• No results found

Is Inflation Persistence Over?

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Is Inflation Persistence Over?"

Copied!
40
0
0

Loading.... (view fulltext now)

Full text

(1)
(2)

ISSN 1518-3548 CGC 00.038.166/0001-05

(3)

Working Paper Series

Edited by Research Department (Depep) – E-mail: workingpaper@bcb.gov.br Editor: Benjamin Miranda Tabak – E-mail: benjamin.tabak@bcb.gov.br Editorial Assistant: Jane Sofia Moita – E-mail: jane.sofia@bcb.gov.br

Head of Research Department: Adriana Soares Sales – E-mail: adriana.sales@bcb.gov.br The Banco Central do Brasil Working Papers are all evaluated in double blind referee process. Reproduction is permitted only if source is stated as follows: Working Paper n. 230.

Authorized by Carlos Hamilton Vasconcelos Araújo, Deputy Governor for Economic Policy.

General Control of Publications

Banco Central do Brasil Secre/Surel/Cogiv

SBS – Quadra 3 – Bloco B – Edifício-Sede – 1º andar Caixa Postal 8.670

70074-900 Brasília – DF – Brazil

Phones: +55 (61) 3414-3710 and 3414-3565 Fax: +55 (61) 3414-3626

E-mail: editor@bcb.gov.br

The views expressed in this work are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the Banco Central or its members.

Although these Working Papers often represent preliminary work, citation of source is required when used or reproduced.

As opiniões expressas neste trabalho são exclusivamente do(s) autor(es) e não refletem, necessariamente, a visão do Banco Central do Brasil.

Ainda que este artigo represente trabalho preliminar, é requerida a citação da fonte, mesmo quando reproduzido parcialmente.

Consumer Complaints and Public Enquiries Center

Banco Central do Brasil Secre/Surel/Diate

SBS – Quadra 3 – Bloco B – Edifício-Sede – 2º subsolo 70074-900 Brasília – DF – Brazil

Fax: +55 (61) 3414-2553

(4)

Is Inflation Persistence Over?

Fernando N. de Oliveira

*

Myrian Petrassi

Abstract

The Working Papers should not be reported as representing the views of the Banco Central do Brasil. The views expressed in the

papers are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect those of the Banco Central do Brasil.

We analyze inflation persistence in several industrial and emerging countries in the recent past by estimating reduced-form models of inflation dynamics. We select a very representative group of 23 industrial and 17 emerging economies. Our sample period is comprised of quarterly data and starts in the first quarter of 1995. Our results show that inflation persistence is low and stable for all countries in our sample. It seems to be lower in industrial relative to emerging countries. Finally, even countries that have had “hyperinflation” experience in the recent past showed low levels of inflation persistence, albeit apparently higher than the other countries in our sample.

Keywords: Inflation, Persistence, Hyperinflation JEL Classification: E3, E30, E31

*

Research Department, Banco Central do Brasil. E-mails: fernando.nascimento@bcb.gov.br and myrian.petrassi@bcb.gov.br

(5)

1 Introduction

One of the most important characteristics of the dynamics of inflation is its degree of persistence. It is related to how quickly inflation reverts to its initial level after a shock. As Mishkin (2007) points out, if inflation is persistent, it increases the costs of monetary policy (in terms of product or unemployment) to keep inflation under control.1

In the last years, both industrial and emerging economies have experienced important changes in the degree of their inflationary persistence. As Cechetti et al show (2007) both the volatility and level of inflation has decreased in industrial economies. In these economies the decades of 1960 and 1970 were considered periods of high and persistent inflation, while the more recent decades, 1990 and 2000, have low levels of inflation as well as low persistence.

Contrary to industrial countries, emerging economies have experienced high levels of inflations for a longer period. Some of these countries, such as Brazil, Argentina, Bolivia, Peru, Mexico, Israel, Poland and Turkey, have had periods of “hyperinflation” in the last thirty years.2Only recently, in the decade of 1990, the levels of inflation have started to decrease in these countries. This, in part, is due to the important changes in the conduct of their macroeconomic policies.3 However, it is not clear if the decrease of the level of inflation has been accompanied by a reduction of their inflationary persistence. 4

Our objective in this paper is to analyze empirically the inflation persistence of several industrial and emerging countries in the recent past. We selected a very representative group of 23 industrial and 17 emerging economies. We want to answer the following questions: Is inflation persistence low for both industrial and emerging economies? Has

1

In a more formal way, we can define inflation persistence as the propensity of inflation to converge slowly towards its long run equilibrium following a shock that has taken inflation away from this equilibrium.

2

Sometimes is hard to define if an inflationary process experienced by a country is a “hyperinflation” episode. That is why we have decided to use it between commas.

3

As examples of some macroeconomic policies we can list: inflation targeting adoption, reduction of budget deficits, improvement of financial regulation, trade liberalization and flexible exchange rate policies among others.

4

See Stock and Watson (2003) for a brief analysis of monetary policy in some industrial countries in the last years.

(6)

persistence been stable throughout our sample period for all countries? Is inflation persistence in countries that have experienced “hyperinflation” in the recent past higher than the ones observed in the other countries?5

Our results show that inflation persistence is low and has been stable for both industrial and emerging economies in general. We observe that persistence seems to be lower in industrial economies relative to emerging ones. We also show that even economies that had experience “hyperinflation” in the near past have low inflation persistence nowadays, albeit apparently higher than the ones observed in the other countries of our sample. One explanation for this is that inflationary memory can be still alive amongst the economic agents.

To obtain our results we estimate several reduced form inflation dynamics. We estimate the following types of models: models with lags of inflation with and without GDP gap; new Keynesian Phillips curves with foreign exchange rates; and models that are reduced-form inflation dynamics of structural models that incorporate some form of wage rigidity in the spirit of Blanchard and Gali (2005). Our sample period starts in the first quarter of 1995. We have quarterly data and use headline consumer inflation as our measure of inflation. 6

This finding of a low and stable persistence parameter for a great number of different countries may be somewhat surprising considering the obvious relevance of Lucas (1976) critique for our exercise. However, it is consistent with recent evidence for the United States as Rudebusch (2005) shows. Rudebusch estimates a new Keynesian Phillips curve to show that the parameters of reduced form regression will tend to be relatively stable even in the presence of realistic changes in monetary policy rules.

5

Our sample of emerging economies is Argentina, Brazil, Bolivia, Chile, Colombia, Czech Republic, Hungary, Israel, Korea, Mexico, Peru, Philippines, Poland, South Africa, Slovak Republic, Thailand, and Turkey. Our sample of industrial countries is: Austria, Australia, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Iceland, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Luxembourg, Netherlands, Norway, New Zealand, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, United Kingdom and United States.

6

Various factors can explain persistence: persistence may be inherited from persistent fluctuations in the determinants of inflation, like marginal cost or output gap (this is called extrinsic persistence); the dependence of inflation on its own past, also called intrinsic persistence and persistence due to the formation of inflation expectations. Each one of this persistence can be associated with one of the three terms of a new Keynesian Phillips curve.

(7)

For many of the countries we considered, substantial shifts in monetary policy have occurred over the past two decades. In the case of European countries the introduction of the Euro is a very important milestone. In the case of emerging economies, we can cite more sound macroeconomic policies including, for many of them, the choice of inflation targeting as a framework for monetary policies. Therefore, one of our key approaches was to allow for the possibility of structural breaks in the inflation dynamics in order to avoid spurious estimates of degree of persistence.

We observe that there is very little instability in the parameters of inflation persistence for most of the economies we study. We did several tests of stability and also recursive least squares estimation. Our full sample estimation of the persistence parameter is in general far away from 1 and stable as the results from unknown break points are consistent with the null hypothesis of no change over time in the persistence of inflation. Overall, our results are in accordance with a stable reduced-form representation for inflation and a low level of inflation persistence.

Our results are consistent with a vast literature that shows that inflation persistence has decreased, such as: Dossche and Everaert (2005), Taylor (1999), Altissimo et al (2006), Benati (2008) and Batini (2002). Our paper, however, contributes to the literature by looking at a greater and more diversified group of countries, including several emerging ones, by considering a more recent period and by estimating various inflation dynamics specifications.

Other papers look at how inflation persistence has evolved over a longer period of time also estimating reduced form inflation processes. For example, Mishkin (2007) studies inflation persistence in the United States in the last 40 years using auto regressive models and decomposing inflation in cycle and trend as in Stock and Watson (2006). Mishkin confirms the results of Stock and Watson (2006), showing that inflation persistence is decreasing worldwide since the 1990s, compared with persistence observed in the 1960 and 1970s.7

7

Stock and Watson (2006) show the inflation dynamic in the United States is well described by several latent factors, such as cycle and trend, both with stochastic volatility. Cycle is a stationary process while trend in non-stationary. Inflation persistence is described as a trend. The authors show that persistence in inflation has decrease substantially in the United States in the last decade.

(8)

Nason (2006) describes the dynamics of inflation in the United States with several different models of inflation and confirms the results of Mishkin (2007) and Stock and Watson (2006) that inflation persistence is decreasing in the United States in the last years. Rudd and Whelan (2005) estimate a new Keynesian hybrid Phillips curve with lags in inflation and show that inflation in the United States is much more forward looking than backward looking, that shows that inflation persistence is decreasing. Fuhrer (2005) also models inflation using a hybrid Keynesian Phillips curve. He separates persistence in two types: one related to the dynamics of the output gap and the other to marginal cost and that depends on lags of inflation. Fuhrer shows that the more relevant part of inflation in the last years is due to intrinsic inflation and not to output gap.

An important explanatory factor behind this low level and stability of inflation persistence in the recent past is the anchoring of inflation expectations of economic agents. By conducting monetary policies such that inflation expectations of economic agents are anchored, the central banks can ensure that actual inflation does not deviate for too long and in a very persistent way from its medium term objective. We believe that long-term inflation expectations have been successively anchored in the recent years and, as a result, inflation expectations are much less dependent on past inflation. Also, actual inflation developments are less persistent.

The rest of the paper is the following. Section 2 describes the data. Section 3 presents the empirical analysis. Section 4 concludes.

2. Data

Our data is quarterly and starts in the first quarter of 1995. It is composed by 40 countries: 23 industrial and 17 emerging. Our data source was International Financial Statistics from International Monetary Fund. Our measure of inflation is headline CPI inflation. We also use as exogenous the following variables: the nominal foreign exchange rate and the GDP gap, that is the difference between nominal GDP and potential GDP obtained through Hodrick-Prescott filtering.

For the purpose of our analysis, we separate our sample of countries in three groups: one group is comprised of industrial countries (Austria, Australia, Belgium, Canada,

(9)

Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Iceland, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Luxembourg, Netherlands, Norway, New Zealand, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, United Kingdom and United States), emerging countries that did not experienced “hyperinflation” in the recent past (Chile, Colombia, Czech Republic, Hungary, Korea, Philippines, South Africa, Slovak Republic and Thailand), and emerging economies that have had “hyperinflation”, such as Argentina, Brazil, Bolivia, Peru, Mexico, Turkey, Israel and Poland.

Table 1 shows descriptive statistics of inflation for our economies: emerging (total), emerging with “hyperinflation” experience and industrial economies. We can see that average quarterly inflation in emerging market (EM) economies was 1.84% and average standard deviation was 0.018. As far as GDP gap is concerned, average GDP gap is -0.14%.

Table 1 column 2 shows descriptive statistics of inflation for the group of emerging economies that has had some “hyperinflation” episode in the last thirty years. We can see that average inflation was 2.32% and average standard deviation was 0.022. Average output gap was -0.30% in this subgroup. Column 3 shows us that in non-emerging countries of our sample, average inflation was only 0.54%. Average output gap, in other hand, was greater: -0.01%.

It is clear from Table 1 that inflation is higher in emerging economies that have had “hyperinflation” in the recent past. The average inflation in these economies was 1 pp. higher than average inflation in the emerging economies that did not experience “hyperinflation” and 1.78 pp. higher than industrial economies that also did not experience “hyperinflation”. Not only average, but also volatility is much higher than non-emerging countries and also non-hyperinflation ones.

In the next section, we will present our empirical analysis based on the estimation of reduced form inflation dynamics for these groups of countries.

(10)

3. Empirical Analysis

3.1 Traditional Models of Inflation

The overall degree of inflation persistence can be measured in several ways. The results reported in this section are based on the methods that are most frequently used in the literature. In order to show how fast inflation returns back to its mean following a disturbance, or its persistence, we measure the dependence of inflation on its past values.

The most obvious way of measuring inflation persistence is to regress inflation on several of its lags as in equation (1) and then calculate the sum of coefficients on lagged inflation. If the sum of coefficients is close to 1, then shocks to inflation have long lived effects on inflation. The higher the sum of the coefficients of inflation lags, the longer it takes for inflation to return back to its mean. In other words, inflation behaves like a random walk so that when inflation goes up it stays up. If the sum of coefficients is well below 1 then a shock to inflation has only temporary effect on inflation and inflation soon reverts to its trend level.

(1) 2 2 1 1 0 βπ φ π ε , [ε ] 0,var(ε ) σε β π = + +

+ = = = − − t t t L k k t k t t E ,

where πt is headline consumer inflation .

To the extent that lagged inflation captures true persistence in the price setting process the model implies that rapid reductions of inflation can only be produced at the cost of substantial increase in unemployment or decrease in product. Hence, the model points to a gradualist approach as providing the best way to effect a large reduction in inflation.

An equivalent approach for analyzing persistence (and the one we will follow in this paper) is to estimate ρ in equation (2) as O´Reilly and Whelan (2005) show.

(2) 2 2 1 0 ρ π φ π ε , [ε ] 0,var(ε ) σε β π = + +

Δ + = = = − − t t t L k k t k t t E .

(11)

There are a number of good reasons for focusing on ρ as our main measure of inflation persistence. For example, in this model, ρ is a crucial determinant of the response to shocks over time. It can also be shown that 1/(1-ρ) gives the infinite-horizon cumulative impulse response to shocks. Moreover, an advantage of focusing on the estimate of ρ rather than on sum of coefficients is that the first one remains pertinent even when the underlying process contains a unit root or is explosive.

We chose the number of lags of first difference of headline consumer inflation in (2) so as the residuals do not present serial correlation, using LM test to identify serial correlation. We also checked for heteroskedasticity with White and Breush-Pagan. If there is evidence of heteroskedasticity, we correct it with the Newey-West robust errors. We did a Wald test of ρ=1 for all estimations of the traditional models and we rejected ρ=1 for all estimations. We also compared the average of the persistence coefficient of inflation of the three groups by doing Wald tests in a system of equations estimated with OLS in which each equation is the same one we estimated individually.

It is also crucial from an econometric point of view to allow for structural breaks in the dynamics of inflation. Otherwise, we could be estimating biased and inconsistent coefficients. We test for breaks using different methods, such as Andrews-Quandt and Chow. We found indication of structural breaks for some countries: Argentina, Austria, Greece and Poland. We then choose some possible breakpoints with the Chow test. We changed the specification including dummies as regressors or interacting them with the lag of inflation regressors. Our results did not change with these new specifications.

In Graph 1, we show the recursive least squares estimations for the inflation persistence coefficient (ρ) in (2): emerging countries that have had high inflation episodes and those that had not and 10 (from 23) industrial countries. Inflation persistence for all countries seems to be stable, especially after 2003. Emerging countries appear to have inflation persistence that fluctuates around 0.5 while industrial countries persistence appears to fluctuate around zero.

Table 2 (column 1) shows the estimated ρ for this specification. The average persistence coefficient was 0.15 and Turkey has the largest one: 0.879. Emerging market economies

(12)

seem to have, on average, greater coefficients: 0.45 compared to -0.07 of the industrial economies. Also, “hyperinflation” EM countries seem to have even larger persistence. Considering only these countries increases persistence coefficient to 0.59. The average persistence of EM economies that do not experience hyperinflation also seems to be greater than industrial countries (0.33 compared to -0.07).8

We repeated the estimation above including in equation (2) the output gap calculated using Hodrick-Prescot filter.9 The results are very similar to the ones described above (see Table 2 column 2). Again, economies that had “hyperinflation” episodes in the recent past showed greater average as well as greater volatility of inflation persistence.

If inflation has indeed become less persistent because monetary policy has anchored inflation expectations more solidly the monetary authorities may find they have less need to induce large swings in economic activity to control inflation. This is a key benefit of establishing a strong nominal anchor. If this is correct, cyclical movements in interest rates need not be as great as it was necessary when expectations are anchored. To try the capture this possibility we will estimate in the following section new Keynesian models of inflation that incorporate inflation expectations.

3.2 New Keynesian Models Estimation

The most important implication of the pure new Keynesian model of inflation is that there is no intrinsic persistence in inflation in the sense that there is no structural dependence of inflation on its own lagged values. Instead, inflation is determined in a completely forward-looking manner. One implication of this model in contrast to traditional ones is that it is much easier to quickly reduce inflation in this model than in the traditional one. In fact, according to the new Keynesian model, inflation can be costless controlled by a credible commitment to keep output close to its potential.

8

We compared the average of persistence coefficient of the three groups by doing Wald tests in a system of equations estimated with OLS in which each equation is the same one we estimated individually. 9

Again, we tested for serial correlation, heteroskedasticity, structural breaks and compared the statistical differences of averages of the inflation persistence coefficient of different groups. We did once more a Wald test of ρ=1 for all estimations of the traditional models with GDP gap. We rejected ρ=1 for all estimations.

(13)

It has been shown that in economies where central banks have adopted explicit inflation objectives, long-term inflation expectations are not related to past inflation. In this context, central bank transparency is crucial. In such a setting, agents will try to disentangle persistent shifts in inflation objective from transitory disturbances and will manage to do so more quickly the more transparent and credible the central bank is. 10

Due to the difficulty of fitting the data with new Keynesian pure forward-looking model, a vast literature that incorporates lags of inflation in the new Keynesian Phillips curve (NKPC) has emerged11. For many, this class of models represents a sort of common-sense middle ground that preserves the insights of standard rational expectations models while allowing for better empirical fit by dealing directly with a well known deficiency of the pure forward looking model of inflation. As a result this class of models has been widely used in applied monetary policy analysis.

The structural equation for inflation that we estimate is in the spirit of hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve as in (3). These models add a dependence of inflation on its lagged values to otherwise purely forward looking models. Such models are often considered as a compromise between the need for rigorous micro foundations of the sort underlying the pure new-Keynesian Phillips curve and the need to fit the data empirically.

(3) 1 2 1 2 1 1 ) var( , 0 ] [ , ] [ ) 1 ( ε σ ε ε ε γ β π ρ ρπ π = = + + + − + = + t t t t t t t t t E X h E where ht is

output gap and Xt is foreign exchange rate.

The parameter that measures inflation persistence is

ρ

. We estimated equation (3) above, using lags of consumer headline inflation as instruments. We also checked for serial correlation with LM test and for heteroskedasticity with White test. In the presence of serial correlation, we included more lags of regressors, until there is no more evidence of serial correlation. In the presence of heteroskedasticity, we corrected

10

The most popular formulation of the new Keynesian framework is based on Calvo (1983) model of price random adjustment. The model assumes that in each period a random fraction of firms reset their price while all other firms keep their prices unchanged. Calvo assumes an imperfectly competitive market structure as well. These two hypotheses generate the basic new Keynesian model of inflation.

11

See Fuhrer and Moore (1995), Gali and Gertler (1999) and Christiano et al (2005) for some theoretical models that justify the inclusion of lags of inflation in the new Keynesian Phillips curves.

(14)

with Newey-West robust matrix. We, again, compared the statistical differences of averages of the inflation persistence coefficient of different groups.

Table 2 column 3 shows the estimated ρ. The average persistence estimator was 0.009, and the standard deviation was 0.43. The country with the highest average was Hungary while the one with the lowest was Portugal. Considering our 3 groups, emerging economies that did not experience “hyperinflation” had an average persistence estimator of 0.03. Within the industrial economies group, the average coefficient was -0.095. The country with the highest persistence was Italy.

Considering countries that experienced “hyperinflation”, the highest persistence was from Poland (0.62) while the one with the lowest was Turkey (-0.18). The average of this group was 0.26.

In Graph 2, we show the recursive least squares estimations for the inflation persistence coefficient (ρ) in NKPC. Again, emerging market economies appear to have higher levels of persistence. And countries that had a “hyperinflation” history have an even higher persistence level.

As we can see these results do not differ from the estimation of the more traditional models presented in section 3.1. Once again, higher inflation in the past implies higher persistence of inflation in the present.

In the next section, we will include wage rigidity in the new Keynesian framework in line with Blanchard and Gali (2005). The objective is to see if there is a change in estimated persistence due to these rigidities.

3.3 New Keynesian Models Estimation with Wage Rigidities

Blanchard and Gali (2005) incorporate wage rigidities in the structural model of inflation. The reduced form equation that results from their structural model is equation (4) below. Note that this equation is very similar to the hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curves specification used in many empirical and policy analysis applications and that

(15)

allows for both backward looking and forward looking inflation terms (with coefficients whose sum is close to one). In our model the relative weight of lagged inflation is tightly linked to the degree of real wage rigidities. The novelty is the inclusion of the first difference of lagged output gap. This is the result of wage rigidity and makes the divine coincidence - where the central bank stabilizing inflation also stabilizes the welfare relevant gap - not possible anymore. The

ρ

coefficient continues to measure inflation persistence. Gali and Blanchard show that this coefficient is an increasing function of wage rigidity.

(4) 2 1 2 1 1 1 1 (1 ρ) [π ] β β ε , [ε ] 0,var(ε ) σε ρπ πt = t− + − Et t+ + ht− + Δht− + t E t = t =

Table 2 (column 4) shows the estimated ρ for this specification. The average persistence coefficient was 0.16 and Netherlands has the highest one: 1.124. Emerging market economies that experienced hyperinflation in the recent past seem to have greater coefficients on average: 0.289 compared to 0.134 of the industrial economies.

For all estimations we tested for structural breaks using Andrews-Quandt Chow and recursive least squares. No breaks were observed in the estimated processes. We did once more a Wald test of ρ=1 for all estimations. We rejected ρ=1 for almost all economies with the exception of Netherlands. We, again, compared the statistical differences of averages of the inflation persistence coefficient of different groups with a system of equations approach.

Another implication of Blanchard and Gali (2005) model is the relation between inflation and unemployment as in equation (5). As Mishkin (2007) points out when researchers estimate this equation they typically find that the coefficients on the unemployment gap have declined in the absolute value since the 1980s often by a marked amount. In other word, the evidence suggests that the Phillips curve has flattened.

(5) πt =ρπt1+(1−ρ)Ett+1]+β1ut1t,Et]=0,var(εt)=σε2

Table 2 (column 5) shows the estimated ρ for this specification. The average persistence coefficient was 0.246 and Spain has the highest one: 2.921. Emerging market

(16)

economies that experienced hyperinflation in the recent past once again seem to have greater coefficients on average: 0.453 compared to 0.23 of the industrial economies.

For all estimations we test for structural breaks using Andrews-Quandt, Chow and recursive least squares. We did not observe any break in any of the processes we estimated. Wald tests rejected ρ=1 for almost all economies with the exception of Ireland and Spain.

As we can see, once again the results for both models of wage rigidities are similar to the ones of traditional and hybrid new Keynesian models. There is clear evidence that persistence is higher and more volatile in emerging economies that had “hyperinflation” than in the rest of our sample.

4. Conclusion

We analyzed inflation persistence in several industrial and emerging countries in the recent past by estimating various reduced-form models of inflation. Our results show that inflation persistence is low and stable, albeit lower for the former than for the latter. We also show that even countries that experienced “hyperinflation” in the recent past showed low levels of persistence but still have higher levels than the other countries in our sample. Overall, our results are consistent with a stable reduced-form representation for inflation and a low level of inflation persistence worldwide.

In interpreting our results, we must first recognize that all of them are based on reduced-from relationships. Thus, they are about correlations and not necessarily about true structural relationships. Explanatory variables in our inflation estimations are themselves influenced by changes in economic conditions. So, changes in the underlying monetary policy regime are likely to be a source changes in reduced-form inflation dynamics. This problem is especially acute for structural relationship involving expectations or other factors that are not directly observable and so cannot be included in reduced form regressions. In such cases, we cannot use the reduced form equations to disentangle the effects of such unobserved factors which themselves may be driven by changes in monetary policy from that of other influences.

(17)

Mishkin (2007) makes it clear that inflation expectations must be a key driving force behind inflation. This dependence has long been implicit in traditional Phillips curve analysis but now expectations are explicit and are also a central feature of new Keynesian Phillips curves in which current period inflation is a function of expectations next period and output gap.

Anchoring of inflation expectations must be related to monetary policy. During the past years most central banks have increased their commitment to price stability in both words and action. The Federal Reserve, the European Central Bank and several central banks of emerging economies have been committed to keep inflation under control. The result has been low and stable inflations but also, as we report in this paper, low and stable inflation persistence.

The pursuit of more aggressive monetary policy to control inflation and the achievement of anchored inflation help explain in part our results. With expectations of inflation anchored the sacrifice ratio becomes lower and monetary policy much more effective to improve the welfare of the economy.

(18)

References

Altissimo, Filippo, Ehrmann, Michael and Smets, Frank (2006). ”Inflation Persistence and Price-Setting Behavior in the Euro Area. A Summary of the IPN Evidence.” European Central Bank. Occasional Paper Series, No. 46, June.

Batini, N. “Euro Area Inflation Persistence”(2002). ECB Working paper No 201.

Benati, Luca. ”Investigating Inflation Persistence Across Monetary Regimes”(2008). Quarterly Journal of Economics, 123, No 3, 1005-1060.

Blanchard, Olivier and Gali, Jordi (2005). “Real Wage Rigidities and the New Keynesian Model”. Conference on Quantitative Evidence of Price Determination, Washington D.C., September, 29-30.

Calvo, Guilherme. “Staggered Prices in a Utility Maximizing Framework” (1983). Journal of Monetary Economics, 12, 383-398.

Cechetti, G. Stephen and Hooper, Peter and Kasman, C. Bruce and Schoenholtz, L. Kermit and Watson, W. Mark (2007). “Understanding the Evolving Inflation Process”. U.S. Monetary Policy Forum, Brandeis University, February.

Christiano, Lawrence, Einchenbaum, Martin and Charles, Evans (2005). “ Nominal Rigidities and the Dynamics Effects of Shocks to Monetary Policy”. Journal of Political Economy, 113, 1-45.

Dossche, M. and Everaert, G. (2005). “Measuring Inflation Persistence.A Structural Time Series Approach”. ECB Working Paper No 495.

Fuhrer, C. Jeffrey (2005). “Intrinsic and Inherited Inflation Persistence”. Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, Working Paper Series Federal No 05.

---, Moore, George (1995). “Inflation Persistence”. Quartely Journal of Economics, 110, 127-159.

Gali, Jordi, Gertler, Mark and Lopes-Salido, David (2001). “European Inflation Dynamics’. European Economic Review, 45,1237-1270.

--- and Gertler, Mark (1999). “A Structural Econometric Analysis”. Journal of Monetary Economics, 44, 195-222.

Lucas, Robert (1976). “Econometric Policy Evaluation: A Critique”. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 1, 19–46.

Mishkin, S. Frederick (2007). “Inflation Dynamics”. Working Paper Series National Bureau of Economic Research, NBER, No 13147.

Nason, M. Jason (2006). “Instability in U.S. Inflation:1967-2005”. Working Paper Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta.

Rudd, Jeremy and Whelan, Karl (2005). “Modelling Inflation Dynamics: A Critical Review of Recent Research”. Working Paper Series Federal Reserve Board.

Rudebusch, Glenn (2005).”Assessing the Lucas Critique in Monetary Policy Models”. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 37, 245-272.

Stock, H. James and Watson, W. Mark (2006). “Why Has U.S. Inflation Become Harder to Forecast?” Working Paper Series National Bureau of Economic Research, NBER, no 12324.

(19)

---(2003). “Has the Business Cycle Changed? Evidence and Explanations”. Federal Reserve of Kansas City Symposium on Monetary Policy and Uncertainty, August, 28-30.

Taylor, J (1999). “Staggered Price and Wage Setting in Macroeconomic”. Taylor and Woodford (Editors), Handbook of Macroeconomics, vol 1.b. North-Holland.

O´Reilly, Gerald and Whelan, Karl (2005). “Has Euro-Area Inflation Persistence Changed Over Time?”. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 87(4), 709-720, November.

(20)

Table 1: Descriptive Statistics – Inflation and Output Gap

Non - Emerging Market Countries Total "Hyperinflation" Experience Total

Average Inflation 1.84% 2.32% 0.54%

Average Standard Deviation 0.018 0.022 0.006

Maximum Inflation 19.43% 19.43% 5.55%

Minimum Inflation -4.10% -1.42% -3.99%

Average Output Gap -0.14% -0.30% -0.01%

Emerging Market Countries

(21)

Table 2: Estimated Inflation Persistence Parameters

Equation (2) Equation (2) Equation (3) Equation (4) Equation (5)

AR(p) Including Output Gap NKPC NKPC including Gap (-1) Output Gali and Gertler -With Unemployment

Argentina 0.479 0.428 0.296 0.412 0.539 Austria 0.123 (0.149) (0.018) 0.146 (0.102) Australia 0.250 0.282 0.018 0.125 0.065 Belgium (0.265) (0.397) 0.198 (0.051) 0.118 Bolivia 0.581 0.596 (0.026) 0.070 -Brazil 0.416 0.426 0.441 0.509 0.503 Canada (0.805) (0.883) 0.021 0.067 0.157 Chile 0.435 0.288 0.073 0.101 -Colombia 0.825 0.782 0.408 0.481 0.445 Czech Republic 0.404 0.508 (0.079) (0.221) 0.124 Denmark (0.199) (0.184) 0.147 0.140 0.229 Finland (0.038) (0.095) (0.126) 0.600 0.050 France (0.250) (0.357) 0.147 (0.150) 0.317 Germany 0.068 (0.057) (0.188) 0.148 0.036 Greece 0.393 (1.431) - - -Hungary 0.657 0.656 0.641 0.596 0.714 Iceland 0.577 0.568 (0.387) (0.270) -Ireland 0.297 0.141 - - 0.601 Israel 0.366 0.381 0.158 (0.071) -Italy 0.095 (0.046) 0.481 0.399 -Japan (0.343) (0.473) 0.370 0.292 0.323 Korea (0.284) (0.416) (1.008) (0.464) (0.641) Luxembourg 0.177 0.068 (0.049) 0.406 0.036 Mexico 0.704 0.783 0.534 0.455 -Netherlands 0.409 (0.082) (0.523) 1.124 (0.739) Norway (0.504) (0.599) 0.173 0.119 0.187 New Zealand 0.319 0.123 0.260 0.347 0.263 Peru 0.601 0.617 0.229 0.245 -Phillipines 0.136 0.183 0.158 0.138 -Poland 0.661 0.659 0.616 0.591 0.547 Portugal (0.340) (0.101) (1.058) (0.397) -South Africa 0.290 (0.071) (0.099) (0.134) 0.397 Slovak Republic 0.347 0.007 (0.127) (0.116) (0.180) Spain (0.385) (0.394) (0.906) 0.103 2.921 Sweden 0.115 (0.040) 0.045 0.112 (0.304) Switzerland (0.383) (0.436) (0.934) (0.834) (0.396) Thailand 0.134 (0.263) 0.316 0.312 0.350 Turkey 0.879 0.864 (0.177) 0.100 0.224 United Kingdom (0.110) (0.250) 0.170 0.224 0.437 United States (0.817) (1.337) 0.166 0.154 0.172

(22)

Graph 1 Stability of Persistence Parameters Modeling Inflation as an

ARMA Process

Emerging Economies – with “hyperinflation”

-2 -1.5 -1 -0.5 0 0.5 1 1.5 1998Q 3 1999Q 1 1999Q 3 2000Q 1 2000Q 3 2001Q 1 2001Q 3 2002Q 1 2002Q 3 2003Q 1 2003Q 3 2004Q 1 2004Q 3 2005Q 1 2005Q 3 2006Q 1 2006Q 3 2007Q 1 2007Q 3 2008Q 1 2008Q 3 2009Q 1

Argentina Brazil Bolivia Israel Mexico Peru Poland Turkey

Emerging Economies – without “hyperinflation”

-3.5 -2.5 -1.5 -0.5 0.5 1.5 199 8Q 3 199 9Q 1 199 9Q 3 200 0Q 1 200 0Q 3 200 1Q 1 200 1Q 3 200 2Q 1 200 2Q 3 200 3Q 1 200 3Q 3 200 4Q 1 200 4Q 3 200 5Q 1 200 5Q 3 200 6Q 1 200 6Q 3 200 7Q 1 200 7Q 3 200 8Q 1 200 8Q 3 200 9Q 1

Chile Colombia Czech Rep. Hungary Korea Phillipines South Africa Thailand Slovak Rep.

(23)

Industrial Economies -2 -1 0 1 2 1999 Q 1 1999 Q 3 2000 Q 1 2000 Q 3 2001 Q 1 2001 Q 3 2002 Q 1 2002 Q 3 2003 Q 1 2003 Q 3 2004 Q 1 2004 Q 3 2005 Q 1 2005 Q 3 2006 Q 1 2006 Q 3 2007 Q 1 2007 Q 3 2008 Q 1 2008 Q 3 2009 Q 1

Australia Canada New Zealand Switzerland United Kingdom France Germany Italy Netherlands USA

Graph 2 – Stability of Persistence Parameters Modeling Inflation as a

New Keynesian Phillips Curve

Emerging Economies – with “hyperinflation”

-1 -0.5 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 1998Q 3 1999Q 1 1999Q 3 2000Q 1 2000Q 3 2001Q 1 2001Q 3 2002Q 1 2002Q 3 2003Q 1 2003Q 3 2004Q 1 2004Q 3 2005Q 1 2005Q 3 2006Q 1 2006Q 3 2007Q 1 2007Q 3 2008Q 1 2008Q 3 2009Q 1

Argentina Brazil Bolivia Israel Mexico Peru Poland Turkey

(24)

Emerging Economies – without “hyperinflation” -1.5 -1 -0.5 0 0.5 1 1998Q 3 1999Q 1 1999Q 3 2000Q 1 2000Q 3 2001Q 1 2001Q 3 2002Q 1 2002Q 3 2003Q 1 2003Q 3 2004Q 1 2004Q 3 2005Q 1 2005Q 3 2006Q 1 2006Q 3 2007Q 1 2007Q 3 2008Q 1 2008Q 3 2009Q 1

Chile Colombia Czech Rep. Hungary Korea Phillipines South Africa Thailand Slovak Rep.

Industrial Economies -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 1996 Q3 1997 Q2 199 8Q1 199 8Q4 1999 Q3 2000 Q2 2001 Q1 2001 Q4 200 2Q3 200 3Q2 200 4Q1 2004 Q4 2005 Q3 2006 Q2 2007 Q1 200 7Q4 200 8Q3

Austria Bélgium Denmark Finland France

(25)

Banco Central do Brasil

Trabalhos para Discussão

Os Trabalhos para Discussão podem ser acessados na internet, no formato PDF, no endereço: http://www.bc.gov.br

Working Paper Series

Working Papers in PDF format can be downloaded from: http://www.bc.gov.br

1 Implementing Inflation Targeting in Brazil

Joel Bogdanski, Alexandre Antonio Tombini and Sérgio Ribeiro da Costa Werlang

Jul/2000

2 Política Monetária e Supervisão do Sistema Financeiro Nacional no Banco Central do Brasil

Eduardo Lundberg

Monetary Policy and Banking Supervision Functions on the Central Bank

Eduardo Lundberg

Jul/2000

Jul/2000

3 Private Sector Participation: a Theoretical Justification of the Brazilian Position

Sérgio Ribeiro da Costa Werlang

Jul/2000

4 An Information Theory Approach to the Aggregation of Log-Linear Models

Pedro H. Albuquerque

Jul/2000

5 The Pass-Through from Depreciation to Inflation: a Panel Study

Ilan Goldfajn and Sérgio Ribeiro da Costa Werlang

Jul/2000

6 Optimal Interest Rate Rules in Inflation Targeting Frameworks

José Alvaro Rodrigues Neto, Fabio Araújo and Marta Baltar J. Moreira

Jul/2000

7 Leading Indicators of Inflation for Brazil

Marcelle Chauvet

Sep/2000

8 The Correlation Matrix of the Brazilian Central Bank’s Standard Model for Interest Rate Market Risk

José Alvaro Rodrigues Neto

Sep/2000

9 Estimating Exchange Market Pressure and Intervention Activity

Emanuel-Werner Kohlscheen

Nov/2000

10 Análise do Financiamento Externo a uma Pequena Economia

Aplicação da Teoria do Prêmio Monetário ao Caso Brasileiro: 1991–1998

Carlos Hamilton Vasconcelos Araújo e Renato Galvão Flôres Júnior

Mar/2001

11 A Note on the Efficient Estimation of Inflation in Brazil

Michael F. Bryan and Stephen G. Cecchetti

Mar/2001

12 A Test of Competition in Brazilian Banking

Márcio I. Nakane

(26)

13 Modelos de Previsão de Insolvência Bancária no Brasil

Marcio Magalhães Janot

Mar/2001

14 Evaluating Core Inflation Measures for Brazil

Francisco Marcos Rodrigues Figueiredo

Mar/2001

15 Is It Worth Tracking Dollar/Real Implied Volatility?

Sandro Canesso de Andrade and Benjamin Miranda Tabak

Mar/2001

16 Avaliação das Projeções do Modelo Estrutural do Banco Central do Brasil para a Taxa de Variação do IPCA

Sergio Afonso Lago Alves

Evaluation of the Central Bank of Brazil Structural Model’s Inflation Forecasts in an Inflation Targeting Framework

Sergio Afonso Lago Alves

Mar/2001

Jul/2001

17 Estimando o Produto Potencial Brasileiro: uma Abordagem de Função de Produção

Tito Nícias Teixeira da Silva Filho

Estimating Brazilian Potential Output: a Production Function Approach

Tito Nícias Teixeira da Silva Filho

Abr/2001

Aug/2002

18 A Simple Model for Inflation Targeting in Brazil

Paulo Springer de Freitas and Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos

Apr/2001

19 Uncovered Interest Parity with Fundamentals: a Brazilian Exchange Rate Forecast Model

Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos, Paulo Springer de Freitas and Fabio Araújo

May/2001

20 Credit Channel without the LM Curve

Victorio Y. T. Chu and Márcio I. Nakane

May/2001

21 Os Impactos Econômicos da CPMF: Teoria e Evidência

Pedro H. Albuquerque

Jun/2001

22 Decentralized Portfolio Management

Paulo Coutinho and Benjamin Miranda Tabak

Jun/2001

23 Os Efeitos da CPMF sobre a Intermediação Financeira

Sérgio Mikio Koyama e Márcio I. Nakane

Jul/2001

24 Inflation Targeting in Brazil: Shocks, Backward-Looking Prices, and IMF Conditionality

Joel Bogdanski, Paulo Springer de Freitas, Ilan Goldfajn and Alexandre Antonio Tombini

Aug/2001

25 Inflation Targeting in Brazil: Reviewing Two Years of Monetary Policy 1999/00

Pedro Fachada

Aug/2001

26 Inflation Targeting in an Open Financially Integrated Emerging Economy: the Case of Brazil

Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos

Aug/2001

27 Complementaridade e Fungibilidade dos Fluxos de Capitais Internacionais

Carlos Hamilton Vasconcelos Araújo e Renato Galvão Flôres Júnior

(27)

28 Regras Monetárias e Dinâmica Macroeconômica no Brasil: uma Abordagem de Expectativas Racionais

Marco Antonio Bonomo e Ricardo D. Brito

Nov/2001

29 Using a Money Demand Model to Evaluate Monetary Policies in Brazil

Pedro H. Albuquerque and Solange Gouvêa

Nov/2001

30 Testing the Expectations Hypothesis in the Brazilian Term Structure of Interest Rates

Benjamin Miranda Tabak and Sandro Canesso de Andrade

Nov/2001

31 Algumas Considerações sobre a Sazonalidade no IPCA

Francisco Marcos R. Figueiredo e Roberta Blass Staub

Nov/2001

32 Crises Cambiais e Ataques Especulativos no Brasil

Mauro Costa Miranda

Nov/2001

33 Monetary Policy and Inflation in Brazil (1975-2000): a VAR Estimation

André Minella

Nov/2001

34 Constrained Discretion and Collective Action Problems: Reflections on the Resolution of International Financial Crises

Arminio Fraga and Daniel Luiz Gleizer

Nov/2001

35 Uma Definição Operacional de Estabilidade de Preços

Tito Nícias Teixeira da Silva Filho

Dez/2001

36 Can Emerging Markets Float? Should They Inflation Target?

Barry Eichengreen

Feb/2002

37 Monetary Policy in Brazil: Remarks on the Inflation Targeting Regime, Public Debt Management and Open Market Operations

Luiz Fernando Figueiredo, Pedro Fachada and Sérgio Goldenstein

Mar/2002

38 Volatilidade Implícita e Antecipação de Eventos de Stress: um Teste para o Mercado Brasileiro

Frederico Pechir Gomes

Mar/2002

39 Opções sobre Dólar Comercial e Expectativas a Respeito do Comportamento da Taxa de Câmbio

Paulo Castor de Castro

Mar/2002

40 Speculative Attacks on Debts, Dollarization and Optimum Currency Areas

Aloisio Araujo and Márcia Leon

Apr/2002

41 Mudanças de Regime no Câmbio Brasileiro

Carlos Hamilton V. Araújo e Getúlio B. da Silveira Filho

Jun/2002

42 Modelo Estrutural com Setor Externo: Endogenização do Prêmio de Risco e do Câmbio

Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos, Sérgio Afonso Lago Alves e Gil Riella

Jun/2002

43 The Effects of the Brazilian ADRs Program on Domestic Market Efficiency

Benjamin Miranda Tabak and Eduardo José Araújo Lima

(28)

44 Estrutura Competitiva, Produtividade Industrial e Liberação Comercial no Brasil

Pedro Cavalcanti Ferreira e Osmani Teixeira de Carvalho Guillén

Jun/2002

45 Optimal Monetary Policy, Gains from Commitment, and Inflation Persistence

André Minella

Aug/2002

46 The Determinants of Bank Interest Spread in Brazil

Tarsila Segalla Afanasieff, Priscilla Maria Villa Lhacer and Márcio I. Nakane

Aug/2002

47 Indicadores Derivados de Agregados Monetários

Fernando de Aquino Fonseca Neto e José Albuquerque Júnior

Set/2002

48 Should Government Smooth Exchange Rate Risk?

Ilan Goldfajn and Marcos Antonio Silveira

Sep/2002

49 Desenvolvimento do Sistema Financeiro e Crescimento Econômico no Brasil: Evidências de Causalidade

Orlando Carneiro de Matos

Set/2002

50 Macroeconomic Coordination and Inflation Targeting in a Two-Country Model

Eui Jung Chang, Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos and Joanílio Rodolpho Teixeira

Sep/2002

51 Credit Channel with Sovereign Credit Risk: an Empirical Test

Victorio Yi Tson Chu

Sep/2002

52 Generalized Hyperbolic Distributions and Brazilian Data

José Fajardo and Aquiles Farias

Sep/2002

53 Inflation Targeting in Brazil: Lessons and Challenges

André Minella, Paulo Springer de Freitas, Ilan Goldfajn and Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos

Nov/2002

54 Stock Returns and Volatility

Benjamin Miranda Tabak and Solange Maria Guerra

Nov/2002

55 Componentes de Curto e Longo Prazo das Taxas de Juros no Brasil

Carlos Hamilton Vasconcelos Araújo e Osmani Teixeira de Carvalho de Guillén

Nov/2002

56 Causality and Cointegration in Stock Markets: the Case of Latin America

Benjamin Miranda Tabak and Eduardo José Araújo Lima

Dec/2002

57 As Leis de Falência: uma Abordagem Econômica

Aloisio Araujo

Dez/2002

58 The Random Walk Hypothesis and the Behavior of Foreign Capital Portfolio Flows: the Brazilian Stock Market Case

Benjamin Miranda Tabak

Dec/2002

59 Os Preços Administrados e a Inflação no Brasil

Francisco Marcos R. Figueiredo e Thaís Porto Ferreira

Dez/2002

60 Delegated Portfolio Management

Paulo Coutinho and Benjamin Miranda Tabak

(29)

61 O Uso de Dados de Alta Freqüência na Estimação da Volatilidade e do Valor em Risco para o Ibovespa

João Maurício de Souza Moreira e Eduardo Facó Lemgruber

Dez/2002

62 Taxa de Juros e Concentração Bancária no Brasil

Eduardo Kiyoshi Tonooka e Sérgio Mikio Koyama

Fev/2003

63 Optimal Monetary Rules: the Case of Brazil

Charles Lima de Almeida, Marco Aurélio Peres, Geraldo da Silva e Souza and Benjamin Miranda Tabak

Feb/2003

64 Medium-Size Macroeconomic Model for the Brazilian Economy

Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos and Sergio Afonso Lago Alves Feb/2003

65 On the Information Content of Oil Future Prices

Benjamin Miranda Tabak

Feb/2003

66 A Taxa de Juros de Equilíbrio: uma Abordagem Múltipla

Pedro Calhman de Miranda e Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos

Fev/2003

67 Avaliação de Métodos de Cálculo de Exigência de Capital para Risco de Mercado de Carteiras de Ações no Brasil

Gustavo S. Araújo, João Maurício S. Moreira e Ricardo S. Maia Clemente

Fev/2003

68 Real Balances in the Utility Function: Evidence for Brazil

Leonardo Soriano de Alencar and Márcio I. Nakane

Feb/2003

69 r-filters: a Hodrick-Prescott Filter Generalization

Fabio Araújo, Marta Baltar Moreira Areosa and José Alvaro Rodrigues Neto

Feb/2003

70 Monetary Policy Surprises and the Brazilian Term Structure of Interest Rates

Benjamin Miranda Tabak

Feb/2003

71 On Shadow-Prices of Banks in Real-Time Gross Settlement Systems

Rodrigo Penaloza

Apr/2003

72 O Prêmio pela Maturidade na Estrutura a Termo das Taxas de Juros Brasileiras

Ricardo Dias de Oliveira Brito, Angelo J. Mont'Alverne Duarte e Osmani Teixeira de C. Guillen

Maio/2003

73 Análise de Componentes Principais de Dados Funcionais – uma Aplicação às Estruturas a Termo de Taxas de Juros

Getúlio Borges da Silveira e Octavio Bessada

Maio/2003

74 Aplicação do Modelo de Black, Derman & Toy à Precificação de Opções Sobre Títulos de Renda Fixa

Octavio Manuel Bessada Lion, Carlos Alberto Nunes Cosenza e César das Neves

Maio/2003

75 Brazil’s Financial System: Resilience to Shocks, no Currency Substitution, but Struggling to Promote Growth

Ilan Goldfajn, Katherine Hennings and Helio Mori

(30)

76 Inflation Targeting in Emerging Market Economies

Arminio Fraga, Ilan Goldfajn and André Minella

Jun/2003

77 Inflation Targeting in Brazil: Constructing Credibility under Exchange Rate Volatility

André Minella, Paulo Springer de Freitas, Ilan Goldfajn and Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos

Jul/2003

78 Contornando os Pressupostos de Black & Scholes: Aplicação do Modelo de Precificação de Opções de Duan no Mercado Brasileiro

Gustavo Silva Araújo, Claudio Henrique da Silveira Barbedo, Antonio Carlos Figueiredo, Eduardo Facó Lemgruber

Out/2003

79 Inclusão do Decaimento Temporal na Metodologia Delta-Gama para o Cálculo do VaR de Carteiras Compradas em Opções no Brasil

Claudio Henrique da Silveira Barbedo, Gustavo Silva Araújo, Eduardo Facó Lemgruber

Out/2003

80 Diferenças e Semelhanças entre Países da América Latina: uma Análise de Markov Switching para os Ciclos Econômicos de Brasil e Argentina

Arnildo da Silva Correa

Out/2003

81 Bank Competition, Agency Costs and the Performance of the Monetary Policy

Leonardo Soriano de Alencar and Márcio I. Nakane

Jan/2004

82 Carteiras de Opções: Avaliação de Metodologias de Exigência de Capital no Mercado Brasileiro

Cláudio Henrique da Silveira Barbedo e Gustavo Silva Araújo

Mar/2004

83 Does Inflation Targeting Reduce Inflation? An Analysis for the OECD Industrial Countries

Thomas Y. Wu

May/2004

84 Speculative Attacks on Debts and Optimum Currency Area: a Welfare Analysis

Aloisio Araujo and Marcia Leon

May/2004

85 Risk Premia for Emerging Markets Bonds: Evidence from Brazilian Government Debt, 1996-2002

André Soares Loureiro and Fernando de Holanda Barbosa

May/2004

86 Identificação do Fator Estocástico de Descontos e Algumas Implicações sobre Testes de Modelos de Consumo

Fabio Araujo e João Victor Issler

Maio/2004

87 Mercado de Crédito: uma Análise Econométrica dos Volumes de Crédito Total e Habitacional no Brasil

Ana Carla Abrão Costa

Dez/2004

88 Ciclos Internacionais de Negócios: uma Análise de Mudança de Regime Markoviano para Brasil, Argentina e Estados Unidos

Arnildo da Silva Correa e Ronald Otto Hillbrecht

Dez/2004

89 O Mercado de Hedge Cambial no Brasil: Reação das Instituições Financeiras a Intervenções do Banco Central

Fernando N. de Oliveira

(31)

90 Bank Privatization and Productivity: Evidence for Brazil

Márcio I. Nakane and Daniela B. Weintraub

Dec/2004

91 Credit Risk Measurement and the Regulation of Bank Capital and Provision Requirements in Brazil – a Corporate Analysis

Ricardo Schechtman, Valéria Salomão Garcia, Sergio Mikio Koyama and Guilherme Cronemberger Parente

Dec/2004

92 Steady-State Analysis of an Open Economy General Equilibrium Model for Brazil

Mirta Noemi Sataka Bugarin, Roberto de Goes Ellery Jr., Victor Gomes Silva, Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos

Apr/2005

93 Avaliação de Modelos de Cálculo de Exigência de Capital para Risco Cambial

Claudio H. da S. Barbedo, Gustavo S. Araújo, João Maurício S. Moreira e Ricardo S. Maia Clemente

Abr/2005

94 Simulação Histórica Filtrada: Incorporação da Volatilidade ao Modelo Histórico de Cálculo de Risco para Ativos Não-Lineares

Claudio Henrique da Silveira Barbedo, Gustavo Silva Araújo e Eduardo Facó Lemgruber

Abr/2005

95 Comment on Market Discipline and Monetary Policy by Carl Walsh

Maurício S. Bugarin and Fábia A. de Carvalho

Apr/2005

96 O que É Estratégia: uma Abordagem Multiparadigmática para a Disciplina

Anthero de Moraes Meirelles

Ago/2005

97 Finance and the Business Cycle: a Kalman Filter Approach with Markov Switching

Ryan A. Compton and Jose Ricardo da Costa e Silva

Aug/2005

98 Capital Flows Cycle: Stylized Facts and Empirical Evidences for Emerging Market Economies

Helio Mori e Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos

Aug/2005

99 Adequação das Medidas de Valor em Risco na Formulação da Exigência de Capital para Estratégias de Opções no Mercado Brasileiro

Gustavo Silva Araújo, Claudio Henrique da Silveira Barbedo,e Eduardo Facó Lemgruber

Set/2005

100 Targets and Inflation Dynamics

Sergio A. L. Alves and Waldyr D. Areosa

Oct/2005

101 Comparing Equilibrium Real Interest Rates: Different Approaches to Measure Brazilian Rates

Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos and Márcio I. Nakane

Mar/2006

102 Judicial Risk and Credit Market Performance: Micro Evidence from Brazilian Payroll Loans

Ana Carla A. Costa and João M. P. de Mello

Apr/2006

103 The Effect of Adverse Supply Shocks on Monetary Policy and Output

Maria da Glória D. S. Araújo, Mirta Bugarin, Marcelo Kfoury Muinhos and Jose Ricardo C. Silva

(32)

104 Extração de Informação de Opções Cambiais no Brasil

Eui Jung Chang e Benjamin Miranda Tabak

Abr/2006

105 Representing Roommate’s Preferences with Symmetric Utilities

José Alvaro Rodrigues Neto

Apr/2006

106 Testing Nonlinearities Between Brazilian Exchange Rates and Inflation Volatilities

Cristiane R. Albuquerque and Marcelo Portugal

May/2006

107 Demand for Bank Services and Market Power in Brazilian Banking

Márcio I. Nakane, Leonardo S. Alencar and Fabio Kanczuk

Jun/2006

108 O Efeito da Consignação em Folha nas Taxas de Juros dos Empréstimos Pessoais

Eduardo A. S. Rodrigues, Victorio Chu, Leonardo S. Alencar e Tony Takeda

Jun/2006

109 The Recent Brazilian Disinflation Process and Costs

Alexandre A. Tombini and Sergio A. Lago Alves

Jun/2006

110 Fatores de Risco e o Spread Bancário no Brasil

Fernando G. Bignotto e Eduardo Augusto de Souza Rodrigues

Jul/2006

111 Avaliação de Modelos de Exigência de Capital para Risco de Mercado do Cupom Cambial

Alan Cosme Rodrigues da Silva, João Maurício de Souza Moreira e Myrian Beatriz Eiras das Neves

Jul/2006

112 Interdependence and Contagion: an Analysis of Information Transmission in Latin America's Stock Markets

Angelo Marsiglia Fasolo

Jul/2006

113 Investigação da Memória de Longo Prazo da Taxa de Câmbio no Brasil

Sergio Rubens Stancato de Souza, Benjamin Miranda Tabak e Daniel O. Cajueiro

Ago/2006

114 The Inequality Channel of Monetary Transmission

Marta Areosa and Waldyr Areosa

Aug/2006

115 Myopic Loss Aversion and House-Money Effect Overseas: an Experimental Approach

José L. B. Fernandes, Juan Ignacio Peña and Benjamin M. Tabak

Sep/2006

116 Out-Of-The-Money Monte Carlo Simulation Option Pricing: the Join Use of Importance Sampling and Descriptive Sampling

Jaqueline Terra Moura Marins, Eduardo Saliby and Joséte Florencio dos Santos

Sep/2006

117 An Analysis of Off-Site Supervision of Banks’ Profitability, Risk and Capital Adequacy: a Portfolio Simulation Approach Applied to Brazilian Banks

Theodore M. Barnhill, Marcos R. Souto and Benjamin M. Tabak

Sep/2006

118 Contagion, Bankruptcy and Social Welfare Analysis in a Financial Economy with Risk Regulation Constraint

Aloísio P. Araújo and José Valentim M. Vicente

(33)

119 A Central de Risco de Crédito no Brasil: uma Análise de Utilidade de Informação

Ricardo Schechtman

Out/2006

120 Forecasting Interest Rates: an Application for Brazil

Eduardo J. A. Lima, Felipe Luduvice and Benjamin M. Tabak

Oct/2006

121 The Role of Consumer’s Risk Aversion on Price Rigidity

Sergio A. Lago Alves and Mirta N. S. Bugarin

Nov/2006

122 Nonlinear Mechanisms of the Exchange Rate Pass-Through: a Phillips Curve Model With Threshold for Brazil

Arnildo da Silva Correa and André Minella

Nov/2006

123 A Neoclassical Analysis of the Brazilian “Lost-Decades”

Flávia Mourão Graminho

Nov/2006

124 The Dynamic Relations between Stock Prices and Exchange Rates: Evidence for Brazil

Benjamin M. Tabak

Nov/2006

125 Herding Behavior by Equity Foreign Investors on Emerging Markets

Barbara Alemanni and José Renato Haas Ornelas

Dec/2006

126 Risk Premium: Insights over the Threshold

José L. B. Fernandes, Augusto Hasman and Juan Ignacio Peña

Dec/2006

127 Uma Investigação Baseada em Reamostragem sobre Requerimentos de Capital para Risco de Crédito no Brasil

Ricardo Schechtman

Dec/2006

128 Term Structure Movements Implicit in Option Prices

Caio Ibsen R. Almeida and José Valentim M. Vicente

Dec/2006

129 Brazil: Taming Inflation Expectations

Afonso S. Bevilaqua, Mário Mesquita and André Minella

Jan/2007

130 The Role of Banks in the Brazilian Interbank Market: Does Bank Type Matter?

Daniel O. Cajueiro and Benjamin M. Tabak

Jan/2007

131 Long-Range Dependence in Exchange Rates: the Case of the European Monetary System

Sergio Rubens Stancato de Souza, Benjamin M. Tabak and Daniel O. Cajueiro

Mar/2007

132 Credit Risk Monte Carlo Simulation Using Simplified Creditmetrics’ Model: the Joint Use of Importance Sampling and Descriptive Sampling

Jaqueline Terra Moura Marins and Eduardo Saliby

Mar/2007

133 A New Proposal for Collection and Generation of Information on Financial Institutions’ Risk: the Case of Derivatives

Gilneu F. A. Vivan and Benjamin M. Tabak

Mar/2007

134 Amostragem Descritiva no Apreçamento de Opções Européias através de Simulação Monte Carlo: o Efeito da Dimensionalidade e da

Probabilidade de Exercício no Ganho de Precisão

Eduardo Saliby, Sergio Luiz Medeiros Proença de Gouvêa e Jaqueline Terra Moura Marins

(34)

135 Evaluation of Default Risk for the Brazilian Banking Sector

Marcelo Y. Takami and Benjamin M. Tabak

May/2007

136 Identifying Volatility Risk Premium from Fixed Income Asian Options

Caio Ibsen R. Almeida and José Valentim M. Vicente

May/2007

137 Monetary Policy Design under Competing Models of Inflation Persistence

Solange Gouvea e Abhijit Sen Gupta

May/2007

138 Forecasting Exchange Rate Density Using Parametric Models: the Case of Brazil

Marcos M. Abe, Eui J. Chang and Benjamin M. Tabak

May/2007

139 Selection of Optimal Lag Length inCointegrated VAR Models with Weak Form of Common Cyclical Features

Carlos Enrique Carrasco Gutiérrez, Reinaldo Castro Souza and Osmani Teixeira de Carvalho Guillén

Jun/2007

140 Inflation Targeting, Credibility and Confidence Crises

Rafael Santos and Aloísio Araújo

Aug/2007

141 Forecasting Bonds Yields in the Brazilian Fixed income Market

Jose Vicente and Benjamin M. Tabak

Aug/2007

142 Crises Análise da Coerência de Medidas de Risco no Mercado Brasileiro de Ações e Desenvolvimento de uma Metodologia Híbrida para o

Expected Shortfall

Alan Cosme Rodrigues da Silva, Eduardo Facó Lemgruber, José Alberto Rebello Baranowski e Renato da Silva Carvalho

Ago/2007

143 Price Rigidity in Brazil: Evidence from CPI Micro Data

Solange Gouvea

Sep/2007

144 The Effect of Bid-Ask Prices on Brazilian Options Implied Volatility: a Case Study of Telemar Call Options

Claudio Henrique da Silveira Barbedo and Eduardo Facó Lemgruber

Oct/2007

145 The Stability-Concentration Relationship in the Brazilian Banking System

Benjamin Miranda Tabak, Solange Maria Guerra, Eduardo José Araújo Lima and Eui Jung Chang

Oct/2007

146 Movimentos da Estrutura a Termo e Critérios de Minimização do Erro de Previsão em um Modelo Paramétrico Exponencial

Caio Almeida, Romeu Gomes, André Leite e José Vicente

Out/2007

147 Explaining Bank Failures in Brazil: Micro, Macro and Contagion Effects (1994-1998)

Adriana Soares Sales and Maria Eduarda Tannuri-Pianto

Oct/2007

148 Um Modelo de Fatores Latentes com Variáveis Macroeconômicas para a Curva de Cupom Cambial

Felipe Pinheiro, Caio Almeida e José Vicente

Out/2007

149 Joint Validation of Credit Rating PDs under Default Correlation

Ricardo Schechtman

(35)

150 A Probabilistic Approach for Assessing the Significance of Contextual Variables in Nonparametric Frontier Models: an Application for Brazilian Banks

Roberta Blass Staub and Geraldo da Silva e Souza

Oct/2007

151 Building Confidence Intervals with Block Bootstraps for the Variance Ratio Test of Predictability

Nov/2007

Eduardo José Araújo Lima and Benjamin Miranda Tabak

152 Demand for Foreign Exchange Derivatives in Brazil: Hedge or Speculation?

Fernando N. de Oliveira and Walter Novaes

Dec/2007

153 Aplicação da Amostragem por Importância à Simulação de Opções Asiáticas Fora do Dinheiro

Jaqueline Terra Moura Marins

Dez/2007

154 Identification of Monetary Policy Shocks in the Brazilian Market for Bank Reserves

Adriana Soares Sales and Maria Tannuri-Pianto

Dec/2007

155 Does Curvature Enhance Forecasting?

Caio Almeida, Romeu Gomes, André Leite and José Vicente

Dec/2007

156 Escolha do Banco e Demanda por Empréstimos: um Modelo de Decisão em Duas Etapas Aplicado para o Brasil

Sérgio Mikio Koyama e Márcio I. Nakane

Dez/2007

157 Is the Investment-Uncertainty Link Really Elusive? The Harmful Effects of Inflation Uncertainty in Brazil

Tito Nícias Teixeira da Silva Filho

Jan/2008

158 Characterizing the Brazilian Term Structure of Interest Rates

Osmani T. Guillen and Benjamin M. Tabak

Feb/2008

159 Behavior and Effects of Equity Foreign Investors on Emerging Markets

Barbara Alemanni and José Renato Haas Ornelas

Feb/2008

160 The Incidence of Reserve Requirements in Brazil: Do Bank Stockholders Share the Burden?

Fábia A. de Carvalho and Cyntia F. Azevedo

Feb/2008

161 Evaluating Value-at-Risk Models via Quantile Regressions

Wagner P. Gaglianone, Luiz Renato Lima and Oliver Linton

Feb/2008

162 Balance Sheet Effects in Currency Crises: Evidence from Brazil

Marcio M. Janot, Márcio G. P. Garcia and Walter Novaes

Apr/2008

163 Searching for the Natural Rate of Unemployment in a Large Relative Price Shocks’ Economy: the Brazilian Case

Tito Nícias Teixeira da Silva Filho

May/2008

164 Foreign Banks’ Entry and Departure: the recent Brazilian experience (1996-2006)

Pedro Fachada

Jun/2008

165 Avaliação de Opções de Troca e Opções de Spread Européias e Americanas

Giuliano Carrozza Uzêda Iorio de Souza, Carlos Patrício Samanez e Gustavo Santos Raposo

References

Related documents

Only the largest companies in this category have any consumer banking business, and this business is currently quite small compared to their mortgage lending operations.. (A

Memory Scheduling is a software-based solution aimed at solving the problem of increasing memory and performance demands of today and tomorrow’s software applications.. It

Methods: People aged 25 to 64 in both the National Health Interview Survey (with 2-year mortality follow-up) and the Medical Expenditure Panel Survey were examined to estimate

Oil companies and industry groups have also recognized that international oil companies operating in emerging economies such as Nigeria, with inadequate

Laser alignment equipment Copies of the Quick Quizzes Module Examinations Performance Profile Sheets. MODULE 32406-09 – introduction to supervisory skills Overhead projector

By taking account of various traffic externalities and focusing on the traffic on local streets, our study therefore amends existing quasi-experimental research on valuation of

Grady received Doctor of Science, Honoris Causa degrees from the Medical University of South Carolina and Thomas Jefferson University, and Columbia University

The middle Neolithic was also a time when cremations and inhumations were being deposited simultaneously as evidenced by the later burials at Duggleby Howe (Gibson &