• No results found

Today s consumers face richer information environments

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Today s consumers face richer information environments"

Copied!
14
0
0

Loading.... (view fulltext now)

Full text

(1)

473

䉷2004 by JOURNAL OF CONSUMER RESEARCH, Inc.●Vol. 30●March 2004 All rights reserved. 0093-5301/2004/3004-0001$10.00

Decision Making in Information-Rich

Environments: The Role of Information

Structure

NICHOLAS H. LURIE

*

Today’s consumers are often overloaded with information. This article argues that traditional approaches to measuring the amount of information in a choice set fail to account for important structural dimensions of information and may therefore incorrectly predict information overload. Two experiments show that a structural approach to measuring information, such as information theory, is better able to predict information overload and that information structure also has important im-plications for information acquisition. A Monte-Carlo simulation, in which decision rules are applied to multiple information environments, shows that the amount of information processing mediates the relationship between information structure and information overload.

T

oday’s consumers face richer information environments than ever before. Whether it is the 13,798 mutual funds on Quicken’s Web site or the 1,057 PDAs on Amazon’s Web site, it is clear that today’s consumers have many choices. Several researchers (e.g., Jacoby, Speller, and Kohn 1974a, 1974b; Keller and Staelin 1987; Malhotra 1982; Scammon 1977) have found evidence that increasing the number of alternatives or attributes in a choice set leads to a decline in the quality of consumers’ choices. (See Keller and Staelin [1987] for a review.) Other research has shown that consumers are less likely to purchase a product when a store offers an extensive selection of that product than when the selection is reduced (Iyengar and Lepper 2000). What factors affect the amount of information that consum-ers are asked to process and the likelihood that they will be overloaded with information?

This article argues that the amount of information in a choice set, and therefore the likelihood of information over-load, depends on multiple structural factors of information. *Nicholas H. Lurie is assistant professor of marketing, Kenan-Flagler Business School, University of North Carolina, Chapel Hill, Chapel Hill, NC 27599-3490 (lurie@unc.edu). The author thanks the members of his dissertation committee: Rashi Glazer (chair), Russell Winer, Michael Ran-ney, and Joydeep Srivastava, as well as Barry Bayus, Gal Zauberman, Rebecca Ratner, Steve Hoeffler, John Lynch, Eric Johnson, and particularly Jim Bettman for their helpful comments and suggestions. The author also thanks Wooseong Kang for programming assistance with the simulation, and the editor, associate editor, and reviewers for the many beneficial comments that improved this article. Financial support for this research was provided by a Mellon Foundation grant from Hal Varian and the School of Information Management and Systems, University of California, Berke-ley, as well as the dissertation competition program of the Center for Technology and Marketing, University of California, Berkeley.

Failing to account for these factors may lead to a faulty prediction of overload. Information structure has important implications for information acquisition, the amount of in-formation processing, and decision quality. As such, this article provides an important conceptual link between re-search on information overload (Jacoby et al. 1974a, 1974b; Keller and Staelin 1987; Malhotra 1982) and research on decision processes (Bettman, Johnson, and Payne 1990; Creyer, Bettman, and Payne 1990; Johnson and Payne 1985; Payne, Bettman, and Johnson 1988). Two experiments and a Monte-Carlo simulation examine how information struc-ture affects information acquisition, decision processes, and decision quality.

MEASURING INFORMATION

Traditional approaches to measuring the amount of in-formation provided to consumers (e.g., Bettman et al. 1990; Jacoby et al. 1974a, 1974b; Keller and Staelin 1987; Mal-hotra 1982; Payne 1976; Payne et al. 1988; Wright 1975) involve simple counts of the number of alternatives and attributes in a choice set. These counts are then used to make predictions about decision processes and the quality of consumers’ choices. Such an approach assumes that more alternatives mean more information. However, is it possible to provide consumers with more alternatives but less infor-mation?

Formal measures of information structure (information theory) developed by Shannon (1949) and extended by Gar-ner (1962) offer a potential alternative to traditional ap-proaches. Information theory proposes that the amount of

(2)

information is a measure of the number and probability of outcomes; more formally,

m

I(A)p⫺

p(a ) log p(a ), (1)

i 2 i ip1

where ai(a1, a2, . . . am) are discrete outcomes. In the

do-main of consumer choice, ai(a1, a2, . . . am) may be thought

of as the attribute levels of attribute A, and p(ai) is the

relative frequency of ai among alternatives. Unlike context

variables, such as interattribute correlation and decision rules, information structure is a task variable that can be measured independently from particular data values (Bett-man, Johnson, and Payne 1993). Information structure in-teracts with context variables to affect the amount of effort involved in making a decision, information acquisition, and decision strategies, as well as decision quality.

A structural approach to information suggests that there are multiple dimensions determining the amount of infor-mation (potential outcomes) that consumers need to process when making choices among a given set of product alter-natives. These include the number of alternatives, the num-ber of attributes, the numnum-ber of different attribute levels associated with each attribute, and the distribution of at-tribute levels across alternatives. As a measure of the amount of information in a choice set, information structure should provide an indication of the amount of information pro-cessing necessary to make a decision.

Formal measures of information have been used exten-sively in psychology and economics (for reviews see Garner [1962] and Dawes [1970]). In marketing, structural (i.e., information theoretic) measures have been used to predict brand switching (Herniter 1973), estimate consideration sets (Gensch and Soofi 1995), measure consumer variety seeking (Kahn 1995) and preferences (Glazer 1984), and manipulate the informativeness of feedback (West 1996).

Because the structural approach encompasses the simple counts of previous research, it can be used to account for previous research showing that an increase in the number of alternatives (attributes) can lead to declines in decision quality. When attribute levels are evenly distributed across alternatives, as in previous research (Bettman et al. 1993; Jacoby et al. 1974a, 1974b; Keller and Staelin 1987; Mal-hotra 1982; Payne et al. 1988), equation (1) reduces to

I(A)plog a,2 (2)

where a is the number of attribute levels of attribute A.

INFORMATION STRUCTURE AND

INFORMATION OVERLOAD

A structural approach suggests that the amount of infor-mation to process increases with the number of attribute levels and is greatest when attribute levels occur with uni-form probability. This means that the likelihood of

infor-mation overload should be higher and choice quality lower when attribute levels are uniformly distributed across alter-natives or when there are more attribute levels. For example, if 50% of calculators offered by a consumer electronics Web site have one-line screen displays and 50% have two-line displays, there is more uncertainty and, therefore, more in-formation to gain by examining the calculators, than if 90% of calculators have one-line displays and 10% have two-line displays. In addition, a structural approach suggests that although an increase in the number of alternatives in a choice set may lead to overload when all other factors are held constant, the same increase in the number of alternatives may not lead to overload when factors such as the distri-bution of attribute levels across alternatives and the number of attribute levels are also changed. For example, a choice set with more alternatives can have fewer attribute levels (e.g., two instead of four types of screen displays), or the attribute levels in the larger set can be nonuniformly dis-tributed across alternatives. This implies that the impact of the number of alternatives on choice quality will be mediated by information structure.

From the general proposition that information overload is a function of the amount of information I(A) in a choice set, come the following testable hypotheses:

H1a: The even (uniform) distribution of attribute

lev-els across alternatives lowers decision quality relative to the uneven (nonuniform) distribution of attribute levels;

H1b: An increase in the number of attribute levels

lowers decision quality.

H2: Information structure mediates the relationship between the number of alternatives and decision quality.

Hypothesis 1 suggests that choice sets with attribute levels distributed evenly across alternatives, or those with more attribute levels, are more likely to be associated with in-formation overload than those for which attribute levels are not evenly distributed across alternatives. Hypothesis 2 sug-gests that information structure, not just the number of al-ternatives or attributes, is the primary determinant of in-formation overload. In particular, a choice set with more alternatives but unevenly distributed attribute levels may in fact lead to decision outcomes that are not significantly worse than a set with fewer alternatives with an even dis-tribution of attribute levels across alternatives.

INFORMATION STRUCTURE AND

INFORMATION PROCESSING

As a measure of the total amount of information in a choice set, information structure is also a measure of the average amount of information associated with a particular element. Because decision makers often adapt their decision-making processes to the decision environment (Payne et al.

(3)

1988), information structure may have important implica-tions for information processing as well as decision quality. Process tracing methods such as Mouselab (Payne et al. 1988), eye tracking (Russo and Dosher 1983), or verbal protocols (Jarvenpaa 1989) may be used to assess infor-mation acquisition. Although not a measure of the use of a particular decision rule (Bettman et al. 1993), information acquisition can be used as a proxy for the amount of in-formation processing, the amount of processing effort, and selectivity in processing (Creyer et al. 1990; Jarvenpaa 1989; Payne 1976; Payne et al. 1988). In particular, the amount of information processing can be assessed by counting the number of times that information boxes are opened (acqui-sitions) for a particular decision; the amount of processing effort can be measured as the time spent per acquisition; and processing selectivity can be determined by the pro-portion of time spent on the most important attribute, the variance in time spent on each alternative, and the variance in time spent on each attribute (Creyer et al. 1990; Payne et al. 1988).

Amount of Information Processing

A structural approach to measuring information suggests that the even distribution of attribute levels raises the amount of information associated with each information element by increasing the decision maker’s uncertainty that a particular alternative takes on a particular attribute value. In other words, the even distribution of attribute levels makes it harder for the decision maker to guess the attribute value for a given alternative; acquiring information about that at-tribute provides more information. This should slow down the rate at which information is processed.

Similarly, an increase in the number of attribute levels raises the amount of information associated with each at-tribute by raising a decision maker’s uncertainty about pos-sible attribute values. In other words, more attribute levels also make it harder for the decision maker to guess the attribute value; acquiring information about an attribute with four levels provides more information than acquiring in-formation about an attribute with two levels. Because the even distribution of attribute levels or an increase in the number of attribute levels raise the average amount of in-formation associated with each attribute by alternative com-bination, decision makers should take more time to acquire and process information. Under time pressure, this should decrease the total number of acquisitions per decision.

H3: When time pressure is high, the even distribution

of attribute levels across alternatives:

(a) increases the average amount of time per ac-quisition;

(b) decreases the number of acquisitions.

H4: When time pressure is high, an increase in the

number of attribute levels:

(a) increases the average amount of time per ac-quisition;

(b) decreases the number of acquisitions. In other words, an increase in the amount of attribute in-formation, whether through the distribution of attribute lev-els or the number of attribute levlev-els, is expected to lead to a higher average time per acquisition and fewer acquisitions under time pressure. Note that these hypotheses question the assumption that information acquisition takes the same amount of time regardless of information structure (e.g., Bettman et al. 1990).

Processing Selectivity

Previous research has shown that decision makers often adapt their decision strategies to the information environ-ment (Payne, Bettman, and Johnson 1993) and that choice sets with more alternatives are associated with less com-pensatory processing (Payne 1976). This suggests more gen-erally that choice sets that contain more information should be associated with less compensatory processing, even if there is no increase in the number of alternatives and at-tributes. Noncompensatory decision rules are associated with higher variance (greater selectivity) in processing across alternatives and attributes, while compensatory de-cision rules involve more uniform processing of information of alternative and attribute information (Bettman et al. 1993; Payne et al. 1988). In particular, noncompensatory decision processes lead to an increase in time spent on information related to the most important attribute and to greater variance in time spent per attribute and time spent per alternative (Creyer et al. 1990). Since choice sets with attribute levels distributed evenly across alternatives and those with more attribute levels contain more information, they should be associated with greater selectivity in processing.

H5a: Under time pressure, the even (uniform)

distri-bution of attribute levels across alternatives in-creases processing selectivity;

H5b: Under time pressure, an increase in the number

of attribute levels increases processing selectiv-ity.

Hypothesis 1 proposes that the even distribution of at-tribute levels or an increase in the number of atat-tribute levels will lead to declines in decision quality. Hypothesis 2 pro-poses that information structure mediates the effect of an increase in the number of alternatives on decision quality. In particular, choice sets with more alternatives but for which attribute levels are unevenly distributed may not be asso-ciated with declines in decision quality. Hypotheses 3 and 4 propose that the even distribution of attribute levels or an increase in the number of attribute levels will increase the amount of time spent on each acquisition and lower the number of acquisitions made under time pressure. Hypoth-esis 5 proposes that the even distribution of attribute levels

(4)

or an increase in the number of attribute levels will lead to greater selectivity (higher variance) in processing under time pressure.

Two experimental studies examine these hypotheses. Hy-potheses 1a and 2 are tested in an experiment that examines the relationship between information structure and infor-mation overload. Hypotheses 1b, 3, 4, and 5 are tested in a second experiment that extends study 1 by examining how information structure affects information processing as well as decision quality.

STUDY 1

Method

Participants and Procedure.

Participants (143 under-graduate students) were asked to imagine they had decided to buy a calculator from Electronics USA, an online retailer of consumer electronics that carries several models of pocket calculators and provides ratings on calculator attributes. They were also told that each of the available calculators costs the same amount ($29.95), a price within their budget. (See Biehal and Chakravarti [1983] for a similar task.)

Participants were told that a recent Consumer Reports article suggests that there are several dimensions to consider when buying a calculator. These include versatility (rated from one to 10 stars with 10 as the best), ease of use (rated from one to seven stars with seven as the best), battery life (ranging from three to 15 hours), warranty (ranging from three months to five years), weight (ranging from one-half to 12 oz.), memory size (ranging from four to 264 kb) and screen size (ranging from one to eight lines). To help par-ticipants in their decision, a friend had indicated the impor-tance weights of each of the seven attributes on a 100-point scale (highversatilityp70, high ease of usep60, long batterylifep50, longwarrantyp40, lowweightp40, largememoryp30, and largescreenp30). In addition, there was a best (or dominant) calculator that was equal to or better than all other alternatives on every attribute. The importance weights and dominant alternative provide a nor-mative sense of choice “goodness” and avoid potential mea-surement errors associated with using participants’ own pref-erences to determine the best choice (Meyer and Johnson 1989; Payne et al. 1993). Four lottery prizes of $25 were offered as incentives for participants to make the “best” choice. In order to prevent ceiling effects and ensure that there would be “information overload,” participants were given only two minutes to make their choices. Those who did not make a choice within that time would be ineligible for the lottery.

Information was presented in a matrix form simulta-neously for all alternatives. A randomly generated single letter and three-digit number identified each calculator model. At the bottom of the screen participants could mark, out of the 18 or 27 available, the calculators they would consider buying for their friend and write the name of the calculator they wished to purchase. This was used to de-termine the probability that the dominant calculator was

considered, the probability that the dominant calculator was chosen, and choice quality relative to the best and worst alternatives in the choice set.

Experimental Variable

Information Structure.

Information structure was ma-nipulated at four levels using a 2 (18 or 27 alternatives)# 2 (even or uneven distribution of attribute levels across al-ternatives) between-participants design. This design allows the replication of previous results, that increasing the number of alternatives lowers the probability of choosing the “best” alternative and creates conditions in which increasing the number of alternatives may not lead to declines in decision quality.

The distribution of attribute levels across alternatives was manipulated by changing the distribution of attribute levels of four of the seven attributes (warranty length, weight, memory, and screen size), each of which occurred at three levels. In the “even” conditions, the three levels of each of the four manipulated attributes were evenly distributed across 18 or 27 alternatives; in the “uneven” conditions, seven-ninths of the calculators had one level, one-ninth of the calculators had the second level, and one-ninth of the alternatives had the third level for each of the four attributes. In the uneven distribution of attribute levels condition, in order to avoid confounding the manipulation of the distri-bution of attribute levels with the skew of attribute levels, the distribution of attribute levels was chosen so that the dominant calculator shared the same level as the majority of calculators for two of the attributes, warranty and mem-ory, and was in the minority of calculators for two of the attributes, weight and screen size. The three levels of the nonmanipulated attributes (versatility, ease of use, and bat-tery life) were evenly distributed across alternatives, and the values of these attributes were identical in all conditions. In study 1, average interattribute correlations were around zero in both even (high information) and uneven (low infor-mation) distribution conditions (r’sp.002and .003, NS). This controls for the potential effects of interattribute cor-relation in which choice sets with positively correlated at-tributes are associated with higher choice quality than those with negatively correlated attributes (Bettman et al. 1993). The order of alternatives was determined randomly but was the same for all participants. To allow choice quality to be compared, the attribute values of the dominant alternative were the same in all four conditions.

Each choice set had either 18 or 27 calculators. Together, the manipulations of attribute levels and the number of cal-culators provided participants in the 18-alternative-uneven distribution condition with 36.28 bits of information, partic-ipants in the 18-alternative-even distribution condition with 46.26 bits of information, participants in the 27-alternative-uneven distribution condition with 41.37 bits of information, and participants in the 27-alternative-even distribution con-dition with 52.75 bits of information. This suggests that over-load is more likely to be observed when comparing the

(5)

36.28-TABLE 1

STUDY 1: CHOICE, CONSIDERATION, AND CHOICE QUALITY

Uneven distribution Even distribution

18 alternatives (36.28 bits) 27 alternatives (41.37 bits) 18 alternatives (46.26 bits) 27 alternatives (52.75 bits) Choice (corrected)a .68 (21/30) .56 (18/31) .58 (17/28) .35 (10/27) Consideration (corrected) .79 (24/30) .70 (22/31) .55 (16/28) .50 (14/27) Choice quality .96 (.04) .95 (.04) .78 (.05) .65 (.05)

NOTE.—The number of bits (amount of information) in each condition is determined by the number of alternatives and the distribution of attribute levels. Choice and consideration are the chance-corrected proportion of participants that chose or considered the dominant alternative in each condition. Actual frequencies are shown in parentheses. Choice quality is the multiattribute utility of the chosen alternative relative to the best and worst alternatives in the choice set. Standard deviations are in parentheses.

a

Choice and consideration proportions are corrected for chance following Malhotra (1982):Pip(PiP )/(1icP )ic , wherePi pthe proportion of correct choice adjusted for chance,P proportion of correct choice by chance alone, andPpthe observed proportion of correct choice unadjusted for chance factors.

ic i

bit and 52.75-bit conditions and less likely to be observed when comparing the 46.26-bit and 41.37-bit conditions—even though each involves an equal increase in the number of alternatives from 18 to 27 and provide information on the same seven attributes.

Dependent Measures

Probability of Choice and Consideration.

Partici-pants were asked to mark the calculators they would con-sider buying for a friend and to write down the name of the calculator they wanted to buy for their friend. To allow the 18 and 27 alternative conditions to be compared, the prob-abilities of choice and consideration were corrected for chance factors (Malhotra 1982; Malhotra, Jain, and Lagakos 1982).

Choice Quality.

Choice quality was assessed in terms of the relative weighted additive utility of each choice (Creyer et al. 1990; Johnson and Payne 1985; Payne et al. 1988):

Choice Qualityp

Weighted Additive ValueChoice⫺Weighted Additive ValueWorst

. (3) Weighted Additive ValueBest⫺Weighted Additive ValueWorst

This measure is bounded by one if the best choice is selected and zero if the worst choice is selected.

Results

One hundred and sixteen participants (81%) finished within the two-minute period. Those who did not finish within the allotted time were dropped from the analysis.

Experimental Checks.

The distribution of attribute lev-els manipulation was measured with two seven-point Likert scales: “Many of the calculators were the same weight” and “Many of the calculators had the same size memory.” Since the correlation of these measures was not high (rp.45), separate analyses were conducted for each measure. The ANOVA results show that participants in the uneven 2#2

distribution condition perceived attributes to be more similar in weight (M’sp4.98 and 4.31; F(1, 112)p6.84, p!

) and more similar in memory size ( and 4.29;

.01 M’sp4.89

) than participants in the even

dis-F(1, 112)p5.84, p!.05

tribution condition. The manipulation of the number of al-ternatives was tested using one seven-point Likert scale: “There were many calculators to choose from.” The 2# ANOVA results show that participants in the 27-calculator 2

condition perceived there to be more alternatives in the choice set than participants in the 18-calculator condition (M’sp6.50and 6.12;F(1, 112)p4.26, p!.05).

Effect on Choice, Consideration, and Choice

Qual-ity.

Table 1 shows chance-corrected choice and consid-eration proportions as well as choice quality scores in the four conditions. Logistic regression shows that increasing amounts of information significantly lowered the chance-corrected probability of choosing (Bp⫺.34 SD, p.16; Wald 2 , ) and considering the

x (1, Np116)p4.65 p!.05

best alternative ( , ; Wald 2 Bp⫺.47 SDp.17 x (1, Np

, ). ANOVA results show that increasing 116)p7.87 p!.01

amounts of information lowered choice quality (M’sp

, .95, .78, and .65) in the 36.28, 41.37, 46.26, and 52.75 .96

bit conditions, respectively (F(3, 112)p10.95 p, !.0001). Polynomial contrasts revealed a significant linear trend of information structure on choice quality (F(1, 112)p

, ). Higher order trends were not significant. 32.03 p!.0001

The analysis supports hypothesis 1a, that the even dis-tribution of attribute levels lowers decision quality. When attribute levels were evenly distributed across alternatives, the dominant calculator was less likely to be chosen (ad-justedproportionsp0.47and 0.62,zp1.67 p, !.05) and less likely to be considered (adjusted proportionsp0.52

and 0.74,zp2.45 p, !.01) than when attribute levels were unevenly distributed. The ANOVA results for the choice quality scores show that the even distribution of attribute levels was associated with lower quality choices than the uneven distribution of attribute levels (M’sp.72and .96; , , 2 ). The interaction

F(1, 112)p29.19 p!.0001 h p.21

p

between the number of alternatives and the distribution of attribute levels was not significant (F(1, 112)p1.61, NS). Results also support hypothesis 2, that information structure

(6)

mediates the relationship between the number of alternatives and choice quality. As mentioned above, an increase in the amount of information in the choice set significantly lowered the probability of choosing and considering the best alter-native. An increase in the number of alternatives lowered the probability of choosing (Bp⫺.07 SD, p.04; Wald , [one-tailed]) and

direction-2

x (1, Np116)p2.79 p!.05

ally lowered the probability of considering (Bp⫺.07,

; Wald 2 ,

[one-SDp.04 x (1, Np116)p2.79 p!.05

tailed]) the best alternative. An increase in the number of alternatives in the choice set also marginally lowered average choice quality (M’sp.80 and .87; F(1, 116)p

, [one-tailed], 2 When both the amount 2.57 p!.06 h p.02).

p

of information and number of alternatives are used to pre-dict the probability that the best alternative is chosen, the number of alternatives is no longer significant (Bp.49, ; Wald 2 NS [one-tailed]), SDp.39 x (1, Np116)p1.57,

but the amount of information remains significant (Bp

, ; Wald 2 ,

⫺.30 SDp.16 x (1, Np116)p3.46 p!.05 [one-tailed]). For the probability that the best alternative is considered, the number of alternatives is not significant

( , ; Wald 2 , NS

Bp⫺.01 SDp.05 x (1, Np116)p.03

[one-tailed]), but the amount of information remains sig-nificant ( , ; Wald 2

Bp⫺.46 SDp.17 x (1, Np116)p

, ). Similarly, for choice quality, the number of 7.40 p!.01

alternatives is no longer significant (F(1, 116)p.04, NS [one-tailed]), but the amount of information remains sig-nificant (F(1, 116)p29.01 p, !.001).

Planned comparisons show that although increasing the number of alternatives in a choice set can sometimes lead to information overload, the same increase in the number of alternatives does not lower decision quality when the amount of information in a choice set is not increased. For example, although the dominant calculator was less likely to be chosen in the 27-alternative-even distribution (52.75 bit) condition than in the 18-alternative-uneven distribution (36.28 bit) condition (adjusted proportionsp0.35 and 0.68,zp2.54 p, !.01) and less likely to be considered for purchase (adjusted proportionsp0.50 and 0.79, zp

, ), it was not significantly less likely to be chosen 2.27 p!.05

in the 27-alternative-uneven distribution (41.37 bit) condi-tion than in the 18-alternative-even distribucondi-tion (46.26 bit) condition (adjusted proportionsp0.56 and 0.58, zp

NS), or less likely to be considered for purchase (ad-.16,

justed proportionsp0.70 and 0.55, zp1.21, NS). Al-though relative choice quality was significantly lower in the 27-alternative-even distribution (52.75 bit) condition than in the 18-alternative-uneven distribution (36.28 bit) condi-tion (M’sp.65 and .96; F(1, 112)p24.06 p, !.0001), choice quality was actually significantly higher in the 27-alternative-uneven distribution (41.37 bit) condition than in the 18-alternative-even distribution (46.26 bit) condition (M’sp.95and .78;F(1, 112)p7.36 p, !.01), suggesting that more alternatives may sometimes be associated with less information and higher choice quality. Together these results show that information structure, not the number of alternatives, is the crucial factor in determining overload.

Discussion

Results from study 1 show that information structure is a better predictor of information overload than simple counts of alternatives. The structural approach encompasses simple counts, thus accounting for traditional findings that an in-crease in the number of alternatives in a choice set can lead to declines in decision quality. At the same time, the struc-tural approach also accounts for other dimensions that affect the amount of information in a choice set. This more thor-ough accounting allows the structural approach to predict when the same increase in the number of alternatives will not lead to overload. In addition, the structural approach shows that overload may occur even if there is no change in the number of attributes or alternatives in a choice set. One way that this may occur is if the distribution of attribute levels across alternatives becomes more uniform.

STUDY 2

Study 2 extends study 1 by examining the effect of in-formation structure on decision outcomes and inin-formation acquisition in a process tracing experiment. Study 2 also uses a within-subjects design that provides a strong test of adaptive behavior (Payne et al. 1988). Importantly, study 2 manipulates information structure while holding both the number of alternatives and the number of attributes constant.

Experimental Procedure

Design and Task.

In study 2, participants acquired formation and chose a calculator for a friend using an in-formation acquisition system similar to Mouselab (Bettman et al. 1990; Creyer et al. 1990; Payne et al. 1988). Partic-ipants made choices among 24 sets of calculators. In study 2, neither the number of attributes nor the number of alter-natives was used to manipulate information structure; in each choice set there were 16 alternatives defined by eight attributes. Information structure was manipulated at four levels, with six repetitions at each level, through the number of attribute levels and the distribution of attribute levels across alternatives. Four lottery prizes of $25 were offered as incentives for participants to make the “best” choice. In order to prevent ceiling effects and ensure that there would be “information overload,” participants were given only one minute for each choice. Because dominant alternatives are rare in most consumer environments, dominant alternatives were not used in this study.

Twenty-seven undergraduate students (juniors and sen-iors) participated in the study. Participants were told that they wanted to buy a calculator for a friend’s birthday. A recent Consumer Reports article suggested eight dimensions to consider when buying a calculator: versatility, ease of use, battery life, warranty, weight, memory, screen quality, and features. Calculators were rated on these dimensions on a scale from zero to 1,000, where 1,000 is best. To help participants in their decision, their friend had indicated the importance of these dimensions on a scale from zero to 100,

(7)

where 100 was the most important. Participants were told to use these weights in their decisions. Participants were given practice using the information acquisition system and were told that they had decided to buy the calculator from Electronics USA, an online retailer. They were also told that they would be making 24 choices and would have 60 sec-onds to make each choice.

Information Acquisition System.

A computer-based information acquisition system similar to Mouselab (Bett-man et al. 1990; Creyer et al. 1990; Payne et al. 1988) was developed specifically for this study. The first row contained attribute weights for the eight attributes. Attribute weights were selected by independent draws from a uniform distri-bution and were rescaled to sum to 100 (Johnson and Payne 1985; Payne et al. 1988). The next 16 rows contained the attribute values for each alternative. At the bottom of the screen, participants could select their preferred alternative among the 16 available alternatives. At the top of the screen a timer showed the time remaining for a particular decision, and an indicator showed the decision number.

Information about attribute weights and attribute values was hidden behind opaque boxes. Moving the mouse cursor over a box revealed its contents, and the information re-mained visible until the cursor was moved out of the box. The information was available for only one box at a time. Participants could open as many boxes as many times as they wished. After 60 seconds, moving the mouse over the boxes no longer revealed information, and a message ap-peared asking participants to “please make a choice.” The information acquisition system recorded the number of boxes opened, the order and time they were opened, the total elapsed time associated with a particular decision, and the final choice.

Each participant made 24 choices (four information struc-ture conditions times six replications). The first 12 choice sets contained three replications of the four information structure conditions. Within each block of 12 choice sets, the order of alternatives within the set, as well as the order of choice sets within the block, was randomized with the same order for all participants. See Creyer et al. (1990) and Payne et al. (1988) for similar procedures.

Experimental Variable

Information Structure.

Information structure was ma-nipulated at four levels through the number of attribute lev-els and the distribution of attribute levlev-els across alternatives. Twenty-four choice sets consisting of 16 alternatives and eight attributes were created. Depending on the condition, there were two or four attribute levels. This manipulation is different from previous information acquisition research (Bettman et al. 1990, 1993; Creyer et al. 1990; Payne et al. 1988) in which the number of attribute levels for any at-tribute equaled the number of alternatives. When there were two attribute levels, two values were randomly chosen for each attribute from a uniform distribution ranging from zero (least preferred) to 1,000 (most preferred). When there were

four attribute levels, four values were randomly chosen for each attribute.

When attribute levels were evenly distributed across al-ternatives and there were two attribute levels, one attribute value was shared by eight of the alternatives, and the other by the remaining eight alternatives. When there were four attribute levels, each of the four attribute values was shared by four of the alternatives. When attribute levels were un-evenly distributed and there were two attribute levels, one attribute value was shared by 14 of the 16 alternatives, and the other by two of the 16 alternatives. When there were four attribute levels, one of the attribute values was shared by 10 of the 16 alternatives, and the other three attribute levels were each shared by two of the remaining six alter-natives. As in study 1, the potential effects of attribute skew were controlled by having the majority of alternatives share the highest attribute value for four of the attributes and by having the majority of alternatives share the lowest attribute value for the remaining four attributes. This suggests that in the uneven distribution condition, half the attributes were less diagnostic and half the attributes were more diagnostic of the best alternative than when the attribute levels were evenly distributed (Van Wallendael and Guignard 1992).

Because it is impossible to change the number of levels of an attribute without simultaneously changing the distri-bution of attribute levels, the manipulations are nonortho-gonal. This means that the effects of the number of attribute levels and the distribution of attribute levels across alter-natives should be judged in terms of their combined effect on the total amount of information in a choice set. The manipulations created information environments with 17.39 bits in the two attribute level–uneven distribution condition, 32.00 bits in the two attribute level–even distribution con-dition, 49.56 bits in the four attribute–uneven distribution condition, and 64.00 bits in the four attribute level–even distribution condition. In study 2, mean interattribute cor-relations were similar but directionally more positive in the even (high information) than in the uneven (low informa-tion) distribution conditions (r’sp.05 and .01, NS). Be-cause choice sets with positively correlated attributes are associated with higher quality decisions (Bettman et al. 1993), this represents a stronger test of hypothesis 1a. Note also that simple counts of alternatives and attributes predict no differences among the choice sets since all choice sets contain 16 alternatives and eight attributes.

Dependent Measures

Seven dependent measures were collected for this study: decision quality, the number of acquisitions, the average time per acquisition, the proportion of time spent on the most important attribute, the variance in time spent per at-tribute, the variance in time spent per alternative, and the amount of alternative versus attribute-based processing. See Payne et al. (1993) for a review of these and other measures of decision-making outcomes and processes.

(8)

TABLE 2

STUDY 2: MEANS AND STANDARD DEVIATIONS OF DEPENDENT MEASURES

Two attribute levels Four attribute levels Uneven distribution (17.39 bits) Even distribution (32.00 bits) Uneven distribution (49.56 bits) Even distribution (64.00 bits) Choice qualitya .87 (.03) .80 (.03) .77 (.04) .74 (.05) Number of acquisitions 168.5 (8.7) 164.8 (9.8) 149.0 (9.3) 141.3 (7.4) Average time per acquisition (seconds) .199

(.008) .214 (.009) .211 (.009) .220 (.010) Proportion of time on most important attribute .31

(.02) .28 (.03) .34 (.04) .35 (.04) Variance in proportion of time per attribute .0062

(.0011) .0080 (.0011) .0114 (.0019) .0085 (.0013) Variance in proportion of time per alternative .0004

(.0001) .0005 (.0001) .0004 (.0001) .0009 (.0002) Acquisition patternb .62 (.04) ⫺ .44 (.04) ⫺ .54 (.05) ⫺ .53 (.05) Percent of unique cells examined .54

(.02) .51 (.02) .47 (.02) .46 (.02) Amount of information experienced (bits)c 9.44

(.35) 16.18 (.59) 23.12 (1.04) 29.57 (1.09)

NOTE.—The number of bits (amount of information) in each condition is determined by the number and distribution of attribute levels. Standard deviations are given in parentheses.

a

Quality of choice relative to the best and worst alternatives in the choice set. b

Index of the relative amount of attribute (⫺) vs. alternative-based (+) processing. c

Percentage of unique cells examined multiplied by the amount of information in each choice set.

study 1 by comparing the utility of the chosen alternative to the utilities of the best and worst choices in each choice set. Because dominant alternatives were not present in study 2, probabilities of consideration and choice were not calculated.

Acquisitions.

To determine how information structure in a choice set of fixed size affects information acquisition, the number of acquisitions and the amount of time spent acquiring information were measured. These measures were used to calculate the average amount of time per acquisition.

Processing Selectivity.

To assess how information structure affects selectivity in processing, the proportion of time spent acquiring information about the most important attribute and the variance in time spent acquiring infor-mation about alternatives and attributes were measured (Bettman et al. 1993; Creyer et al. 1990; Payne et al. 1988). To normalize the variance associated with positively skewed time data and to limit the effects of outliers, time values were transformed by taking logs and observations more than three standard deviations away from the mean and were not included in the variance of proportions analysis (West 1996; Winer, Brown, and Michels 1991).

Acquisition Pattern.

Although no specific prediction of attribute versus alternative-based acquisition was made, an index of attribute versus alternative-based transitions was created by taking the number of alternative-based transitions minus the number of attribute-based transitions and then dividing by the sum of alternative- and attribute-based

tran-sitions (Payne 1976). This index ranges from⫺1 (indicating only attribute-based processing) to +1 (indicating only al-ternative-based processing).

Results

Table 2 provides the means and standard deviations for the dependent measures as a function of information struc-ture. Of the 27 participants, four did not take the task se-riously: they did not gather any information (open any boxes) for at least one of the 24 decisions and, therefore, were not included in the analysis. The mean quality of par-ticipants’ choices was fairly high (Mp.80). On average, participants made 156 acquisitions per choice set with an average time per acquisition of .21 seconds, and they spent 32% of their time acquiring information on the most im-portant attribute. In addition, participants generally pro-cessed information by attribute rather than by alternative (Mp⫺.53). A MANOVA on the seven dependent mea-sures reveals a significant effect of information structure (Wilks’slp.193 F(21, 172.8), p6.37 p, !.0001). A sep-arate MANOVA analysis shows a significant effect of the distribution of attribute levels (Wilks’slp.20 F(7, 16), p

, ) and the number of attribute levels (Wilks’s 8.98 p!.001

, , ), as well as a

signif-lp.12 F(7, 16)p16.99 p!.0001

icant interaction between attribute distribution and the number of attribute levels (Wilks’s lp.27 F(7, 16), p6.22 p, !

). .001

(9)

Decision Quality.

As in study 1, ANOVA results show that an increase in the amount of information in a choice set led to declines in decision quality: (M’sp.87, .80, .77, and .74) in the 17.39, 32.00, 49.56, and 64.00 bit conditions, respectively (F(3, 66)p6.48, p!.001). Trend analysis shows a significant linear effect for information structure (F(1, 22)p13.73 p, !.001). Higher-order effects were not significant. Support was found for hypothesis 1a, that the even distribution of attribute levels lowers decision quality relative to the uneven distribution of attribute levels (M’sp.77 and .82; F(1, 22)p30.29 p, !.0001, 2

h p

p

), as well as hypothesis 1b, that an increase in the number .58

of attribute levels lowers decision quality (M’sp.76 and

.84;F(1, 22) , , 2 ). The interaction

be-p9.34 p!.01 hpp.30

tween attribute distribution and the number of attribute lev-els was not significant (F(1, 22)p.65, NS).

Acquisitions.

The ANOVA results show that increasing amounts of information generally increased the time per acquisition (M’sp.199, .214, .211, and .220) in the 17.39, 32.00, 49.56, and 64.00 bit conditions, respectively (F(3, 66)p7.80 p, !.0001) and decreased the number of acquisitions (M’sp168.5, 164.8, 149.0, and 141.3) in the 17.39, 32.00, 49.56, and 64.00 bit conditions, respectively (F(3, 66)p8.65 p, !.0001). Trend analysis shows signif-icant linear effects for time per acquisition (F(1, 22)p

, ) and the number of acquisitions 18.44 p!.0001

(F(1, 22)p24.36 p, !.0001). Higher-order effects were not significant. Support was found for hypothesis 3a, that the even relative to the uneven distribution of attribute levels increases the average time per acquisition (M’sp.217and .205; F(1, 22)p11.88 p, !.01, 2 ), and marginal

h p.35

p

support was found for hypothesis 3b, that the even distri-bution of attribute levels lowers the number of acquisitions (M’sp153.1 and 158.8; F(1, 22)p2.51 p, !.07 [one-tailed], 2 ). Support was found for hypotheses 4a and

hpp.10

4b, that increasing the number of attribute levels from two to four increases the average time per acquisition (M’sp

and .205; , , 2 ) and

.216 F(1, 22)p10.56 p!.01 h p.32

p

decreases the number of acquisitions (M’sp145.2 and 166.7;F(1, 22)p17.92 p, !.001, 2 ).

h p.45

p

Processing Selectivity.

Results show that increasing amounts of information generally led to an increase in the proportion of time spent on the most important attribute (M’sp.31, .28, .34, and .35) in the 17.39, 32.00, 49.56, and 64.00 bit conditions, respectively (F(3, 66)p3.15, ), increased variance in the proportion of time spent

p!.05

per attribute (M’sp.0062, .0080, .0114, and .0085) in the 17.39, 32.00, 49.56, and 64.00 bit conditions, respectively (F(3, 66)p5.91 p, !.001), and increased variance in the proportion of time spent per alternative (M’sp.0004, .0005, .0005, and .0009) in the 17.39, 32.00, 49.56, and 64.00 bit conditions, respectively (F(3, 66)p5.14 p, ! ). Mixed support was found for hypothesis 5a, that the .01

even distribution of attribute levels increases processing se-lectivity. The even relative to the uneven distribution of attribute levels does not have a significant effect on the

proportion of time spent on the most important attribute (M’sp.31and .33;F(1, 22)p1.66, NS) or the variance in time spent per attribute (M’sp.0083 and .0088; , NS), but does significantly increase the

var-F(1, 22)p.36

iance in time spent per alternative (M’sp.0007and .0004; Support was found for

2

F(1, 22)p7.05, p!.01,h p.24).

p

hypothesis 5b, that increasing the number of attribute levels increases processing selectivity. In particular, increasing the number of attribute levels increases the proportion of time spent on the most important attribute (M’sp.34 and .30; , , 2 ), increases the variance

F(1, 22)p7.98 p!.01 hpp.27

in time spent per attribute (M’sp.0100 and .0071; , , 2 ), and increases the

var-F(1, 22)p8.87 p!.01 h p.29

p

iance in time spent per alternative (M’sp.0007and .0005;

, , 2 ).

F(1, 22)p5.82 p!.05 hpp.21

Acquisition Pattern.

Although participants generally processed by attribute in all conditions, the pattern of acqui-sitions differed across conditions (M’sp⫺.62,⫺.44,⫺.54, and⫺.53) in the 17.39, 32.00, 49.56, and 64.00 bit conditions, respectively (F(3, 66)p16.77 p, !.0001). The even relative to the uneven distribution of attribute levels leads to relatively greater processing by alternative (M’sp⫺.49 and ⫺.58; , , 2 ). The number of

at-F(1, 22)p26.94 p!.001 hpp.55

tribute levels has no significant effect on acquisition pattern (M’sp⫺.54and⫺.53;F(1, 22)p.20, NS).

Additional Analysis: Amount of Information

Experi-enced.

To examine how information structure affects the amount of information actually experienced by the decision maker, two additional measures of processing were exam-ined.1The first is the percentage of unique cells (out of the

128 available) that were examined. The second is the per-centage of unique cells multiplied by the amount of infor-mation available in each choice set. The ANOVA results show that increasing amounts of information led to a de-crease in the percentage of unique cells examined (M’sp

, 51%, 47%, and 46%) in the 17.39, 32.00, 49.56, and 54%

64.00 bit conditions, respectively (F(3, 66)p12.51 p, ! ) but an increase in the amount of information expe-.0001

rienced (M’sp9.44bits, 16.18 bits, 23.12 bits, and 29.57 bits) in the 17.39, 32.00, 49.56, and 64.00 bit conditions, respectively (F(3, 66)p269.40 p, !.0001). The even rel-ative to the uneven distribution of attribute levels decreased the percentage of unique cells examined (M’sp48%and 51%; , , 2 ) and increased the

F(1, 22)p6.08 p!.03 hpp.22

amount of information experienced (M’sp22.88bits and

16.28 bits; , , 2 ).

Sim-F(1, 22)p342.06 p!.0001 hpp.94

ilarly, an increase in the number of attribute levels decreased the percentage of unique cells examined (M’sp46%and 52%;F(1, 22)p19.64 p, !.0001, 2 ) and increased

h p.47

p

the amount of information experienced (M’sp26.34bits

and 12.81 bits; , , 2 ).

F(1, 22)p306.31 p!.0001 hpp.93

(10)

Discussion

Results from study 2 provide additional support for the idea that information structure affects information overload and that structural elements, such as the number and dis-tribution of attribute levels, can affect decision quality even if the number of alternatives and attributes in a choice set are held constant. Study 2 also provides insight into the process through which information structure affects decision quality. In particular, study 2 suggests that choice sets that contain more information per element are also associated with fewer acquisitions and more time per acquisition. Be-cause fewer information elements are acquired, decision-making quality declines. To the extent that choice sets that contain more information are also more diagnostic, these results are consistent with previous research that shows that increased diagnosticity lowers information acquisition (Van Wallendael and Guignard 1992). One explanation is that choice sets that contain more information decrease confi-dence thresholds or concern about conficonfi-dence thresholds. Future research should examine these possibilities by mea-suring choice confidence.

Study 2 also shows that increased amounts of information lead consumers to be more selective in their information acquisition (e.g., spend a larger proportion of time on the most important attribute). This means that they are less likely to process all of the information and therefore less likely to choose the best alternative in a set. Given that studies 1 and 2 show that information structure affects information over-load and information acquisition, it is important to examine potential moderators of the relationship among information structure, the amount of information processing, and infor-mation overload.

STUDY 3: SIMULATION

Previous research has shown that the impact of the num-ber of alternatives and numnum-ber of attributes on decision effort without time pressure and decision quality under time pressure depends on the decision strategy used. In particular, Monte-Carlo simulations have shown that an increase in the number of alternatives and attributes in a choice set has a more dramatic impact on information acquisition and de-cision quality for compensatory dede-cision rules than non-compensatory decision rules (Payne et al. 1993).

At the same time previous simulation research on decision strategies has not examined the effect of information struc-ture, including the number and distribution of attribute lev-els, on decision effort and decision quality. In previous stud-ies, the number of attribute levels has equaled the number of alternatives, and attribute levels have been evenly dis-tributed across alternatives (Bettman et al. 1993; Creyer et al. 1990; Johnson and Payne 1985; Payne et al. 1988).

To explore further the potential relationship among in-formation structure, inin-formation processing, and decision making, a Monte-Carlo experimental simulation (Hastie and Stasser 2000; Payne et al. 1993) was conducted. In study 2, the effects of information structure on decision quality

and information acquisition (i.e., consumers’ adaptive be-havior) were measured. In the simulation, decision processes were manipulated explicitly through the decision rules of an idealized consumer, and the amount of information cessing was measured through elementary information pro-cesses (EIPs; Payne et al. 1988). This allows the interaction between information structure and decision processes to be examined.

Method

Procedure and Experimental Variables.

The infor-mation structure was manipulated through the number of alternatives (eight or 16), the number of attributes (four or eight), the number of attribute levels (two or four), and the distribution of attribute levels across alternatives (even or uneven). Unlike previous simulation research (Bettman et al. 1993; Creyer et al. 1990; Payne et al. 1988), the number of attribute levels was manipulated independently rather than being equal to the number of alternatives. When there were two attribute levels, two values were randomly chosen for each attribute from a uniform distribution ranging from zero to 1,000. When there were four attribute levels, four values were randomly chosen for each attribute. Attribute levels were randomly permutated across alternatives for each at-tribute. Attribute weights were randomly generated from a uniform distribution ranging from zero to one and normal-ized to sum to one (Johnson and Payne 1985; Payne et al. 1988).

When attribute levels were evenly distributed, each at-tribute level occurred the same number of times. When two attribute levels were unevenly distributed, three-quarters of the alternatives had one level of an attribute and one-quarter of the alternatives had the other level. When four attribute levels were unevenly distributed, five-eighths of the alter-natives had the first level, one-eighth had the second level, one-eighth had the third level, and one-eighth had the fourth level. In the uneven condition, the best alternative shared the same attribute level as the majority of alternatives for one-half of the attributes and the same attribute level as the minority of alternatives for one-half of the attributes. Mean interattribute correlations were not significantly different in the even (Mp⫺.038) and uneven (Mp⫺.034) distri-bution conditions (F(1, 2,398)p1.02, NS). As in study 2, the manipulations of the number of attribute levels and the distribution of attribute levels are nonorthogonal since they cannot be changed independently from one another. This means that the impact of these variables should be inter-preted in terms of their combined effect on information structure.

To study how information structure affects the relation-ship between the amount of information processing (EIPs) and decision quality, time pressure was manipulated at two levels. In the no-time-pressure condition, no limit was placed on the number of EIPs used in choice. In the time-pressure conditions, decision rules were constrained to 64 EIPs. This limit, based on previous research (Payne et al. 1988), was

(11)

12.5% of the maximum number of EIPs required for the weighted additive model with no time pressure. Note that, as in previous research, the time-pressure condition assumes that any given EIP (e.g., a read) takes the same amount of time regardless of information structure. Results from study 2 question this assumption.

Five decision strategies (WADD, LEX, SAT, EBA, and MCD) were applied to each information environment (John-son and Payne 1985; Payne et al. 1988). Based on prelim-inary simulation runs, cutoff levels of 300 and 500 were set for the satisficing (SAT) and elimination by aspects (EBA) rules, respectively. The experimental manipulations created 160 experimental cells per simulation run. Based on the size of previous simulations (Johnson and Payne 1985; Payne et al. 1988), the simulation was run 50 times to create 8,000 observations.

Dependent Variables

Amount of Information Processing.

The amount of information processing was measured as the sum of EIPs—reads, products, additions, comparisons, differences, and eliminations (Johnson and Payne 1985; Payne et al. 1988).2

Choice Quality.

Choice quality was measured as the utility of the chosen alternative relative to the expected value of random choice, where the expected value of random choice is the average utility of all alternatives in the choice set (Johnson and Payne 1985; Payne et al. 1988). This scale equals one if the best alternative is chosen and zero for random choice.

Results

Amount of Information Processing.

The ANOVA re-sults from the no-time-pressure condition show that an in-crease in the amount of information in a choice set inin-creased the number of EIPs (Bp5.72 F(1, 3,990); p1,582.01, , 2 ). There was also a main effect of

deci-p!.0001 hpp.28

sion strategy on the number of EIPs (F(4, 3,990)p44.10, , 2 ) as well as a significant interaction

p!.0001 hpp.04

between the amount of information in the choice set and

decision strategy ( , , 2

F(4, 3,990)p302.07 p!.0001 hpp

). An increase in the number of alternatives increased EIPs .23

(M’sp102.04and 197.80) in the eight- and 16-alternative conditions, respectively (F(1, 3,920)p26,339.51, p!

, 2 ) as did an increase in the number of at-.0001 hpp.87

tributes(M’sp106.06and 193.78) in the four- and eight-attribute conditions, respectively (F(1, 3,920)p22,100.27, , 2 ). The even distribution of attribute levels

p!.0001 hpp.85

slightly increased the number of EIPs to the uneven condition (M’sp150.59 and 149.24; F(1, 3,920)p5.24 p, !.03, ). An increase in the number of attribute levels

2

h p.001

p

slightly decreased the number of EIPs(M’sp150.62 and

2Weighting EIPs by response times (Bettman et al. 1990) led to similar

results.

149.22) in the two-level and four-level conditions,

respec-tively ( , , 2 ).

F(1, 3,920)p5.66 p!.02 hpp.001

The significant interaction between the distribution of at-tribute levels and decision strategy (F(4, 3,920)p6.67, , 2 ) shows that decision strategy moderates

p!.001 h p.007

p

the effect of the distribution of attribute levels on EIPs. The even distribution of attribute levels raised the number of EIPs for the MCD strategy (M’sp246.41 and 253.37; , , 2 ) but had no

sig-F(1, 3,920)p27.81 p!.0001 hpp.007

nificant effect on the LEX (M’sp76.45 and 74.41; , NS), SAT ( and 51.13; F(1, 3,920)p2.40 M’sp49.42 , NS), EBA ( and 87.07; F(1, 3,920)p1.69 M’sp86.95 , NS), or WADD strategies ( F(1, 3,920)p.01 M’sp

and 287.00; , NS) in the uneven 287.00 F(1, 3,920)p.00

and even distribution conditions, respectively.

The significant interaction between the number of attri-bute levels and decision strategy (F(4, 3,920)p71.82, , 2 ) shows that decision strategy also

p!.0001 hpp.068

moderates the effect of the number of attribute levels on EIPs. In particular, an increase in the number of attribute levels raised the number of EIPs for the MCD strategy (M’sp243.45 and 256.33; F(1, 3,920)p95.26, p! , 2 ) and lowered the number of EIPs for the .0001 hpp.024

LEX strategy (M’sp84.63 and 66.23; F(1, 3,920)p

, , 2 ) in the two- and four-level 194.44 p!.0001 hpp.047

attribute conditions, respectively. The number of attribute levels marginally increased EIPs for the SAT strategy

and 49.15; , ,

(M’sp51.40 F(1, 3,920)p2.91 p!.09 ) and had no significant effect on the EBA

2

hpp.001

(M’sp87.63and 87.39;F(1, 3,920)p.33, NS) or WADD strategies (M’sp287.00 and 287.00; F(1, 3,920)p.00, NS) in the two-level and four-level attribute conditions, respectively.

Decision Quality.

The simulation assumes, as in pre-vious research (Bettman et al. 1990; Johnson and Payne 1985; Payne et al. 1988), that any given EIP takes the same amount of time regardless of information structure. Under this as-sumption, ANOVA results show that an increase in the amount of information lowered decision quality under time pressure (Bp⫺.00074 F(1, 3,990); p34.67 p, !.0001, ). There was also a significant effect of decision

2

h p.009

p

strategy on relative decision quality (F(4, 3,990)p28.50, , 2 ) as well as a significant

interac-p!.0001 h p.028

p

tion between information structure and decision strategy (F(4, 3,990)p5.71, p!.001, 2 ). An increase

h p.006

p

in the number of alternatives lowered decision quality (M’sp.49 and .38) in the eight- and 16-alternative conditions, respectively (F(1, 3,920)p44.82 p, !.0001, ) as did an increase in the number of

attri-2

hpp.011

butes (M’sp.53and .34) in the four- and eight-attribute conditions, respectively (F(1, 3,920)p136.46 p, !.0001, ). The even distribution of attribute levels

in-2

h p.034

p

creased relative decision quality (M’sp.41and .45) in the uneven and even attribute distribution conditions, respec-tively (F(1, 3,920) , , 2 ) when EIPs

p6.32 p!.02 hpp.002

were constrained. An increase in the number of attribute levels also increased relative decision quality (M’sp.39

(12)

and .47) in the two- and four-level attribute conditions,

re-spectively ( , , 2 ).

F(1, 3,920)p24.21 p!.0001 hpp.006

The significant interaction between the number of attrib-ute levels and decision strategy (F(4, 3,920)p3.80 p, ! , 2 ) shows that decision strategy also moderates .01 h p.004

p

the effect of the number of attribute levels on decision qual-ity. In particular, an increase in the number of attribute levels raised decision quality for the MCD (M’sp.27 and .42; , , 2 ) and the EBA

F(1, 3,920)p15.39 p!.0001 hpp.004

strategies (M’sp.30 and .47; F(1, 3,920)p19.36 p, !

, 2 ) in the two- and four-attribute-level con-.0001 hpp.005

ditions, respectively. An increase in the number of attribute levels marginally increased decision quality for the LEX strategy (M’sp.56 and .63; F(1, 3,920)p3.37 p, !.07, ) but had no significant effect on the SAT

2

hpp.001

(M’sp.26 and .30; F(1, 3,920)p1.23, NS) or WADD strategies (M’sp.56 and .55; F(1, 3,920)p.07, NS) in the two- and four-level attribute conditions, respectively. The interaction between the distribution of attribute levels and decision strategy was not significant (F(4, 3,920)p

, NS). .56

Mediation Analysis.

Using the corresponding EIP counts from the no-time-pressure condition to predict decision quality under time pressure, in a model that controls for de-cision strategy, shows a significant effect of EIPs (Bp

⫺.00094; F(1, 3,994)p92.08 p, !.0001, 2 ). As

h p.023

p

mentioned above, a separate analysis shows a significant ef-fect of information structure on decision quality under time pressure (Bp⫺.00074 F(1, 3,990); p34.67 p, !.0001, ). When EIPs are added as a covariate to this

2

hpp.009

model, the effect of information structure on choice quality is no longer significant (Bp.0056 F(1, 3,989); p.12, NS), but EIPs remain significant (Bp⫺.0011 F(1, 3,989); p

, , 2 ). These results show that the 77.15 p!.0001 hpp.019

amount of information processing (EIPs) without time pres-sure perfectly mediates the relationship between information structure and decision quality under time pressure (Baron and Kenny 1986).

Discussion

Results from the simulation provide additional insights into the relationship among information structure, infor-mation processing, and decision making. Like the experi-mental studies, the simulation shows that increased amounts of information I(A) lead to declines in decision quality. The simulation also shows that the relationship between infor-mation structure and inforinfor-mation overload depends on the decision rule used, with information structure having a greater effect under certain decision rules (e.g., MCD) than others (e.g., WADD). Despite these differences, increasing amounts of information led to significant declines in decision quality under time pressure regardless of the rule used.

More important, the simulation helps explain the rela-tionship among information structure, the amount of infor-mation processing (EIPs), and inforinfor-mation overload. In par-ticular, greater amounts of information lead to greater

information processing, which in turn lead to greater de-clines in decision quality under time pressure. By showing that EIPs mediate the relationship between information structure and decision quality, the simulation helps explain the process through which changes in information structure can lead to information overload.

GENERAL DISCUSSION

Almost 30 years ago, William Wilkie (1974, p. 465) noted that “information itself has not been carefully defined for the consumer environment. . . . Clearly, however, market-ing research will have to grapple with this zone of inquiry in the future.” Now, in the age of the Internet, developing an understanding of how information-rich environments af-fect consumer decision making is of crucial importance. Given the disparate ways in which information can be pre-sented to consumers and the high potential for information overload in online environments, it is important to use mea-sures that capture the multiple dimensions of information. Structural measures of information, such as those from in-formation theory, offer a way to capture these dimensions and predict information overload more effectively. A struc-tural approach suggests that the number of alternatives and attributes in a choice set are just two potential determinants of the amount of information in a choice set. Other dimen-sions, such as the number of attribute levels and the distri-bution of those levels across alternatives, can also play an important role in determining the amount of information associated with a set of alternatives.

Importantly, structural measures of information encom-pass the frequency-based approaches traditionally used in marketing but also provide different predictions than tra-ditional approaches. Contrary to what is found by merely counting the number of alternatives and attributes in an information environment, accounting for the distribution and number of attribute levels suggests that more alternatives do not necessarily mean more information. Study 1 exam-ines the potential benefits of using formal measures of in-formation structure by creating conditions that replicate pre-vious findings, in which more alternatives lead to declines in decision quality, but also by creating conditions in which the same increase in the number of alternatives does not lead to overload. Results of this study contradict previous studies (e.g., Jacoby et al. 1974a, 1974b; Keller and Staelin 1987; Malhotra 1982; Scammon 1977) that suggest that the probability of overload can only increase for choice sets with more alternatives (attributes), when the number of at-tributes (alternatives) is held constant.

Study 2 provides additional insights into the relationship between information structure and information overload by measuring information acquisition as well as decision qual-ity. In particular, study 2 shows that consumers adapt their acquisition of information in response to changes in mation structure. When a choice set contains more infor-mation per element, fewer acquisitions are made, more time is spent per acquisition, and consumers are more selective in their information acquisition. Study 2 also shows that a

(13)

change in information structure that increases the amount of information in a choice set can lead to declines in decision quality—even if there is no change in the number of at-tributes or alternatives.

Study 3, a Monte-Carlo simulation, helps illustrate the link among information structure, the amount of information processing, and decision quality by applying different de-cision rules to multiple information environments. Results from this study show that information structure affects in-formation processing (EIPs) and decision quality, but that these effects depend on which decision strategy is used. More importantly, study 3 shows that increasing the amount of information in a choice set leads to increased information processing (EIPs), and this increase in processing mediates the relationship between information structure and infor-mation overload. As such, this series of studies builds an important conceptual link between research on information overload (Jacoby et al. 1974a, 1974b; Keller and Staelin 1987; Malhotra 1982) and research on decision processes (Bettman et al. 1990; Creyer et al. 1990; Johnson and Payne 1985; Payne et al. 1988).

In addition to linking related streams of research, this article provides novel insights that can inform researchers who are interested in decision outcomes as well as those who are interested in decision processes. For example, nei-ther of these streams of research has considered how struc-tural elements, such as the number and distribution of at-tribute levels, affect decision outcomes or processes. This research suggests that these elements should be considered, particularly in environments in which information overload is likely. For those who are interested in decision outcomes, results from this research question the assumption that more alternatives necessarily mean more information and a greater likelihood of information overload. Similarly, results from study 2, in which increased amounts of information were found to increase time per acquisition, bring into question the assumption that processing speeds are constant for a given EIP within a given environment (Bettman et al. 1990; Johnson and Payne 1985; Payne et al. 1988).

Before discussing future research, it is important to point out the limitations of this research. It should be noted that these findings are from studies that experimentally control for multiple environmental and individual factors that may affect information overload in real choice settings. For ex-ample, in order to control for experience effects, novel stim-uli and environments were used. In the real world, decision makers often draw on their knowledge of product categories. Product category experience and expertise may change con-sumers’ processing of information and affect the extent to which they are overloaded with information (Alba and Hutchinson 1987). In addition, the convenience samples used in this research are by no means representative of the U.S. population as a whole. At the same time, product cat-egories were chosen to be of interest to participants, and the participants were provided with financial incentives to make good choices. The congruent results across the three studies,

two experiments, and simulation provide additional confi-dence in the results.

There are a number of potential avenues for future re-search, including an examination of mechanisms for reduc-ing information overload, as well as research that examines the potential impact of information overload on the quality of consumers’ lives (Mick 2003). Other research could

References

Related documents

• An approximately $130 million impact related to the timing of expected cash flow in the MS business prior to the completion of the sale of the business on January 31 st ;

• AECOM reiterated its fiscal 2020 financial guidance, including its expectation for adjusted EBITDA 1 between $720 million and $760 million and for free cash flow 6 between

Consistent with its previously-announced restructuring actions that are expected to deliver at least 210 basis points of adjusted operating margin expansion in the DCS segment

The Company believes that non-GAAP financial measures such as adjusted EPS, adjusted EBITDA, adjusted net/operating income, adjusted tax rate, adjusted interest expense,

“We delivered 17% adjusted EBITDA growth in the second quarter and 16% adjusted EBITDA growth in the first half of the fiscal year, which reflects strong execution on our $225

In particular, the Company believes that non-GAAP financial measures such as adjusted EPS, adjusted EBITDA, adjusted operating income, adjusted tax rate, adjusted interest

In particular, the Company believes that non-GAAP financial measures such as adjusted EPS, adjusted EBITDA, adjusted operating income, adjusted tax rate, adjusted interest

In particular, the Company believes that non-GAAP financial measures such as adjusted EPS, adjusted EBITDA, adjusted operating income, adjusted tax rate, adjusted interest