• No results found

3 Price Discrimination

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Share "3 Price Discrimination"

Copied!
10
0
0

Loading.... (view fulltext now)

Full text

(1)

There is no universally accepted definition for price discrimination (PD). In most cases, you may consider PD as: producers sell two units of the same physical good at different prices (, either to the same consumer or to different consumers.) Note that:

• There is no PD if the price difference reflects the costs of serving;

• One cannot infer PD does not happen when differentiated products are sold to different consumers.

It is useful to classify, according to Pigou (1920), price discriminations by first, second, and third degree PD:

• First degree (1) PD: producers capture the whole consumer surplus;

• Second degree (2) PD: in the case of incomplete information, producers use selfse- lection devices to extract consumer surplus;

• Third degree (3) PD: there exist direct signals about demands, and producers use this signal to price-discriminate.

(2)

3.1 First degree (Perfect) PD

One necessary condition for the 1 PD is complete information: producers know the de- mands. Given this, how can a monopolistic producer engage in 1 PD? Consider a market with n identical consumers and (market) demand function D(p). Denote the inverse demand as: p = P (q).

• The monopoly can offer a tariff T (q) such that:

T (q) =

⎧⎪

⎪⎩ Z q

0 P (x)dx/n − Z q

0

P (x)dx/n

if q = qc/n otherwise, where > 0, and qcis the competitive market demand.

• Consider an affine pricing schedule (or a two-part tariff): T (q) = A + pq. Note that when A = 0, T (q) is a linear tariff. Let Sc=

Z qc

0 [P (x) − pc]dx, and offer:

T (q) =

⎧⎨

Sc/n + pcq 0

if q > 0 if q = 0, where pc is the competitive market demand.

• When consumers have different demands:

T (q) =

⎧⎨

Sic+ pcq 0

if q > 0 if q = 0.

• No that 1 PD has the same price and quantity as in perfect competition.

(3)

3.2 Third degree (multimarket) PD

Based on some direct signal (exogenous information), a producer can divide consumers into m groups. It is then as if there are m “independent” markets. Note that for the markets to be truly independent, we need to assume:

• No arbitrage between groups;

• The producer cannot price discriminate within the group.

Hence the monopolistic producer charges a linear tariff for each group. That is, the monopoly solves:

p1,pmax2,...,pm

Xm

i=1piDi(pi) − C³Xm

i=1Di(pi)´ .

Recall the multiproduct monopoly’s problem (independent demands, separable costs), we know that pi are determined according to the inverse elasticity rule:

pi− C0(q) pi

= 1 εi

, where εi = −Di0(pi)pi/Di(pi).

• Some examples:

— Low-price discount to first time magazine subscribers;

— Student and senior citizen discounts;

— Legal and medical service bills;

— Goods in poor countries that do not reflect transportation costs and import taxes, etc.

• Compared to uniform pricing in all markets, 3 PD makes the monopoly and con- sumers in high-elasticity markets better off, while it makes consumers in the low- elasticity markets worse off. How about total social surplus? Let C³X

iqi

´

= c ·³X

iqi´

, and consumer surplus Si(pi) = R

p Di(x)dx. We can write the change

(4)

in social surplus when monopoly practices 3 PD with {p1, ..., pm} and uniform price with p:

∆W =X

i[Si(pi) − Si(p)] +X

i(pi− c)qi−X

i(p − c)qi. Note that:

Si(pi) ≥ Si(p) + S0i(p)(pi− p), since: Si00(·) = −D0i(·) > 0, or S(·) is convex. Hence,

Si(pi) − Si(p) ≥ −qi[pi− c − (p − c)], or,

Si(pi) − Si(p) + (pi− c)qi− (p − c)qi≥ (pi− c)qi− (pi− c)qi = (pi− c)∆qi. Hence, we have the lower bound for the social surplus change:

∆W ≥X

i(pi− c)∆qi. Similarly,

Si(p) ≥ Si(pi) + Si0(pi)(p − pi), following the same reasoning, we have the upper bound:

∆W ≤X

i(p − c)∆qi.

• Thus, a necessary condition for the 3 PD to be preferred socially is that it raises total output. The elimination of the 3 PD can be dangerous if it reduces outputs significantly (for example, it leads to the closure of markets). Sometimes it can be a win-win situation (Pareto improvement) to allow firms to price-discriminate.

(5)

3.3 Second degree PD (arbitrage and screening)

Note that the absence of direct signals empowers consumers with the ability to engage in personal arbitrage. Perfect PD is, in general, not possible. However, even when there is no exogenous information (direct signals) for the monopolistic producer to tell the consumers apart, a monopoly can still extract some consumer surplus. Let’s first go through a common way of 2 PD — the two-part tariff.

3.3.1 Two-part tariffs

A two-part tariff, T (q) = A + pg, offers a (continuum) menu of bundles {T, q} located on a straight line. Uniform pricing is a special case of two-part tariff when A = 0. Suppose the consumers have the following preferences:

U =

⎧⎨

θV (q) − T 0

if she pays T for quantity q otherwise;

where: V (0) = 0, V0(·) > 0, and V00(·) < 0. Let V (q) = 1−(1−q)2 2 and there be two groups of consumers: one with taste parameter θ1 and the other taste parameter θ2. Let the fraction of consumers with θ = θ1 be λ, and θ1 < θ2. The monopolistic producer has a constant marginal cost c < θ1. Solving the consumer’s problem:

maxq . θiV (q) − (A + pq), we have:

qi = Di(p) = 1 − p/θi, and consumer surplus Si(p) except for T as:

Si(p) = θiV (Di(p)) − pDi(p) = (θi− p)2i

. The aggregate demand at price p can be expressed as:

D(p) = λD1(p) + (1 − λ)D2(p)

= 1 − p[λ/θ1+ (1 − λ)/θ2]

≡ 1 − p/eθ.

(6)

• Perfect PD: charging a price p1 = c and Ai= i−p)2

i . Hence profit Π1: Π1 = λ(θ1− c)2

1 + (1 − λ)(θ2− c)22

.

— This is the highest profit that a monopoly can get;

— Welfare is optimal.

• Monopoly pricing (linear tariff): the monopoly solves:

maxp . (p − c)D(p).

And, the monopoly price is: p2 = (c + eθ)/2.

— The monopoly may want to give up consumers with lower θ, and serves only θ2 consumers. This cannot be optimal if:

D1(c + θ2 2 ) ≥ 0, or,

θ1≥ c + θ2 2 . Let’s assume this inequality holds.

• Two-part tariff: A = S1(p). Now, the monopoly solves:

maxp . S1(p) + (p − c)D(p).

And, the monopoly price is: p3 = cθ1/(2θ1− eθ).

Compare these results, we have:

Π1 ≥ Π3 ≥ Π2, and (under the assumption: θ1≥ (c + θ2)/2),

c = p1< p3< p2.

Note again, ignoring the redistributive concerns, welfare (social surplus) is higher under the two-part tariff than that of the linear one, because: the marginal price is lower.

(7)

• In general, for any linear tariff T (q) = pq with p > c, there exists a two-part tariff T (q) = ee A +pq such that, if consumers are offered the choice between T and ee T , both types of consumers as well as the monopoly are made better off.

— As it turns out it is tricky to demonstrate this algebraically. We’ll get into the idea in just a minute. For now, a figure helps a lot...

— Consider c <p < p, and ee A = (p − ep)D2(p).

— Type-θ1 consumers prefer the linear tariff, while type-θ2 consumers choose the two-part tariff. The change in the monopoly’s profit (from type-θ2 consumers) is:

(1 − λ)[ eA +pDe 2(p) − pDe 2(p) − c(D2(p) − De 2(p))]

= (1 − λ)[ep(D2(p) − De 2(p)) − c(D2(p) − De 2(p))]

= (1 − λ)(ep − c)(D2(p) − De 2(p)) > 0.

3.3.2 Tie-in Sales and 2 PD

Consider a consumer who enjoys one unit of basic (tying) good together with q complemen- tary (tied) goods, and derive surplus: θV (q) − T (q). The producer produces the basic good at cost c0, and the complementary good at cost c per unit. Note that c0 becomes a fixed cost per customer served. It plays no role in the pricing decision of the complementary good.

• Suppose tie-in sales are not allowed, and there are competitive firms willing to provide the complementary good at price c. If the producer serves both types of customers, it sets the price of the basic good to S1(c), the surplus of the type-θ1 consumers.

• If tie-in sales are allowed, we have already shown that the producer would charge a price p > c for the complementary good, and S1(p) < S1(c) for the basic good.

But note that: here, the tie-in sale reduces welfare as long as the producer serves both types of consumers. But the prohibition of tied-in sales may result in only type-θ2consumers

(8)

are served (if (1 − λ)S2(c) ≥ S1(c)). In this case, tie-in sales are not necessary detrimental.

3.3.3 Non-linear tariffs

Again, studying a figure helps us to draw the following conclusions:

1. Type-θ1 (low-demand) consumers derive no net surplus; type-θ2 (high-demand) con- sumers derive a positive surplus;

2. The incentive compatibility (personal-arbitrage) constraint for the high-demand consumers are binding;

3. The high-demand consumers purchase the social optimal quantity, q2 = D2(c); the low-demand consumers purchase a suboptimal quantity, q1 < D1(c). This is the so-called “absence of distortion at the top”.

• The monopoly’s profit is:

Πm= λ(T1− cq1) + (1 − λ)(T2− cq2).

It chooses two bundles: (T1, q1) and (T2, q2) to maximize Πm. There are two kinds of constraints:

— IR: θ1V (q1)−T1 ≥ 0. The IR (individual rationality) constraints require the con- sumers to buy. Note that if the IR constraint for type-θ1 consumers is satisfied, type-θ2 consumers are automatically willing to buy, because: they can always choose to buy q1 at T1 and get net surplus θ2V (q1) − T1 > 0.

— IC: θ2V (q2) − T2 ≥ θ2V (q1) − T1. The IC (incentive compatibility) constraints are used to prevent personal arbitrage (type-θ2 consumers choose the bundle designed for type-θ1 consumers). Since the idea is to induce type-θ2 consumers to “reveal” their high demands, thus, the IC constraint for type-θ1 consumers is most likely irrelevant (not binding). We can proceed taking into account only type-θ2 consumers’ IC constraint and check later if the IC constraint for type-θ1 consumers is satisfied.

(9)

• When Πm is maximized, it must be the case that both constraints (the IR of type-θ1 and the IC of type-θ2) are binding; i.e., T1 = θ1V (q1), and θ2V (q2)−T2= θ2V (q1)−T1. Hence,

T2 = θ2V (q2) − θ2V (q1) + T1= θ2V (q2) − (θ2− θ1)V (q1).

— Observe that: Type-θ1 consumers surplus is entirely appropriated;

— Note also, T2 < θ2V (q2) so that type-θ2 consumers enjoy net surplus: (θ2 − θ1)V (q1) > 0.

• Using T1 and T2, we can write down the monopoly’s problem as:

max

(q1,q2)λ[θ1V (q1) − cq1] + (1 − λ)[θ2V (q2) − (θ2− θ1)V (q1) − cq2].

The FOCs are: ⎧

θ1V0(q1) = c/³

1 −1−λλ θ2θ−θ1 1´

; θ2V0(q2) = c.

• Observe that: 0 < 1−1−λλ θ2θ−θ1 1 < 1 when: λ ∈ (θ2θ−θ2 1, 1). Hence, as long as both types of consumers are served (λ is not too small), θ1V0(q1) > c (the quantity consumed by type-θ1 consumers is suboptimal).

• Note also: the FOCs ⇒ V0(q1) > V0(q2), since V (·) is concave, we have q1< q2.

• Finally, check the IR constraint for type-θ1 consumers. θ1V (q2) − T2 = θ1V (q2) − θ2V (q2) + (θ2− θ1)V (q1) = (θ2− θ1)[V (q1) − V (q2)] < 0 = θ1V (q1) − T1.

(10)

3.3.4 Quality Discrimination

So far, we consider the monopoly discriminates among consumers with different tastes by offering different quantities of the same good at different prices. The same analysis applies to the situation that the monopoly discriminates among consumers with different tastes for quality by offering different qualities at different prices.

Consumers have preference U = θs − p (if buying), where: s is the quality, and p = p(s).

The producer produces s with cost c(s), where: c(·) is increasing and convex.

• Let q ≡ c(s): the cost of quality s;

• Let V (q) ≡ c−1(q) = s: the quality obtained at cost q.

Then,

U = θV (q) − p(V (q)) = θV (q) − ep(q),

where: p(q) ≡ p(V (q)). Moreover, by construction, the monopoly’s cost function is lineare in q. Therefore, it should be clear now that quality discrimination is identical to the above analysis. The monopolistic producer uses lower-quality goods as a market-segmentation device.

References

Related documents

We describe a message authentication algorithm, UMAC, which authenticates messages (in software, on contemporary machines) roughly an order of magnitude faster than current

Analysis of the effect of skewness on traffic delays was based on the commercial simulation model of intersections known as aaSIDRA [8]. The studied signalised

The esterase gene is part of the complex class 1 integron containing the Asian rifampin resistance gene, arr-2, which is also contained as a gene cassette (17).. If this structure

For a systematically selected subsample of 385, we estimated travel time from their homes to the facility using the cost- friction surface approach, Open Source Routing Machine

Regulatory review for the single-mode microwave cavity “is going to be filed as a normal heat process,” says Dunne, and will be subject to the same microbiological validation as

Pentru a putea folosi dispozitivul securizat Aladdin e-Token pe care se află certificatul digital calificat (utilizat pentru crearea semnăturii electronice extinse), trebuie

The academic admissions process, when measured against the current trend to seek national recognition for academic elite status, reveals the inconsequential nature

Solid fence with no gaps.. If room permits, an air conditioning barrier could be a cost effective option. In order for this to be effective, the barrier must block line of sight