• No results found

Capital Inflows and Real Exchange Rate Appreciation in Latin America

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2020

Share "Capital Inflows and Real Exchange Rate Appreciation in Latin America"

Copied!
67
0
0

Loading.... (view fulltext now)

Full text

(1)

Munich Personal RePEc Archive

Capital Inflows and Real Exchange Rate

Appreciation in Latin America

Reinhart, Carmen and Calvo, Guillermo and Leiderman,

Leonardo

University of Maryland, College Park, Department of Economics

1992

Online at

https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/13843/

(2)

IhZF WORKING PAPER

Q 1992 International Monekary Fund

This is a Working Papwand the author would welcome any comments on the present texL C ~ ~ t i o n s should refer to a Wwhng Paper or the International Monetary Fund, men- tioning the auhor, and rhe date of issuance. The views expressed me those of the author and do nor necessarily

rcprrsent those of the Fund.

INTERNATIONAL

MONETARY

FUND

Research Department

Capital Inflows and Real Exchange Rate Appreciation

L/

Prepared by Guillermo A . Calvo, Leonarda Leiderrnan 2J, and Carmen M. Reinhaxt

August, 1992

Abstract

The characteristfcs of recent c a p i t a l inflows into Latin America

are discussed. It is argued that these inflows are partly explained

by

conditions outside the region, like recession in the U n i t e d States and

lower international interest rates.

This

suggests

the

possibility

that

a reversal of those conditions

may

lead to a future c a p i t a l outflow,

fncreasing t h e macroeconomic vulnerability

of

Latin

American

economies.

Policy options are argued to be lfmited.

JEL Classification Numbers :

GI, F41

1J

An

earlier version of t h i s paper was presented at seminars at

the

~ o r l d Bank and Inter-American Development Bank,

The

authors w i s h to thank the p a r t i c i p a n t s at these seminars, numerous colleagues and, in

particular,

K.

Bruno, S. Calvo,

P.

Clark,

E.

Fernandez-~rias and

M.

Kiguel for their helpful suggestions.

2/

Mr.

Leiderrnan is on leave From t h e Department of Economics at

-

(3)

-

ii

-

Table of Contents

Summary

I.

Introduction

11. The Accounting of C a p i t a l Flows

1x1. Stylized Facts

1 . Anatomy o f c a p i t a l inflows

2 . Real exchange rate appreciation 3 . Rates of return differentials

4 . Other macroeconomic developments 5 . Previous episodes of c a p i t a l inflows

6. External factors

IV.

Role

of

External Factors: Econometric Analysis

1. Camovement of reserves and the real exchange rate 2 . Quantifying the role of external factors

V .

Policy

Implications

References

Text Tables

Charts

Latin America: Balance of Payments,

1973-91

Latin

America: Items

in

the Capital Account

Latin America: Macroeconomic Indicators

U . S . Balance

of

Payments

Changes in Capital Accounts

Establishing

the

Gomovement

in

Macroeconomic Series

Contemporaneous Correlations of the Regional Variables w i t h Selected

U. S

.

Indicators

Causality Tests

Tests f o r the Significance

of

the Foreign Factors

Decomposition

of

Variance: Real Exchange Rate

Decomposition

of

Variance: O f f i c i a l Reserves

1. Secondary Harket Prices f o r Loans

2 . T o t a l Reserves Minus

Gold

3 , Real Effective Exchange Rate

4 . Stock Market Performance 5 . Interest Rate Spreads

6.

Risk

and Returns

7 . First Principal Components

(4)

Charts

8 . The

External Variables

2

6a

9 . Response

of

O f f i c i a l Reserves to a One-Standard Deviation

Shock

in

the First Foreign Factor 30a

10.

Response

of

the

R e a l Exchange Rate to a One-Standard

Deviation in the First Foreign Factor 30b

(5)

During the p a s t t w o years, Latin America has received s i z a b l e i n t e r -

national c a p i t a l flows, amounting to $24 billion in 1990 and $40 billion

in 1991. In most cases, they have been accompanied by a marked accumulation

in international reserves, significant appreciations in real exchange rates, booming stock markets, faster economic growth, and wider current account

deficits. Although the restoration o f voluntary a c c e s s to international capital markets a f t e r nearly a decade

has

been heralded as a positive

development, the resurgence in c a p i t a l i n f l o w s has a l s o been a source of concern to polccymakers in the region, who f e a r , in p a r t i c u l a r ,

that

the

accompanying real exchange rate a p p r e c i a t i o n w i l l adversely a f f e c t the export sector. In addition, g i v e n that the previous c a p i t a l inflow e p i s o d e was f o l l o w e d

by

t h e debt c r i s i s of the 1980s, t h e r e are fears that some of

the capital k n f l o w s are of the " h o t money" variety. These highly specula-

tive flows could be reversed on s h o r t notice and, p o s s i b l y , spark a domestic

financial

crisis.

This paper focuses on t w o a s p e c t s of the present c a p i t a l inflow

phenomenon. F i r s t ,

in

an e f f o r t to determine h o w vulnerable these economies

are to an unexpected reversal in c a p i t a l flows, it a s s e s s e s quantitatively

to what extent the recent increase i s due t o external forces. Second, k t

discusses the form and timing o f the a p p r o p r i a t e policy r e s p o n s e , examining t h e pros and cons of a menu of p o l i c y measures, including t a x e s o n c a p i t a l imports, trade policy, f i s c a l tightening, central bank sterilized and

nonsterilized intervention, and banking regulations.

The empirical analysis indicates that capital is returning to mast L a t i n Amerfcan countries despite considerable differences in domestic p o l i c i e s and macroeconomic conditions. External f a r c e s , particularly

developments in t h e United S t a t e s , have played an i m p o r t a n t role i n

inducing capftal flaws i n t o Latin America. The sharp decline in U.S.

interest rates, the continuing recesslon, and capital account developments

in the United States have encouraged a p o r t f o l i o s h i f t toward L a t i n American

assets. The policy analysis suggests t h a t , although e x t e r n a l factors be reversed in t h e future, it is dkfficult to advocate sterilized intervention, given t h e fiscal burdens it entails, unless countries a d o p t a strong fiscal

stance and c a p i t a l inflows are expected t o be short-lived. A more cornpre-

hensive

policy intervention m i x , including r a i s i n g marginal reserve

requirements on short-term bank d e p o s i t , imposing t a x e s on short-term c a p i t a l imports, or a combination

of

these measures, are v i a b l e p o l i c y

(6)

I.

Introduction

The revival of substantial intexnational c a p i t a l inflows to Latin

America Is perhaps t h e most notable and v i s i b l e change

in

the economic

situation of the regian during the l a s t two years.

While

capltal i n f l o w s to Latin America averaged about $ 8

billion

a year in

the

second

h a l f

of the

1980s,

they

surged to $24 b i l l i o n

in

1990

and to $40

billfon

by

1991.

Of

t h e latter amount, 45 percent went to

Mexico,

and most of the remainder went:

to Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, and Venezuela. Interestingly, capftal fs returning to most L a t i n American countrfes despite the wide

differences

in

macroeconomic policies and economic performance between them.

In

mast countries, the increased c a p i t a l inflows are accompanied

by

en

appreciation in the real exchange r a t e , booming stock and seal e s t a t e

markets, faster economic growth, an accumulation of international reserves,

and a strong recovery of secondary market prices for foreign loans.

Without doubt, an important part of t h i s phenomenon is explained

by

the fundamental economic and political refarms which have recently taken p l a c e in a nuaber of these countries, including t h e restructuring of their

external debts. Indeed, it would have been difficult to attract foreign

c a p i t a l

in

the magnitudes mentioned above w i t h o u t these reforms.

Nevertheless, while domestic reform is a necessary

ingredient

f o r c a p i t a l

inflows,

it

only

p a r t i a l l y explains L a t i n America's forceful

reentry

in

international capital markets. For instance, domestic reforms alone cannot

explain

why

c a p i t a l inflows have occurred

in

countries t h a t had n o t

undertaken substantial reforms or why they d i d n o t occur, until only

recently, in countries where reforms where introduced

well

before 1990.

In

order f o r domestic reforms to

explain

t h e observed comovement a £ c a p i t a l

inflows across countries in the region, one would have to posit the

existence of strong reputatfonal externalities (or "contagion" e f f e c t s ) , where reforms

in

some of t h e countries give rise to expectations of future

reforms in other countries in the region.

T h i s

paper maintains t h a t some of the renewal of capital inflows to

Latin America is due to external factors, and can be considered as

an

external shock common to

the

region.

We

argue that f a l l i n g interest rates,

a continuing recession, and balance of payments developments

in

the

United

S t a t e s , along

with

developments

in

other industrialized countries,

have

encouraged investors to s h i f t t h e i r resources to

Latin

America t o take

advantage of

renewed

investment opportunities and the increased solvency

in

t h a t region.

J

I

Taking i n t o account economic developments outside the

regian helps to explain t h e universality

of

these inflows.

From a

historical perspective

then,

the present e p i s o d e

may

w e l l

be an

additional

L a t i n America is n o t the o n l y region

that

has experienced increased

c a p i t a l i n f l o w s in 1991. In fact, similar developments have occurred

in

(7)

case of

financial shocks in

the Center that a f f e c t the

Periphery, of

the

type stressed by Diaz Alejandro

in

several

of

h i s contributions.

I

J

International c a p f t a l

inflows

affect the b t i n American economies in at least

four dimensions.

2J First, they increase the availability

of

c a p i t a l

in

the

indiv2dual economies. As debt

and

equity capital become more

mobile

and accessible, domestic agents can better smooth o u t their

consumption over t i r u e and investors can more promptly react to changes in

expected

profitability.

Second, capital inflows have been associated with a marked appreciation

of

the real exchange rate in m o s t of the sample

countries. The

larger

transfer from abroad has to be accompanied

by an

increase

in

domestic absorption. Assuming normality of t r a d a b l e and

nontradable goods, at the initial real exchange rate domestic residents plan

to spend part

of

the

transfer i n terms of t r a d a b l e goods. This cannot

be an

equilibrium outcome because foreign transfers must,

by

definition, be s p e n t

entirely

on tradable goods. Therefore, the real exchange sate

has

to appreciate

in

order to induce a s h i f t away from nontradable and into tradable goods.

Third,

c a p i t a l fnflawa impose their own burdens and challenges

on

domestgc

policymaking.

The

desfre by some central banks to attenuate t h e

degree

of

real exchange rate appreciation in the short run frequently leads

them

to actively intervene and purchase from the private sector part

of

the inward flow of f o r e i g n exchange. Moreover, the attempt t o avoid domestic monetfzatfon of these purchases has o f t e n l e d the monetary authorities t o

s t e r i l i z e

some

of

the

inflows, which tends

to perpetuate a

high

dornestic/foreign interest rate

differential,

and

gives

rise to increased f i s c a l burdens.

The

exrent

to

which

the

inflows

are

sustainable

is also o f

concern

to

the

authorities. The

history

of Latin America gives

reason

for

such concern:

the

major episodes

of

c a p i t a l

inflows, during the 1920s

and

1978-81,

were followed

by

major

economic crises and c a p i t a l outflows,

such

as in t h e

1930s and

the

debt crisis

In

the mid-1980s.

Fourth,

c a p i t a l inflows can provide important--yet ambiguous--signals to participants fn world financial markets. On the one hand, an increase in

the

inflows

can be interpreted as reflecting more

favorable

medium- and

long-term

investment opportunities in the receiving

country.

Yet,

on

the

other

hand,

c a p i t a l may pour

in

for purely short-term speculative purposes

to a country where lack of credibility

of

government policies leads t o

high

nominal

returns on domestic f i n a n c i a l a s s e t s .

In

f a c t , there have been several such episodes

in

Latin

America, where

lack

of

credibility and a

short- term

financial

bubble were assocf ated

with large

inflows

of

%ot

money"

from

abroad.

While

it remains to

be

seen

which

one

of

these t w o

scenarios best fits the present episode, she

strong recovery in

secondary

market prices

of

bank

claims on

several

of zhese

countries (Chart 1) end

See e

.

g.

Diaz

A l e jandro

(1983,

1984)

.

2

J For a recent study of the e f f e c t s of c a p i t a l movements, s e e

(8)

C h a r t

1 .

SECONDARY MARKET

PRICES

FOR

LOANS

{In percent of face value)

A R G E N T I N A B O L I V I A

C O L O M B l A

r-

- 7 1

0 76 U R U G U A Y -- --

0 > A

-

0 7 ? J

0.7

4

- -

( I b l .

0 6 6 I I

-

- -

A n #O *I1 US An m4 )ul 0 9 Jan Ba A+- Jan-41 Jurl-Yi An-12

o * . 0 4 D

-

0 1 0 7 3 '

0 7 - o a s - n a -

o w -

on.. E C U A D O R

P E R U

O 4 1

0 0s

i

---,-..,--- ,

--A+. .+ ---+.-. .

.-.

- .-..

. --,---

1

a n 18 Ad I a Jln a * A* a* J=rl M Jd P) A n 9t hl P I Jar, 97

(9)
(10)

various

other

indicators of country

risk

provide

at least p a r t i a l

signals in

support of the first,

more

favorable,

scenario.

7211s paper has three main objectives

which

are developed based on data

for ten

Latin

American countries. 2J The f i r s t is t o document the current

episode of capttal inflows to Latin Amer%ca and to compare it t o

earlier

such episodes. The second is to quantitatively assess the role of external

factors

in

accounting f o r the observed c a p i t a l

inflows

and the real exchange rate appreciation. The t h i r d is to elaborate

on

the implications

of

capital

inflows for economic policy

in Latin

American countries. The paper is

organized as follows. Sectton I1 deals,

with

the basic concepts and the

relationship between c a p i t a l inflows, the accumulation of reserves, and the

gap between national saving and investment. The stylized facts about

capital

inflows

to the r e g i o n are documented in Section 111,

which

includes

a comparison w i t h previous e p i s o d e s . S e c t i o n I V provides a quantitative

assessment of t h e role of external factors an the accumulation

of

reserves

and

on

the real exchange rate appreciation

in the

ten countries considered.

The implications of c a p i t a l i n f l o w s for domestic economic policy are discussed

in

Section V .

11. The Accountinn of C a w i t a l Flows

International c a p i t a l flows are recorded

in

the non-reserve capital account of the balance of payments.

This

account includes all international transactions w i t h a s s e t s o t h e r than o f f i c i a l reserves, such as transactions

in

money, stocks, government bonds, land, factories, and so

an.

When a

n a t i o n a l agent sells en asset to someone abroad, the transaction enters h f s

country's balance of payments as a credit: on the c a p i t a l account and is

regarded as a capital inflow. Accordingly, net borrowing abroad by domestlc

agents ar a purchase of domestic stocks

by

foreigners are considered as capital inflows, whlch respectively represent debt and equity

finance.

The

methodology of the International Monetary

Fund

breaks down c a p i t a l

flows

into three main categories: f o r e i g n direct investment, p o r t f o l i o

investment, and other capital.

The

simple

rules

of double-entry accounting ensure that, up to

statistical discrepancies, the capital account surplus

or

n e t capital

inflow

(denoted by KA)

Is

related to the c u r r e n t account surplus (denoted

by

CA)

and to the official reserves account (denoted by RA) of the balance of

payments through the identity:

1/

For tracing

on

the evolution

over

time

of individual

country

ratings

-

see, for instance, LDC Debt R e ~ o r t

by

Salmon Brothers.

The

countries included

in our

sample are:

Argentina, Bolivia,

B r a z f l ,

C h i l e , Colombia, Ecuador, Mexico, Peru, Uruguay, and Venezuela.

(11)

A n important property of the

current

account is

that

it measures the change

in

the

economy's net foreign wealth. A country that runs a current account

d e f i c i t must finance

t h i s

d e f l c i t either

by

a private c a p i t a l inflow or by a reduction

in

its o f f t c i a l reserves. In both cases the country is running

down i t s net foreign wealth. Another important characteristic of the

current account is that national income accounting implies that its surplus

is

equal to the difference between national saving and national investment ( t h a t is, CA = S-I). Accordingly, an increase in the

current

account d e f i c i t can be traced to either

an

increase

in

national investment, a decline

in

national savings, or any combination of these variables t h a t results in an increased investrnent/savings gap. FSnally, the o f f i c i a l xeserves account records purchases or sales of o f f i c i a l reserve a s s e t s

by

central banks. Thus, t h i s account measures

the

extent

of

official foreign

exchange intervention by the authorities, and is often referred to as the

o f f i c i a l settlements balance

or

t h e overall balance

of

payments (see

footnote 3

an

page 3 ) .

The foregoing discussion i n d i c a t e s that there are t w o polar cases

of

central bank intervention under increased capital inflows. In a no-

intervention scenario, the increased n e t exports of a s s e t s in the c a p i t a l account are financing an increase in net imports of goods and services. Under these circumstances, c a p i t a l inflows would

not

be associated w i t h

changes

in

central banks' holdings of o f f i c i a l reserves. A t the other

extreme is s scenario in which the domestic authorities actively intervene

and purchase

the foreign

exchange brought

in

by

t h e capital inflow. Thus,

the increase in

KA

is matched, one-to-one, by an increase

in official

reserves {recorded as a reduction

in

RA). In this case, there is

no

change

in the gap between national saving

and

national investment, n o r is there any change

in

the

net foreign wealth of the

economy. That

is, the c a p i t a l

inflow would then be

perfectly correlated

w i t h

changes

in

o f f i c i a l reserves.

In

r e a l i t y ,

we

observe fareign exchange market intervention b u t not on a scale that

would

produce a one-to-one relationship between reserves

accumulation and capital i n f l o w . Put d i f f e r e n t l y , the observed increase in

capital Inflows to Latin America is

partly

matched

by

an increase in the region's current account d e f i c i t and

by an

increase

in

central banks' o f f i c i a l reserves. The pertinent data are discussed

In

the next section.

111. Stvlized Facts

In

this

section we quantify some of the key aspects of the current

e p i s o d e

of

c a p i t a l inflows to

Latin

America and t h e related

underlying

macroeconomic developments.

l

J

To document the regional aspects of

See a l s o Financial T i m e s (1992), Kuczynski (19921, and Salornon

(12)

t h i s phenomenon we aggregate

annual

data and focus on Latin America as a

whole.

a/

Monthly data f o r

individual

countries provide greater d e t a i l and are also discussed here and

in

the

sectton that follows.

The

current

developments are then compared with previous episodes of c a p i t a l inflow.

L a s t , we elaborate

on

the

role of external developments, especially those

in

the United S t a t e s .

1.

Anatomv of c a p i t a l inflows

Table 1 presents a breakdown

of

L a t i n America's balance of payments i n t o its three main accounts. The capital inflows under consideration

appear in the form of surpluses

in

the c a p $ t a l account, of about

$24

billion in 1990 and about

$40

billion in 1991. It can be seen

that

a substantial

fraction o f the inflows have been channelled to foreign exchange reserves,

which increased by about $ 3 3 billion in 1990-91. About 63 p e r c e n t of the i n f l o w in 1990 was matched

by

an increase in official reserves, leaving the remaining 37 percent to finance the deficit in the current account. Y e t , the latter increased markedly in 1991, accounting f o x 55 percent of the c a p i t a l

inflow.

considering 1990-91 as a whole, the net c a p i t a l inflow was

equally split into a widening in the current account d e f i c i t (a reduction in CA) and an increase in o f f i c i a l reserves (a reduction tn R A ) . The former suggests that c a p i t a l inflows have been assoctated with

an

increase in the gap between national investment and national saving. In countries like Chile and Mexico,

an

important part of the i n f l o w s has financed increases

in

private investment; y e t , in countries like Argentina and Brazil there has been a marked rise

in

private consumption.

2/

The increase

in

o f f i c i a l

reserves, in turn, indicates that the capital inflow was met with a rather

heavy degree of f o r e i g n exchange market Lntervention by the various monetary

authorities.

Part

of

t h e increased c a p i t a l inflows represent repatriation

of

previous flight capital (whose s t o c k abroad Is estimated at about

$200

b i l l i o n at the end

of

the

1980s).

3

J

But, there also are new investors

in

Latin America. Table 2 reports various items fn the c a p i t a l account of Latin America. Notice t h a t quantitatively the most important item is the increase

in

net external borrowing, which accounts f o r 70 percent

of

the

capital inflow in 1990-91, and which is primarily borrowing by the p r i v a t e

For the purposes of the present section, Latin America includes the

same s e t of countries included under Western Hemisphere in

IMF's

World

Economic Outlook and

International

Financial

S t a t i s t i c s . 2

J These figures, which are available

from

the authors, express

investment and consumption as shares of GDP and

rely

on

preliminary national

income accounts data f o r

1991.

(13)
(14)

Table

2.

Latin

America:

Items

in

the

Capital

Account

(In biljims

of

U.S.

doltars)

Net external Nm-debt Asset

tranmions

Errors and

Year borrowing creating flows (net) I / ommissions 1 f Total

1973 6.0 2.5

--

--

8.5

1974 11.7 2.2

--

--

13.3

1975

11.4

3.3

--

--

14.7

1976 14.2 2.7

--

--

16.9

1977

19.4

2.8 -2,5 -3.4 16,4

1 978

28.0

4.9 -2.5 -3.1 27.4

1 979 30.2 7.2 -2.4 -2.1 32.9

1980 43.1 6.8 -3.0

-

13.0 34.0

1981 61 -0 8.2 -8.9

-

17.5 41.9

1982 45.7 7.2 -7.7 -22.1 23.0

1983 18.7 4.6 -10.9 -8.8 13.6

1984 14.1 4.5 -3.1 -3.0 12.5

1985 6.2 6.1 -5.4 -1.4 5.5

1986 11.3 4.3 -1.3 -1.9 12.3

1987 10.0 6.0 -1.2 0,s 15.3

1988 3,8 8.8 -4.3 -3.5 4.7

1989 10.9 6.9 -2.1 -3.6 12.1

1990 28.0 8.6

-

12.5 -0.2 23.9

1991 f

7.3

14.9 6.7 1.7 39.8

Swrce: Data for western hemisphere, World Ecmomc Outlook, IMF, various

issues.

11 These two categories

are

included in

net

external

borrowing and mn-debt creating flows from

[image:14.612.71.519.156.485.2]
(15)

sector from foreign private banks.

U

Increased external borrowing

reflects the restoration of access to voluntary c a p i t a l market flnancfng

after the debt crisis--a restoratfon that follows a period of s i x years

during which voluntary Loan and bond financing flows to Latin America were severely limited. 2J

In

addition to greater domestic borrowing abroad,

there were increases

in

p o r t f o l i o knvestment and foreign direct investment. The latter amounted to about $12 billion, $4 b i l l i o n of which was the result of privatizations.

Since there has been a substantial degree of central bank intervention

in the face of capital inflows, there is an important degree of comovement

between o f f i c i a l reserves and capftal inflows.

In

fact,

if

one is

interested

in

monthly developments, for which direct data on capital inflows are n o t available, changes fn reserves are a reasanable proxy f o r these

inflows,

Chart

2,

which

d e p i c t s

monthly

data on o f f i c i a l international

reserves for the countries in our sample, shows t h a t for most of the countries, there is a pronounced upward trend

in

the stock of official

reserves starting from about the first half

of

1990. In 1991, the year w i t h

the hfghest c a p i t a l inflows to the region, reserves accumulation accelerated as

the

monetary authoritkes

in

most countries reacted to the c a p i t a l inflows

by

actively increasing t h e i r purchases of foreign assets constituting

international reserves. Brazil and Uruguay are exceptions to t h i s pattern,

as in both countries, capital inflows w e r e not accompanied by an increase In

reserves.

2. Real e x c h a n ~ e rate a t e

Chart

3 provides evidence on

the

behavior

of

the real effective exchange rates. 3J A t least t w o regularities emerge from t h i s

figure:

( I )

with t h e exception

of

Brazil, a l l countries are experiencing a real

exchange rate appreciation since January of 1991. In h a l f of

the

cases the real appreciation a £ the domestic currency began before January

1991;

and ( 2 ) even w5thin a small sample of monthly observations covering four years,

there

is considerable evidence a£ cyclical behavior

of real

exchange rates.

Leading examples of this phenomenon are Brazil,

Chile,

and Uruguay.

While

some of these cycles can be attributed to fluctuations

in

capital inflows, they are also the r e s u l t of other shacks such as fluctuations in the terms

of

trade and

in

domestic monetary, f i s c a l , and exchange rate policies.

Combining the evidence from Charts 2 and 3 indicates t h a t there

is an

important degree of comovement in these variables across countries, desptte the

wide

differences in policies

and

institutions among them.

We

v i e w t h i s comovement as compatible w i t h the notion t h a t

there

is a common shock t h a t

Same

of

t h i s increased borrowing

may

represent hidden repatriation

of

flight c a p i t a l ,

2

J See, for instance, El-Erian

(1992)

and International Monetary Fund

(December 1991. Chapter 111).

(16)

Chart

2.

TOTAL

RESERVES

MINUS GOLD

Billions of U.S. dollars

BRAZIL

"

7

7

0 1 ) , BOLIVIA

Y O , CHILE 1

ECUADOR

1 , --I

09 3

on -

o r -

RE

-

as -

IU

-

O J -

0 2 4 h-

vy

m

.

h M

.

MID

.

h m

.

Urn

.

h 9 1

.

U U

.

h a p

.

VENEZUELA

(17)
(18)

Chart

3.

REAL

EFFECTIVE EXCHANGE

RATE

4 0 BRAZIL

4 0 4 7

I S

4 0

4. 4 1

- Y a s - Y a h o c r & m . h O l d a i

URUGUAY

'.

7

-*-IYI - CHILE

4- '

4 a -

4 M - 4m

-

* w -

ECUADOR *m

am

a w

3 M

a-

*&?

1 8

am

*'M

-

a74 '

a n

-

3 1 - am

-

383

-

3 w .

3- 4

> a . . . . . . .. . .

Source: Information Notice System, IMF.

(19)
(20)

a f f e c t e d the whole region and resulted

i n

increased c a p i t a l

inflows

and real

exchange rate appreciation.

3. Rates

of

return d i f f e r e n t i a l s

Expected rates of return en available assets across cauntrfes

play

a

key

role

in

investors' decisfons

on

whether

or

not to move capttal

internationally. Since data

for

expected returns are not

read5ly available,

and depend on how one models expectations, we first look at the stylized

facts in

the

farm of e x post returns ( s e e Charts 4 and 5).

As shown in Chart 4 ,

there

was a large increase

in

the

U.S. d o l l a r

stock prices of major Latin American markets i n 1991. Argentina exhibits

the biggest s i n g l e annual return of almost 400 percent, while Chfle and

Mexico registered returns of about 100 percent each.

l

J

According to the

"emerging markets" data from IFC, investments

in

Latin American securities

y i e l d e d total returns of

134

percent in dollar terms

in

1991.

,These

s t o c k

market booms are associated w i t h increased

purchases by

Latin American

investors as well as by foreigners. The marked increases

in

s t o c k market

prices have resulted in skmflar rises %n the prices of country and regional

market funds traded in the United States and elsewhere. Along w i t h these price developments, there has been a maxked x i s e

in

market capitalization

of

Latin American equity markets

in 1991.

Overall market capitalization in

Argentina rose from $ 3 . 3 b i l l i o n

in

1990 to $18.5

billion

i n

1991; in

Brazil

it rose from $16.4 billion in 1990 to $ 4 2 . 8 billion in 1991;

in

Chile from

$13.7 billion

in 1990 to $28 billion

in

1991; and

in

Mexico it rose from

$ 3 2 . 7 b i l l t o n in 1990 to $101.2 billion in 1991. 2J According to Salomon Brothers, $850 b i l l i o n of f o r e i g n investment entered

Brazil's

stock market

in

t h e last four months of 1991, and about

$600 million

was invested by foreigners in t h e Argentine

equity

market

in 1991.

3

J

However, as the

figures indicate and Chart 4 confirms, the s t a c k market booms and the

attendant

high

returns appear to materialize after c a p i t a l

has

begun to

flow

in

to the region. It would

thus

be

d i f f i c u l t to argue that high stock

market return differentials

were

responsible for a t t r a c t i n g the f i r s t

wave

of c a p i t a l i n f l o w s .

Chart 5 provides evidence on the

lending

and deposit interest rate

spreads between U.S.

dollar

equivalent domestic i n t e r e s t rates and interest

rates in the United S t a t e s . Since kn some

of

these countries interest rates

are regulated, and since c a p i t a l m o b i l i t y

is

f a r

from free,

spreads across

the various countries cannot be compared in a straightforward manner. In

The price/earnings ratio

in

Argentina increased

from 3.1 in 1990:IV

to

3 8 . 9 in

1991:IV;

in Chile

it increased

from

8 . 9

in 1990:IV

to

17.4

in

1991:IV; and in Mexico it moved from 1 3 . 2 in 1990:IV to 14.6 In 1991:IV.

These figures are from Emerging Markets Data Base, International Finance

Corporation.

2

J These figures are

from

P

g

,

Fourth Quarter 1991, International Finance Corporation.

(21)

addition, as Chart 6 h i g h l i g h t s , the

variability

in domestic i n t e r e s t rates

varies markedly across countries.

To

accommodate t h i s feature

the

scales in

Chart

4

vary from country to

country,

wkth Argentina and

Peru

having

the

broadest ranges and Bolivia and Colombia the narrowest. With these caveats

in

mind, the dominant impression

from

Chart 5 i s that of

relatively

high

interest d i f f e r e n t i a l s in L a t i n America in the 1990-91 p e r i o d . It is also evident

from

Chart 5 t h a t the pattern of spreads varies considerably across

countries.

In

e f f e c t , t h i s is n o t surprising since the monetary authorities

in

these countries have n o t reacted

in

a uniform manner to the capital

inflows and

the

timing

of

regulatory changes has also varied considerably

across the countries considered.

While

the

relatively

high

differential rate of return on L a t h American

a s s e t s has been associated w i t h a marked rise

in

c a p i t a l inflows to the region,

the

inflows have not arbitraged away

the

large differentials. In

some countries, such as Argentina, the interest rate differential decreased

sharply as capital poured in; yet in others, such as Chile, there was a less

pronounced response of t h e interest rate differential to the

inflows

(see

Chart 5). As argued

in

Section

V ,

these different patterns may r e f l e c t

cross-country differences

in

the authorities' choices between s t e r i l i z e d and

nonstexilized intervention. In any case, it should

be

stressed that some of

the relatively

high

observed differentials may be due to the f a c t that they

are measured here ex post, as opposed to ex ante which is the one that is relevant for investor's decisions. I n particular, as in a "Peso problem," s i z a b l e discrepancies between ex ante and ex post returns could

be

accounted

for by the fact that investors assigned a non-negligible

probability

that

Latin American reforms could collapse, that capital controls could

be

re-

imposed, that there could be large devaluations against the dollar,

or

that

interest rates in t h e United States could sharply rise.

Y e t , even

if

there were d i r e c t data on expected, or ex ante, rates of

return differentials, we suspect t h a t these c o u l d

well

show substantial

persistence

over

time due to the existence

of

financial and

exchange

rate

risk. In fact, Chart 6 illustrates for both debt and equity instruments how

in

countries t h a t provided h i g h ex p a s t returns one also observes a

relatively

high variance of these returns. In addition, differentials may

persist due to high transactions costs and information costs

I/,

c a p i t a l

controls, and country transfer (or political) risk. However, whether the

observed differentials reflect these fundamental factors or are due ta a

financial

bubble is y e t to be determined.

In

sum, three main s t y l i z e d f a c t s

emerge

with regard to i n t e r e s t rate

differentials. F i r s t , there is little comovement in domestic i n t e r e s t rates

-

I/

Some

of

the factors

that

make f t d i f f i c u l t f o r foreign investors to

-

invest in several Latin American markets are: the lack of full financial

information about various traded companies, the absence

of

a comprehensive

s e t

of

insider trading regulations and of strict

broker

requirements in some

cases, and the difficulties

in

dealing with standard accounting practices

(22)

C h a r t

4.

S T O C K

M A R K E T P E R F O R M A N C E

(Stock Price

Indices In

U.S.

Dollars, January 1988= 100)

P!ote T h c S 8 P 5 0 0 ~ n d e l r w a s u s e d t o r t h c U n ~ t e d S t a t e s

S o u r c e s : S t a n d a r d E P o o r ' s a n d I n t c r n a l n o n a l f ~ n a n c c C o r p o r a t i o n . O u a r f c r l y R e v i e w o f

(23)
(24)

Chart

5.

INTEREST

RATE SPREADS

(DaHsr Equivalent d Domestic Rate less U.S. Rate. Annual Rates)

BRAZIL

-

:

U R U G U A Y

,,

,-

-

-

- .- - - . . . - - 1

1m. CHILE

E C U A D O R

I

1

I

any urn CIW MU CI# urn b m u r m m

P E R U

Lsrxkops-

\

m V E N E Z U E L A

S o u r c e : International Financial S t a t i s t i c s a n d v a r i o u s C e n i r a l Bank bulletins.

(25)
(26)

C h a r t

6 .

R I S K

A N D R E T U R N S

Credit

Markets:

Lending

Rates of

intersst

A v e r a g e M o n t h l y R e t u r n i n U . S . D o l l a r s

0 . 0 4 0

Argentina

-

-

a U r u g u a y

-

-

a M e x i c o Paru a

Q Chile

Bolivia Braxil

-

-=u;S~a\arn bia V e n e z u e l a

-

E c u a d o r

e

S t a n d a r d D e v i a t i o n

Selected

Stock

Markets

0

0 . 0 2 0 . 0 6 0.1 0 . 1 4 0 . 1 8 0 . 2 2 0 . 2 6 0 . 3

S t a n d a r d D e v i a t i o n A v e r a g e M o n l h l y R e t u r n i n V . S . D o l l a r s

S o u r c e s : I n t e r n a t i a n al F i n a n c i a l S t a t i s t i c s , v a r i o u s C e n t c s l B a n k B u l l e t i n s , I F C O u a r t e r l y R e v i e w o f E m e r g i n g S t o c k M a r k e l s , a n d S t a n d a r d & P o o r s .

0 . 0 5

0 . 0 4

-

4.03

-

0.02 -

Argentine u

M e x i c o

0 Chile

V e n e z u e l a

P B razilp

a

C o l o m b i a

(27)
(28)

(in U.S.

dollars),

and hence in spreads, across t h e countries

in

our

sample.

Second, the "noise-to-signal ratio" of the domestic dollar rates varies

substantially across countries. As Chart 6 illustrates based on

ex

post

d a t a , countries o f f e r i n g t h e highest returns also had the greatest

volatility of returns. Third, d e s p i t e s i z a b l e capital inflows

the

positive differentials have not been f u l l y arbitraged away. The persistence and s i z e of thts wedge between domestic and f o r e i g n rates also appears to

vary markedly across countries,

4 . Other macroeconomic develovments

Selected macroeconomic developments are reported in Table 3 . Consider

how developments

in

1991--the

year

when c a p i t a l inflows grew to about

$40 billion--differ from e a r l i e r years. First, t h e r e was n renewal of economic growth. A f t e r three years of s t a g n a t i o n , real GDP increased by

almost 3 percent in 1991. However, gross capital formation as perceht of

GDP

remained constant at about t h e same level of the second half of the

1980s suggesting a more efficient utilization of xesouxces. A t the same

time, there was a marked drop

in

the

sate of in£ lation (which nevertheless remained at a three-digit level f o r t h e r e g i o n ) , and a significant reduction in central government fiscal d e f i c i t s .

The changfng economic conditions in Latin America are also reflected

in

the region's debt and solvency indicators. A t $441 billion, external debt amounts to 2.6 times exports of goods and services. Although still high,

this ratio has decreased markedly from the 3.5 figure in 1986. Since m o s t

o f Latin America's external debt ta comercial banks is still in terms of floating r a t e s , the drop

in

shorr tern U . S . i n t e r e s t rates and the drop in the debt to exports ratio has translated into a sapid decline in the

external debt service ratio over the last two years. In f a c t , the level of

the

debt service ratio in 1991 ( i . e . , 32.8 percent) is

of

the same order

of

magnitude as the levels observed before the previous c a p i t a l inflow episode

of 1978-81. As indicated above, capital inflows have been associated

with

r a p i d accumulation of international reserves, which reached t h e record figure of $ 65.3 billion in 1991. As shown

in

Table 3 , the r a t i o of reserves to irnporca was 33.5 in 1991, which is of a similar order of

magnitude as

in 1 9 7 7 - 7 8 .

These developments represent only part of the changing economic

environment

in

Latin America of the early 1990s.

In

addition to these, the move toward privatization and deregulation, the introduction of financial reforms, and the restructuring

o f

existing external debt have a l l

contributed to

bringing

Latin America back on the List of

viable

investment

locations

in

world financial markets.

Unfortunately,

the fact that several

(29)
(30)

sf these variables could n o t be quantified prevented us from including them

in the econometric analysis of the n e x t s e c t i o n .

It

is useful te compare the present episode of c a p i t a l i n f l o w s w i t h earlier similar episodes.

I

J

The previous capital inflows episode

occurred from

1978

to 1982, and was the precursor of the ensuing debt

crisis.

However,

the data

in

Tables 1 to 3

highlight

important differences

across these t w o episodes. First, the capital inflows o b s e r v e b t h u s f a r i n 1 9 9 0 - 9 1 are much smaller than

in

1 9 7 8 - 8 2 .

In

particular, c a p i t a l inflows

between $45

billion

and $50 billion were observed in each one of the three

years 1980-82. This difference becomes larger i f one compares the c a p i t a l

inflows as a percentage of GDP; while capital inflows in 1978-82 represented

7

percent o f GPP at t h a t t i m e , the capital inflows in 1991 are in the order of 4 percent of GDP f o r t h a t year. Y e t , the difference would probably become smaller if changes in capital

flight

are

taken i n t o account. While

in the earlier episode capital flight was increasing in m o s t countries along with increased (reported) capital inflows, in the present episode capital

inflows appear to be accompanied by a decrease in the stock of flight c a p i t a l for these countries.

Second, these t w o episodes differ in how

the

capital inflows are

matched by changes in the other accounts of the balance of payments. While

t h e present c a p i t a l inflows are accompanied

by

approximately equal increases

Ln the current account d e f i c i t and

in

o f f i c i a l reserves, the l a t t e r played a

relatively

minor

role

in

the 1 9 7 8 - 8 2 episode. That is, most capital inflows in

1978-82

financed

high

current account d e f i c i t s , with the monetary

authorities playing a less a c t i v e role, Notice t h a t the current account

d e f i c i t peaked

in

1981 at 5 . 5 percent of G D P , while the d e f i c i t i n 1991 is about

2

percent o f GDP. The combination of smaller current account deficits and t h e marked increase in o f f i c i a l reserves in

1990-91

indicates t h a t

during the present episode t h e r e is less of a decline in Latin America's net

foreign wealth than

in

the

earlier

episode and that there is more of a

cushion against adverse shocks to capital flows in future p e r i o d s .

2/

The

heavier degree of o f f i c i a l intervention in forefgn exchange markets in the

present episode may reflect the authorities' objectives t o bring actual reserves-to-imports ratios

back

to their desired levels

and/or

to meet

increases in t h e nominal demand for money with foreign-reserves-backed

monetization.

Third, the set

of underlying

macroeconomic condkrions and t h e

behavior

of fundamentals are now different from those in 1978-82 (Table 3 ) . In the

e a r l i e r e p i s o d e inflation rates were increasing, as were government budget

d e f i c i t s , and at the same time real GPP was growing at about 5 percent a

1/

I n fact, such comparisons are

the

subject of a separate research

-

p r o j e c t t h e authors are preparing.

2/ Notice, however, t h a t t h e burden of foreign debt was larger at

the

-

(31)

year.

In

the present circumstances, inflation is

falling,

although i t is still h i g h , and governments are balancing their previous d e f i c i t s . At the same time, there is now a recovery of growth in the reglon, which in the prevtous

three

years had b a s i c a l l y disappeared.

B e s i d e s these d i f f e r e n c e s , there are many simhlarities in the t w o episodes: accumulation of international reserves, real exchange rate

appreciation, boornrng stock markets, and h i g h differentials between domestic and foreign rates of return. The similarity e x h i b i t e d

by

the behavior of s t o c k markets then and now 5 s striking. In 1979, s t o c k prices in dollar

terms rose

by

234 percent in Argentina, while in

Chile

they rose

by

116

percent and

in

Mextco by 63 percent--magnitudes in line w i t h the experience in 1991.

While more d i f f i c u l t to document, another important episode of c a p i t a l inflows to Latin America occurred in t h e 1920s, when the investment climate seemed reasonabLy good. As Diaz Alejandro (1983) n o t e s , before World War

I

portfolio and direct investment i n L a t i n America originated mainly i n

Europe. However, the 1920s were dominated by c a p i t a l inflows from the

United S t a t e s , while investments from Europe markedly slowed down. In

p a r t i c u l a r , there was a pronounced expansion of public borrowing in the New

York market at that time. Diaz Alejandro (1983) provides evidence of

sizable investments

by

Britain and t h e

United

States

in

Argentina,

Chile,

Cuba, and Mexico. Toward the end of the 1920s, these t w o major foreign investors had accumulated a stock of claims in Latin America of around four

times the value of

annual

merchandise exports in that

region.

J

I

An

important

lesson from

these episodes is

that

the c a p i t a l inflows

were eventually reversed in what turned out to be major crises.

During

the debt crisis of the mid 1980s, capital inflows to Latin America were reduced

to about 20 percent of their earlier values, P u t differently, the total

amount of

voluntary

loan and bond financing flowing t o Latin American

countrkes during t h e entire 1983-88 period was considerably smaller t h a t f o r

1982

alone. As access to fnternational credit markets

was

curtailed and

the

capital account surplus dwindled, a sharp reduction

in

current account deficits became necessary,

In the 1920s-30s episode, external factors resulted

in

a sharp fall in

c a p i t a l inflows to L t i n America

toward the

end of the

1920s, well

before

some of the countries

in

the

region

began having difficulties servicing

t h e i r external d e b t s . Foreign capital

markets

d r i e d

up in the 1930s. While

the increased burden of debt servicing in the c r i s i s of the 1980s came via higher interest r a t e s , during the c r i s i s of the

1930s

it came through a fall

fn the dollar price level which led to a marked increase i n the real burden

o f debt servicing. It is at t h i s p o i n t that most countries suspended normal

Thus, assuming a 5 percent rate of return

Diaz

Alejandro (1983)

Figure

Table 2. Latin America: Items in the Capital Account
Table 4. US, Balance of Payments
Table 5. Changes in Capital Accounts (In billims of U. S. dollas)
Table 6. Eetablishing the Comavement Jn Maeroeconomle Series
+2

References

Related documents

Sense of belonging was measured with the Sense of Belonging Instrument- Psychological, social engagement was measured with the Lubben Social Network Scale and psychological

In fact, since cognitive science is such an interdisciplinary field, we expect students to go to graduate programs in Computer Science, Psychology, Philosophy, Neuroscience,

The published sources consulted in development of the conceptual model include: studies on the benefits of preservation [Blue Ribbon Task Force on Sustainable Digital Preservation

The present study discusses the use of fuzzy inference mechanism to recognize the most notable rules in the development of fault prediction model using GUAJE framework ( Alonso

A techno-economical model of a SUNDISC cycle plant was created based on efficiency estimates for the solar field and receivers, empirical correlations for the heat transfer in the

It was felt that building upon the underlying aims of PCARs and person centred planning, ensuring student active participation and that the student is held at the centre of the