be written as

(

)

(

)

(

)

* * * * ln * ln

rs r s s rs s

s d p s d p

ψ θ θ θ π

− =

(4)

where π*rs can obey the adding-up condition,

*

0 rs rπ =

, the homogeneity condition,

sπrs* =0, and the symmetry restriction, π*rssr* ∀r s, .

Then, we rewrite the last term of Equation (2) as, −ψ*

sθrs*

(

d

(

lnW′′

)

d

(

lnWs

)

)

and substitute

(

ln

)

*

(

ln s

)

s s

d W′′ =

θ d W′ in this expression

(

)

(

)

* * * * *

ln s ln s

rs s rs

s s d W s d W

ψ θ θ ′ ψ θ ′

∑ ∑

+

(5)

By using

sθrs* =θr* and the former term of expression (5) simplifies to

(

)

* * * ln s

r s

s d W

ψ θ θ ′

, as shown in Appendix A. Next, we insert this term into expression (5), and by rearranging the terms, it yields

(

) (

)

* * * *

ln s

rs r s

s d W

ψ

θ −θ θ ′ (6)

We substitute

(

ln s

)

is

(

ln i

)

i

d W′ =

θ d w into the expression (6) and obtain

(

)

(

)

* * * * s ln

rs r s i i

s i d w

ψ

θ −θ θ

θ (7) By distributive property, we rewrite expression (7) as

(

)

(

)

* * * * *

ln ln

s s

rs i i r s i i

s i d w s i d w

ψ

∑ ∑

θ θ −ψ

θ θ

θ (8)

(

)

* *

ln s

rs i i

s i d w

ψ

∑ ∑

θ θ can be simplified to *

(

*

)

(

)

ln

s

rs i i

i s d w

ψ

∑ ∑

θ θ , as shown in Appendix A. Since

* s

s i i

sθ θ =θ

, we define

sθ θrs i* sri . We can then rewrite the first term of expression (8) as

(

)

*

ln

ri i

i d w

ψ

θ , where θir* represents the revenue gained by the firm from the additional production of the

rth product for ith input [3]. We can simplify * * * s

(

ln

)

r s i i

s i d w

ψ θ θ θ

by taking θr* outside of the sum and

*

s

θ inside of the sum; thus, we end up with −ψ θ* r*

∑ ∑

i sθ θs* isd

(

lnwi

)

. Using the definition

* s

s i i

sθ θ =θ

, we obtain −ψ θ* r*

iθid

(

lnwi

)

= −ψ*

iθ θr* id

(

lnwi

)

.

Substituting simplified terms into expression (8) yields

(

)

(

)

(

)

(

)

* * * * *

ln ln ln

ri i r i i ri r i i

i d w i d w i d w

(4)

Define

(

*

)

ri ri r i

π =ψ θ −θ θ and substitute expressions (4) and (9) into Equation (2). Thus, the linear form of the multi-output production decision equation becomes

(

)

*

(

)

*

(

)

(

)

ln ln ln ln

r r r s rs s i ri i

g d zd Z +

π d p +

π d w (10) The properties of the parameters are demonstrated in Appendix B. In summary, all parameters automatically hold the adding-up condition,

rθr*=1,

*

0 rs rπ =

, and

∑ ∑

r iπri =0. Next, one can impose homogeneity condition on price parameters,

sπrs* =0 and

iπri =0. The symmetry restriction only holds for output price parameters πrssrr s, . Homogeneity condition is proved as a property of parameter πri

al-though previous study by [4] could not confirm homogeneity condition for this parameter. It is worth noting that symmetry in the n × m matrix π =

[ ]

πri is not necessary to hold.

3.2. An Empirical Model

We parameterize Equation (10) by assuming θr*,

*

rs

π and πri are constants and add disturbance

*

r

ε for em-pirical estimation, where εr* is m-variate normal distribution with zero means [2]. Thus, the empirical model for multi-output production decision in a profit maximizing firm that uses multiple inputs is

* * *

rt r r t s rs st i ri it rt

g dzdZ +

π dp +

π dw +ε (11)

To estimate parameter, we calculate arithmetic means of output shares, grt =

(

gr t, +gr t,−1

)

2; log difference

of quantity and prices, dxt =lnxt −lnxt1 with x representing z, p and w; Divisia volume index,

t r rt rt

dZ =

g dz ; and include ε* ~N

( )

0,Σ .

The model naturally maintains the adding-up conditions. Symmetry conditions on π*

and homogeneity conditions on * *

rs π   =  

π and π are imposable. Log-likelihood-ratio tests (LRT) can test these restrictions. The covariance matrix, Σ, happens to be singular due to the adding-up conditions.

After dropping one equation we estimate the remaining m-1 equations simultaneously [7]. Maximum likelih-ood or iterative seemingly unrelated regression (SUR), which also iterates to maximum likelihlikelih-ood [8] [9], can estimate the parameters * *

r θ   =  

θ , π*

and π . By imposing input-output separability restriction we get

* * *

rt r r t s rs st rt

g dzdZ +

π dp +ε (12)

where input prices disappear from the linear form. Further output separability restriction simplifies Equation (12) to

* * * *

ln st

rt r r t r rt

t

p

g dz dZ d

P

θ ψ θ   ε

= −  +

  (13)

Both restrictions can be tested with an LRT.

4. Conclusions

This study makes it possible to empirically estimate the decision model that optimizes the production process with multiple inputs being used across multiple outputs. The model aligns with the dual approach of cost mini-mization and revenue maximini-mization for the profit maximizing multi-product firm while keeping jointness in production structurally intact.

We reformulate multi-output production decision model by using proper parameterization to linearize theo-retical model’s functional form. Homogeneity property for the individual input price parameter for each output is formally proven, which is never done before.

References

(5)

[2] Laitinen, K. (1980) A Theory of the Multiproduct Firm. In: Theil, H. and Glejser, H., Eds., Studies in Mathematical and Managerial Economics, North Holland, New York, 28.

[3] Seale Jr., J.L., Vorotnikova, E. and Asci, S. (2014) An Empirical Input Allocation Model for the Multiproduct Firm.

Economics Letters, 124, 367-369.http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2014.06.021

[4] Zhu, M., Onel, G. and Seale Jr., J.L. (2015) An Empirical Input Allocation Model for the Cost Minimizing Multipro-duct Firm. Economics Letters, 132, 73-76.http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2015.04.015

[5] Clements, K.W. (1980) An Aggregative Multiproduct Supply Model. European Economics Review, 13, 239-245. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0014-2921(80)90057-4

[6] Rossi, N. (1984) The Estimation of the Product Supply and Input Demand by the Differential Approach. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 66, 368-375.http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/1240804

[7] Barten, A.P. (1977) The Systems of Consumer Demand Functions Approach: A Review. Econometrica, 45, 23-50. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/1913286

[8] Harvey, A. (1990) The Econometric Analysis of Time Series. 2nd Edition, The MIT Press, Cambridge.

[9] Kmenta, J. and Gilbert, R.F. (1968) Small Sample Properties of Alternative Estimators of Seemingly Unrelated Re-gressions. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 63, 1180-1200.

(6)

Appendix A: Simplification of Summation Terms

The expression * * *

(

ln s

)

rs s

s s d W

ψ θ θ ′

∑ ∑

can be written as

(

) (

)

(

) (

)

(

)

(

)

* * * * 1 * * *

1 1 1

* * * 1 * *

1

ln ln

ln ln .

m

r rm m r rm

m

rs m rs

s s

d W d W

d W d W

ψ θ θ θ θ θ θ

ψ θ θ θ θ

 ′ ′  − + + + + + +  ′ ′  = −

+ +

   

Using

sθrs* =θr*, it simplifies to

(

)

* * *

ln s

r s

s d W

ψ θ θ ′

. In explicit form, ψ*

∑ ∑

sθrs* iθisd

(

lnwi

)

can be written as

(

)

(

)

(

)

(

(

)

(

)

)

* * 1 1 *

1 1 ln 1 ln 1 ln 1 ln

m m

r d w nd wn rm d w n d wn

ψ θ θ + + θ + + θ θ + + θ .

Further rearrangement and simplification, it yields

(

)

(

)

(

)

(

)

* * 1 * 2 * * 1 * 2 *

1 1 2 1 1 ln 1 1 2 ln

m m

r r rm d w r n r n rm n d wn

ψ θ θ +θ θ + + θ θ + + θ θ +θ θ + + θ θ ,

and we can write this simplified expression as *

(

*

)

(

)

ln

s

rs i i

i s d w

ψ θ θ

=

∑ ∑

.

Appendix B: Properties of Parameters

Define * *

(

* * *

)

rs rs r s

π = −ψ θ −θ θ . Sum πrs* over r , which leads to

(

)

* * * * * * * * * * * * * *

0

rs rs r s rs s r s s

rπ = −ψ r θ −θ θ = −ψ rθ +ψ θ rθ = −ψ θ +ψ θ =

and hence, *

rs

π obeys the adding-up condition. To show the homogeneity condition, sum *

rs

π over s

(

)

* * * * * * * * * * * * * * 0

rs rs r s rs r s r r

sπ = −ψ s θ −θ θ = −ψ sθ +ψ θ sθ = −ψ θ +ψ θ =

.

Lastly, symmetry holds for m × m matrix, where πrs* =π*srr s, .

Define θri =

sθ θrs i* s . Sum θri over both i and r to show it as a normalized input price parameter. Using [2]

definition

sθ θs* isi, we find

(

*

)

(

*

)

*

1

s s s

ri rs i rs i s i i

i rθ = i r sθ θ = i s rθ θ = i sθ θ = iθ =

∑ ∑

∑ ∑ ∑

∑ ∑ ∑

∑ ∑

.

Individually summing over r and i, respectively, yields

(

* s

)

(

*

)

s * s

ri rs i rs i s i i

rθ = r sθ θ = s rθ θ = sθ θ =θ

∑ ∑

∑ ∑

and

(

* s

)

(

s

)

* * *

ri rs i i rs rs r

iθ = i s θ θ = s iθ θ = sθ =θ

∑ ∑

∑ ∑

for the parameter with m × n dimension. Define

(

*

)

ri ri r i

π =ψ θ −θ θ . Sum πrs* over r which leads to

(

*

)

* 0

ri ri r i ri i r i i

rπ =ψ r θ −θ θ =ψ rθ −ψθ rθ =ψθ ψθ− =

and hence, πri obeys the adding-up condition. To show the homogeneity condition, sum πri over i

(

)

(

)

(

)

* * * * * * * 0. i

ri ri r i ri r i r i r i

i i i i i i

i i

r i i r i i r i i r r r

π ψ θ θ θ ψ θ ψ θ θ ψθ ψ θ θ θ

ψθ ψ θ θ θ ψθ ψ θ θ ψθ ψθ

= − = − = −

= − = − = − =

∑ ∑

References

Related documents

Thus, the profit-maximizing firm will hire the amount of labor associated with the intersection of its marginal revenue product of labor curve and its horizontal labor supply

Feeding entire male pigs with chicory root for 16 days increased the CYP1A2 and CYP2A dependent activity.. More- over, we showed that the protein and mRNA expression of CYP1A2 and

The relationship among price elasticity, demand, and total revenue has an important implication for the selection of the profit-maximizing price and output: A monopoly firm will

Theaverage and profits on policies to maximizing firm equilibria, in a deeper understanding how much higher at the profit maximization is.. Do countries rely on policies to

• Human ear very sensitive to short term variations Î Need to playout voice as close as possible to sampled voice • Buffer absorbs variation in network queuing delays • BUT.. adds

– No scripts: Exploratory Testing – Record test findings as you go... Testing is about

ESTACIONES - PRIMAVERA PORTENA - VERANO PORTENO - OTONO PORTENO - INVIERNO PORTENO Pf TONOS 20005 EXTASIS Pf EMBA - EXTASIS.. (- LA MAJA

In support of strengthening student academic achievement, each school that receives Title I, Part A funds must develop jointly with, agree on with, and distribute to =, parents